Softpanorama

May the source be with you, but remember the KISS principle ;-)
Home Switchboard Unix Administration Red Hat TCP/IP Networks Neoliberalism Toxic Managers
(slightly skeptical) Educational society promoting "Back to basics" movement against IT overcomplexity and  bastardization of classic Unix

Philip Pilkington: The Origins of Neoliberalism. Part I


Philip Pilkington: The Origins of Neoliberalism, Part I – Hayek’s Delusion

By Philip Pilkington, a writer and research assistant at Kingston University in London. You can follow him on Twitter @pilkingtonphil

It is not only by dint of lying to others, but also of lying to ourselves, that we cease to notice that we are lying.

– Marcel Proust

Friedrich Hayek was an unusual character. Although well known to be a libertarian political philosopher, he is also commonly associated with being an economist. And it’s certainly true that at one time Hayek’s focus was solely on economics. In the 1920s Hayek was still within the fold of pure economics, publishing papers and works that were taken seriously by the discipline. However, by the 1930s Hayek’s theories had started to come apart at the seams. Exchanges between Hayek and John Maynard Keynes and Piero Sraffa show Hayek as confused and even somewhat desperate. It was around this time that Hayek discontinued making any substantial contributions to economics. Not coincidentally this overlapped with the time when most economies, mired as in Great Depression, demonstrated that Hayek’s theories were at best impractical, at worst a complete perversion of facts.

So, Hayek turned instead to constructing political philosophies and honing a metaphysics rather than engaging in any substantial way with the new economics that was emerging. When pure logic and empirical reality ceased to support Hayek’s emotionally charged ideology he turned, to the more malleable sphere of meaning and metaphysics. He became concerned with watery terms like “freedom” and “liberty”, which he then set out to impregnate with a meaning that would support his dreams. The most famous result of this period of conversion, which resembled less St. Paul on the road to Damascus and more so an alcoholic who had hit rock bottom, was Hayek’s 1944 work The Road to Serfdom. In a very real way it was this book that marked the close of Hayek’s career as a serious economic thinker and set him on the path of the political propagandist, agitator and organiser.

The over-arching argument of the book is well-known and need not be repeated too extensively here. Hayek thought that all totalitarianisms had their origins in forms of economic planning. Economic planning was the cause of totalitarianism for Hayek, rather than the being just a feature of it. Underneath it all this was a rather crude argument. One may as well make the observation that totalitarianism was often accompanied by arms build-up, therefore arms build-ups “cause” totalitarianism. But Hayek pushed it and most probably believed it anyway, for reasons that we shall soon see.

The implicit argument here was that, Britain for example, which had begun to increasingly plan its economy during the war, was on a slippery slope that would end in totalitarianism. It must be understood that Hayek’s argument had no factual basis. Only a polemicist could argue that the two totalitarianisms that existed in this period – namely, Hitler’s Germany and Stalin’s Soviet Union – had formed because a naïve democratic government had engaged in some economic planning that then got out of hand and resulted in tyranny. But Hayek’s motivations probably lay somewhat deeper – probably so deep that he himself could not properly recognise them.

The Rise of the Third Reich: Hayek’s Historical Repression

To understand Hayek’s “reasoning” a bit better we should consider the political situation that he refused to return to after Austria’s annexation by Hitler in 1938. The broad reasons for Hitler’s rise to power are beyond dispute among serious historians today. The sweeping picture of Germany in this era is that she was not only humiliated after the First World War but was also subject to vicious reparations payments – payments which ultimately set off a hyperinflation in the country. The average German knew that the national humiliation and the economic turmoil were intimately connected and so they became increasingly bitter about the Treaty of Versailles which they thought, quite rightly, had subjected the country to both economic and political bondage. It was into this vacuum that Hitler and his cronies stepped and began, in the early to mid-1920s, to accumulate political support.

However, after the hyperinflation came to an end and thanks to loans from the United States, the reparations troubles eased and the German economy began to return to moderate growth. Hitler’s popularity fell enormously in this period. But the 1929 stock market crash soon came and the loans from the United States promptly dried up. Unemployment soared in Germany and the government, like so many others across the world, engaged in severe austerity in order to attempt to balance the budget. They believed that this would return the country to economic prosperity.

In retrospect it is quite obvious that Hitler’s immediate rise to power was due to the economic downturn and the government’s deflationary policy response. In 1930 the Nazis had become the second largest party, obtaining 18.3% of the votes. When compared with the 2.8% of the vote they received in 1928 during an era of high employment and an economically optimistic outlook it quickly becomes obvious what the underlying forces driving Hitler’s election actually were.

That the economic policies the Weimar government had engaged in had led to the election of Hitler was and is obvious to any unbiased observer. But there were many who actively repressed this fact. The liberals that had supported the government’s austerity measures no doubt felt some burden, whether unconscious or otherwise, of guilt. This is best illustrated by an anecdote that the American economist John Kenneth Galbraith relates regarding the Chancellor who presided over the austerity, Heinrich Brüning, which he published in his book Money: Whence It Came, Where It Went:

In the 30s, Brüning joined the Harvard faculty as Professor of Government. At a welcoming seminar one evening I asked him if his Draconian measures at a time of general deflation had not advanced the cause of Adolf Hitler. He said that they had not. When, unwisely, I pressed the point, he asked me if I disputed the word of the former Chancellor of the German Reich.

This was then, rather unsurprisingly, a touchy subject for Brüning which he preferred to evade. After all, the facts were simply not on his side and there was no way he could rationally argue to the contrary. Likewise too for those liberals like Hayek who firmly believed that the austerity measures were the only road to salvation. Mark Ames at the eXiledonline sums up rather nicely the reaction this provoked in Hayek and the other Austrian school libertarians:

Von Hayek and his fellow Austrian aristocrats who were forced to flee from the fruits of their economic programs, did a complete revision of history and retold that same story as if the very opposite of reality had happened. Once they were safely in England and America, sponsored and funded by oligarch grants, hacks like von Mises and von Hayek started pushing a revisionist history of the collapse of Weimar Germany blaming not their austerity measures, but rather big-spending liberals who were allegedly in charge of Germany’s last government. Somehow, von Hayek looked at Chancellor Bruning’s policies of massive budget cuts combined with pegging the currency to the gold standard, the policies that led to Weimar Germany’s collapse, policies that became the cornerstone of Hayek’s cult—and decided that Bruning hadn’t existed.

An Existential Choice

It is not hard to discern whether Hayek was lying or simply deluded. He was not lying – at least not consciously. For the rest of his life he was driven by a genuine belief in the idea, put forward in The Road to Serfdom, that economic planning was what had led to totalitarianism in Europe. It was not hard to discern if Hayek was lying simply by looking at the zeal with which he pursued the crusade against planning. This was not the cynical enthusiasm of a charlatan, but instead the forward impetus of a man who, as if riding a bicycle, would come crashing down emotionally if lost his momentum.

Hayek’s entire ideology and career had begun to come apart in the 1930s. His theories were shown to be inconsistent in the academic journals of the time and the practical implications of those theories had shown themselves to be both discredited and dangerous. A man in such a position only has two choices: he can either completely re-evaluate his ideas which, if they were held with unshakeable conviction and constituted a core component of his emotional make-up, as seems to have been the case with Hayek, would have likely resulted in a mental collapse; or, alternatively, he can engage in a massive repression, shut out reality and construct around himself a fantasy world.

Hayek opted for the latter. So too did all of what was to become the neo-Austrian school which soon developed into a sealed hermetic cult of True Believers who reinforced each other’s unsubstantiated ideas and defended each other from the threatening world outside the circle. But this cult was largely fringe. Although it did command some respect among neoliberals in the Thatcher and Reagan administrations, it was the respect accorded to the eccentric rather than that accorded to the practical man. Lip service was paid to the doctrines of Hayek and the Austrians, but their extremist and impractical economic policy implications were sterilised and kept out of immediate contact with the levers of power. Milton Friedman’s more pragmatic doctrines of monetarism were preferred so far as economic policies went.

But we should not fool ourselves. Hayek’s delusion did indeed have profound effects on history. Indeed, as we shall see, it was even directly responsible for Friedman’s rise. For Hayek, in his crusade against what he thought the germ from which totalitarianism spread, became a tireless worker and organiser. With the ingenuity of a Leninist, Hayek formed around him a host of like-minded thinkers and politicians. Backed by the funding of right-wing millionaires, Hayek constructed a network of people who he initiated into his delusion and convinced that every manifestation of collective intervention into the free market was just one more stepping stone on the road to serfdom.

Likewise in the popular mind – for Hayek did effectively become a political propagandist rather than a respected intellectual in the 1940s – Hayek’s delusion, with all its emotional overtones, spread quite effectively. Today whenever we encounter an anxiety-ridden Tea Partier or a fearful and paranoid internet Austrian, it is Hayek’s delusion that we are hearing echoed through the chambers of history, albeit in slightly vulgarised form. It is the fear, distrust and paranoia which Hayek’s portrait of a free society descending into barbarism evokes that captures the minds of those it touches. That it is completely deluded and ignorant of history only makes it more effective, like all propaganda, in its role as propaganda. The bigger the lie, the more emotional investment it requires to believe in and so the more it captures the uncritical and the emotionally weak.

The inner sanctum from which Hayek’s delusion emanated was called the Mont Pelerin Society. In the next piece in this series we will turn to how Hayek’s delusion was diluted by those in the Mont Pelerin Society to fit with the American political system; this is what we might call the American version of neoliberalism. While in the final piece we will consider how Hayek’s delusion was gradually converted into the European form of neoliberalism when it was confronted with the problem of trade unions. As we shall see there is much overlap between these two forms of neoliberalism and each borrows from the other – this, of course, being the reason why they are not generally distinguished between – but most importantly, they share a common root in the wall that Hayek erected in his mind in the 1930s and 1940s to block out a world that he himself had played a part in creating.

Topics: Guest Post, Politics, Social values, The dismal science

 Email This Post Posted by Yves Smith at 5:50 am

146 Comments » Links to this post

 

146 Comments:

 
  •  Schofield says:

    January 9, 2013 at 6:30 am

    Have you failed to factor in the Nazis use of MMT and Hayek’s Libertarian dogma failure to recognise this in your full essay?

    Reply
  •  skippy says:

    January 9, 2013 at 6:32 am

    IMO having at his father’s suggestion as a teenager, read the genetic and evolutionary works of Hugo de Vries, a fuse was lit in Hayek’s head.

    Hugo De Vries book Intracellular Pangenesis and his lack of understanding the mutation theory of evolution, in favor of concept of genes, rediscovering the laws of heredity in the 1890s, well its just more eugenics, better breeding et al crap…eh

    Skippy… Was old pop angry about the law against using the Von creeping in the shadows? Ask Ayn Rand methinks.

    BTW… The Prime Minister’s fundamentalism is driven in large part by the neo-liberalism of Friedrich Hayek, who argued that the only determinant of human freedom was the market. In fact, Hayek also argued that any form of altruism was dangerous because it distorted the market. To avoid inefficiencies, altruism had to be purged from the human soul. Hayek described altruism as something belonging to primitive societies that had no place in the modern world.

    http://www.theaustralian.com.au/opinion/kevin-rudd-child-of-hayek/story-e6frg6zo-1111112713990

    PS. Dialectical materialism… barf~

    PSS. Thank again PP.

    Reply
  •  David Lentini says:

    January 9, 2013 at 6:35 am

    Excellent commentary on Hayek. But I think that if Hayek was truly delusional as you claim, and I think it very likely he was, then refrring to his campaign for neo-liberalism as “propaganda” and “lies” is not accurate, since creating propaganda and lying are both conscious acts.

    Instead, I’d focus on the basis of Hayek’s delusion and why that delusion is so easily shared. From your history, I suspect that Hayek’s best work was done in the heyday of liberal ecnomic theory. When the markets crashed and Weimar Germany came unglued, and Marx’s prediction that capitalism would be the next (and last) phase of “history” looked quite prescient, it appears that Hayek retreated into a fantasy in which, as you note, cause and effect was reversed so that, in his mind, totalitarianism was caused by the economic planning needed to respond to the social chaos caused by the Great Depression instead of the failure of liberal economics. In short, Hayek could not accept the failure of his beloved liberalism and jiggered the facts to avoid his fears.

    The question then becomes how did this obvious fantasy become so compelling to so many? First, as you note, the Great Depression shattered many ideas about wealth, virtue, and genetic superiority. In the liberal world, the rich were rich either directly because of their virtuous actions or indirectly becuase of their superior genetic constitutions that passed inhereted virtual along with inhereted wealth. When all came crashing down, everyone is poor and therefore everyone is equal. Second, as John Dean described so well in his book Conseratives Without Conscience a great number of the population are very easily attracted to power. Systems of government and economics that emphasize egalitarian distribitions of power and wealth, like democracry and socialism, inherently limit the accumulation of power and are distrustful of power generally; these social arrangements will be hated by those who crave power and those who fall under the spell of the powerful.

    I think both factors are critical to understanding Hayek and the popularity of his ideas, especially in America. Amercians historically have equated wealth with moral virtue, the physical proof of God’s largesse on the blessed. Americans also have come to worship power in the form of the “pioneer” who creates a New Eded from the desert and, again, is justly rewarded for that work. The ’29 crash destroyed the connections between wealth and virtue and hard work; this was too much cultural cognitive dissonance for many, who became the true believers along with Hayek and the useful idiots for the rich who were plotting to unravel the New Deal at the earliest opportunity.

    Reply
  •  jake chase says:

    January 9, 2013 at 7:16 am

    I am not Sigmund Freud and will not attempt to psychoanalyze Hayek (or you either), but IMHO you do Hayek’s book, Road to Serfdom, an injustice. Because everything I write longer than two sentences is monitored, I will need a few more comments (3) to make my point.

    Reply
  •  The Gizmo51 says:

    January 9, 2013 at 8:57 am

    After having the 99% fund the wealth of the 1% for over 30 years President Obama has decided enough is enough and now it’s time for the 1% to pay their fair share. Close the tax loopholes (which should have never been created in the first place) of the rich and get a well paying job for all Americans and the problem would be solved. No, there is no spending problem. The problem was started by, continued by, and propagandized. by the republinos when they decided to Starve the Beast. Tell the average American that as their disposable income goes down and buys less and less that they have a spending problem, not an income problem. Doesn’t make sense for America and certainly doesn’t make sense for Americans.

    Reply
  •  Stevedoc22 says:

    January 9, 2013 at 9:19 am

    You cannot act as if the dramatic hyperinflation in postwar Germany did not have a profound effect on German savings (wiped out), pyschology (traumatized) and opinion of democratic government (incompetant). The depression and austerity response (which did not extend to Hindenburg’s karge landowner buddies, who kept getting grain subsidies) were just the last straw. Meanwhile, the Nazis were building support and honing their political skills.

    Reply
  •  Max424 says:

    January 9, 2013 at 10:55 am

    re: lies, propaganda, delusion, the lines are very blurry

    Yeah they are.

    I was talking with a young couple outside the poolroom late last night. They were trying to convince me that Wolf Blitzer was a journalist, and certainly not, as I claimed, a paid propagandist –or worthless hack, take your pick– who in another era, not so long ago, would’ve been laughed off center stage.

    We could have argued for many bitter cold hours about the present state of American journalism, instead (thanks to President Obama), I opted to use my new tactic, which is to reach right through the bullsh-t to the ultimate diamond. How easy is it? Pluck it, then present it. I said:

    “So, what does Wolfy think about the assassination of US citizens by the President of the United States. Is he for or against this? Or is he, as he is on all other things, perfectly neutral?”

    Who, when, where, how many!

    (Always with the who, when, where, how many)

    “Sorry, friends. This is the Age of Google. You both have iPhones, you are 30 seconds away from acquiring the truth.”

    “Now: who, when, where, and especially how many are completely and totally irrelevant. Obviously, all the necessary questions begin with why. Why are US citizens being assassinated by their President? Why do you not know this? Why is there not revolutionary outrage all across this Greatest of All Democracies and Birthplace of All Freedoms? Is it because, why the f-ck is Wolf Blitzer still on television?”

    They are indoctrinated sheep, and probably want to remain so. However, though I like them both, very much, I didn’t let up. The conversation ended with me saying:

    “No you guys, not in my experience. Ignorance is not bliss, ignorance in the end, is pain.”

    I walked back into the poolroom thinking, I’m 52, I gotta stop getting into time-wasting conversations like this if I want to be the best pool player in the world.

    At that moment, the best player that I have ever seen (and I’ve seen all the living), asked me if I wanted to practice. I said, Yeah, let’s go. 10-ball, no Rotation, you’re too good in that game.

    For next hour I sat in my seat and watched a half-man half-machine mow down balls and never miss. Not once. In the back of my head that traitorous voice started to rise up like it always does when I’m watching this master of the craft: Given forty lifetimes … one hundred lifetimes … (all right … enough)… GIVEN ONE THOUSAND LIFETIMES, you could never play like this.

    When the session ended, I said: Ok D.H., I’ll see you tomorrow. Drive safe.

    I started hitting balls by myself. Hitting them good. Real good. Splitting pockets. My true voice came back, the audible one. I said to some railbirds who’d been watching me get slaughtered:

    You know, that f-cker don’t play that good.

    And after the slightest of pauses to consider this, we all burst into laughter.

    Reply
  •  pebird says:

    January 9, 2013 at 11:15 am

    Philip:

    Very informative post, thanks for doing the research and historical background on Hayek. Persuasive analysis. I have this post bookmarked for future reference. Looking forward to the upcoming posts.

    Reply
  •  aj says:

    January 9, 2013 at 11:27 am

    Great post. I look forward to reading the rest.

    Reply
  •  Craig Clark says:

    January 9, 2013 at 12:39 pm

    My comment is that anytime I take the time to write a somewhat thoughtful (i.e. contains factual data) response to an article that my comments do not get posted. I don’t know if I am doing something wrong in the posting process (if so, my apoligies) or this is an attempt to censor comments so that only those who disagree and don’t make too good of an argument are published.

    Reply
  •  Samuel Conner says:

    January 9, 2013 at 1:02 pm

    Hi Philip,

    Re: the causes of the Weimar hyperinflation, this item may be of interest:

    http://www.macroresilience.com/2012/10/12/hyperinflation-deficits-and-real-interest-rates/

    It would be interesting to know what was going through the minds of the leaders of the Reichsbank, but it kind of looks like they were simply funding asset grabs by those in a position to borrow at negative real interest rates. Some things never change, perhaps.

    Reply
  •  BC says:

    January 9, 2013 at 1:03 pm

    “Not coincidentally this overlapped with the time when most economies, mired as in Great Depression, demonstrated that Hayek’s theories were at best impractical, at worst a complete perversion of facts.”

    Let me reprint a short but succint article summarizing the facts surrounding Herbert Hoover’s “austerity.” Spoiler alert–he did everything that modern economists perscribe.

    The Depression You’ve Never Heard Of: 1920-1921

    NOVEMBER 18, 2009 by ROBERT P. MURPHY

    When it comes to diagnosing the causes of the Great Depression and prescribing cures for our present recession, the pundits and economists from the biggest schools typically argue about two different types of intervention. Big-government Keynesians, such as Paul Krugman, argue for massive fiscal stimulus—that is, huge budget deficits—to fill the gap in aggregate demand. On the other hand, small-government monetarists, who follow in the laissez-faire tradition of Milton Friedman, believe that the Federal Reserve needs to pump in more money to prevent the economy from falling into deep depression. Yet both sides of the debate agree that it would be utter disaster for the government and Fed to stand back and allow market forces to run their natural course after a major stock market or housing crash.

    In contrast, many Austrian economists reject both forms of intervention. They argue that the free market would respond in the most efficient manner possible after a major disruption (such as the 1929 stock market crash or the housing bubble in our own times). As we shall see, the U.S. experience during the 1920–1921 depression—one that the reader has probably never heard of—is almost a laboratory experiment showcasing the flaws of both the Keynesian and monetarist prescriptions.

    The 1929–1933 Great Contraction

    Despite what many readers undoubtedly “learned” in their history classes as children, Herbert Hoover behaved like a textbook Keynesian following the 1929 stock market crash. In conjunction with Treasury Secretary Andrew Mellon, Hoover achieved an across-the-board one percentage point reduction in income tax rates applicable to the 1929 tax year.

    Hoover didn’t stop with tax cuts to bolster “aggregate demand”—though analysts at that time would not have used the term. He also signed into law massive increases in the federal budget, with fiscal year (FY) 1932 spending rising 42 percent above 1930 levels. Hoover ran unprecedented peacetime deficits, which stood in sharp contrast to his predecessor Calvin Coolidge, who had run a budget surplus every year of his presidency. In fact, in the 1932 election FDR campaigned on a balanced budget and excoriated the reckless spending record of the Republican incumbent.

    It wasn’t merely that Hoover spent a bunch of money. He spent it on just the types of things that we associate today with Roosevelt’s New Deal. For example, he signed off on numerous public-works projects, including the Hoover Dam. Of particular relevance today is the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC) established under Hoover, which quickly injected more than $1 billion to prop up troubled banks that had made bad loans during the boom years of the late 1920s—and this was when $1 billion really meant something.

    It is true that Hoover eventually blinked and raised taxes in 1932, in an effort to reduce the federal budget deficit. Today’s Keynesians point to this move as proof that reducing deficits is a bad idea in the middle of a depression. Yet an equally valid interpretation is that it’s horrible to hike tax rates in the middle of an economic disaster. After the bold tax cuts pushed through by Andrew Mellon in the 1920s, the top marginal income-tax rate in 1932 stood at 25 percent. The next year, because of Hoover’s desire to close the budget hole, the top income tax rate was 63 percent. Given this extraordinary single-year rate hike, it is no wonder that 1933 was the single worst year in U.S. economic history. (For what it’s worth, the FY 1933 budget deficit was still huge, coming in at 4.5 percent of GDP. Despite the huge rate hikes, federal tax revenues only increased 3.8 percent from FY 1932 to FY 1933.)

    So we see that the standard Keynesian story, which paints Herbert Hoover as a do-nothing liquidationist, is completely false. Yet Milton Friedman’s explanation for the Great Depression is almost as dubious. Following the stock market crash, the New York Federal Reserve Bank immediately slashed its discount rate—how much it charged on loans—in an attempt to provide relief to the beleaguered financial system. The New York Fed continued to slash its discount rate over the next two years, pushing it down to 1.5 percent by May 1931. At that time, this was the lowest discount rate the New York Fed had ever charged since the establishment of the Federal Reserve System in 1913.

    It wasn’t merely that the Fed (along with other central banks around the world) was charging an unusually low rate on loans it advanced from its discount window. The entire mentality of central bankers was different during the early years of the Great Depression. Writing in 1934, Lionel Robbins first noted that during previous crises, the solution had been for central banks to charge a high discount rate to separate the wheat from the chaff. Those firms that were truly solvent but illiquid would be willing to pay the high interest rates on central-bank loans to get them through the storm. Firms that were simply insolvent, on the other hand, would know the jig was up because they couldn’t afford the high rates. Yet this tough love was not administered after the 1929 crash, as Robbins explained: “In the present depression we have changed all that. We eschew the sharp purge. We prefer the lingering disease. Everywhere, in the money market, in the commodity markets and in the broad field of company finance and public indebtedness, the efforts of Central Banks and Governments have been directed to propping up bad business positions.”

    We therefore see an eerie pattern. When it came to both fiscal and monetary policy during the early 1930s, the governments and central banks implemented the same strategies that the sophisticated experts recommend today for our present crisis. Of course, today’s Keynesians and monetarists have a ready retort: They will tell us that their prescribed medicines (deficits and monetary injections, respectively) were not administered in large enough doses. It was the timidity of Hoover’s deficits (for the Keynesians) or the Fed’s injections of liquidity (for the monetarists) that caused the Great Depression.

    The 1920–1921 Depression

    This context highlights the importance of the 1920–1921 depression. Here the government and Fed did the exact opposite of what the experts now recommend. We have just about the closest thing to a controlled experiment in macroeconomics that one could desire. To repeat, it’s not that the government boosted the budget at a slower rate, or that the Fed provided a tad less liquidity. On the contrary, the government slashed its budget tremendously, and the Fed hiked rates to record highs. We thus have a fairly clear-cut experiment to test the efficacy of the Keynesian and monetarist remedies.

    At the conclusion of World War I, U.S. officials found themselves in a bleak position. The federal debt had exploded because of wartime expenditures, and annual consumer price inflation rates had jumped well above 20 percent by the end of the war.

    To restore fiscal and price sanity, the authorities implemented what today strikes us as incredibly “merciless” policies. From FY 1919 to 1920, federal spending was slashed from $18.5 billion to $6.4 billion—a 65 percent reduction in one year. The budget was pushed down the next two years as well, to $3.3 billion in FY 1922.

    On the monetary side, the New York Fed raised its discount rate to a record high 7 percent by June 1920. Now the reader might think that this nominal rate was actually “looser” than the 1.5 percent discount rate charged in 1931 because of the changes in inflation rates. But on the contrary, the price deflation of the 1920–1921 depression was more severe. From its peak in June 1920 the Consumer Price Index fell 15.8 percent over the next 12 months. In contrast, year-over-year price deflation never even reached 11 percent at any point during the Great Depression. Whether we look at nominal interest rates or “real” (inflation-adjusted) interest rates, the Fed was very “tight” during the 1920–1921 depression and very “loose” during the onset of the Great Depression.

    Now some modern economists will point out that our story leaves out an important element. Even though the Fed slashed its discount rate to record lows during the onset of the Great Depression, the total stock of money held by the public collapsed by roughly a third from 1929 to 1933. This is why Milton Friedman blamed the Fed for not doing enough to avert the Great Depression. By flooding the banking system with newly created reserves (part of the “monetary base”), the Fed could have offset the massive cash withdrawals of the panicked public and kept the overall money stock constant.

    But even this nuanced argument fails to demonstrate why the 1929–1933 downturn should have been more severe than the 1920–1921 depression. The collapse in the monetary base (directly controlled by the Fed) during 1920–1921 was the largest in U.S. history, and it dwarfed the fall during the early Hoover years. So we hit the same problem: The standard monetarist explanation for the Great Depression applies all the more so to the 1920–1921 depression.

    The Results

    If the Keynesians are right about the Great Depression, then the depression of 1920–1921 should have been far worse. The same holds for the monetarists; things should have been awful in the 1920s if their theory of the 1930s is correct.

    To be sure, the 1920–1921 depression was painful. The unemployment rate peaked at 11.7 percent in 1921. But it had dropped to 6.7 percent by the following year, and was down to 2.4 percent by 1923. After the depression the United States proceeded to enjoy the “Roaring Twenties,” arguably the most prosperous decade in the country’s history. Some of this prosperity was illusory—itself the result of subsequent Fed inflation—but nonetheless the 1920–1921 depression “purged the rottenness out of the system” and provided a solid framework for sustainable growth.

    As we know, things turned out decidedly differently in the 1930s. Despite the easy fiscal and monetary policies of the Hoover administration and the Federal Reserve—which today’s experts say are necessary to avoid the “mistakes of the Great Depression”—the unemployment rate kept going higher and higher, averaging an astounding 25 percent in 1933. And of course, after the “great contraction” the U.S. proceeded to stagnate in the Great Depression of the 1930s, which was easily the least prosperous decade in the country’s history.

    The conclusion seems obvious to anyone whose mind is not firmly locked into the Keynesian or monetarist framework: The free market works. Even in the face of massive shocks requiring large structural adjustments, the best thing the government can do is cut its own budget and return more resources to the private sector. For its part, the Federal Reserve doesn’t help matters by flooding the shell-shocked credit markets with green pieces of paper. Prices can adjust to clear labor and other markets soon enough, in light of the new fundamentals, if only the politicians and central bankers would get out of the way.

    Reply
  •  Generalfeldmarschall Von Hindenburg says:

    January 9, 2013 at 1:21 pm

    An important and oft overlooked question that comes to the fore in this discussion is, ‘how is it that a totalitarian system that’s run by an elite group characterized by inherited, privately held wealth is somehow less a tyranny than one run by petite bourgeois or pseudo intellectuals in the name of ‘the masses’, or ‘the volk’?
    It seems that The Austrians felt miffed that their country missed out on the glories of liberal capitalism experienced in the west and simply went from rickety agrarian relic of the Metternich era to part of the Greater German Reich.
    Also, while the NSDAP meddled with the conduct of business in many ways that liberal Britains government could or would not, you have only to look at German newspapers and magazines from the Hitler era to see that private enterprise was very much alive and thriving.

    Reply
  •  Eric Zuesse says:

    January 9, 2013 at 1:50 pm

    I intend to do a book about the origins of libertarianism, and already my research leads me toward a much more sinister picture than Pilkington seems to be describing (though the sample chapter does also cover von Hayek, and not much like Pilkington does). I am seeking feedback on the book proposal with sample chapter. Anyone who is interested in possibly provideng input on it can reach me at [email protected] and I shall be happy to send it to you in the body of an email, for your feedback.

    Reply
  •  Eric Zuesse says:

    January 9, 2013 at 1:52 pm

    Pardon, that email address is [email protected].

    Reply
  •  ebear says:

    January 9, 2013 at 4:01 pm

    Slug it out boys!

    (This site gets funnier with each passing day)

    http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=GTQnarzmTOc&NR=1&feature=fvwp

    Reply
  •  Jim says:

    January 9, 2013 at 4:10 pm

    Hayek in his thinking probably knew very well that his preference for a system of particular values, in his case a market order, cannot be logically grounded. This is why he conceals his choice behind evolutionary considerations which confer upon his reasoning an air of objectivity.

    I would submit that all of us, in our economic/political thinking (whether it be the doctrine of market liberalism, socialism, capitalism, MMT, MMR or heterodox Keynesianism) tend to conceal our choice for a system of particular values behind some type reasoning that attempts to create an air of objectivity.

    The issue which must be faced by all ideologies, including my own, is that there is always a choice on where to conceptually cut one’s focus in order to situate a problem to begin with and this suggests that the language of problem identification is metaphorical—it does not transparently reflect a situation that exists independent of our formulation.

    What this means, especially for such schools of thinking like market liberalism, MMT or even MMR is that there is an inescapable normative dimension to every descriptive formulation

    There is no purely descriptive reading of any situation or event–if we dare to look closely enough at the role of conceptualization and categorization in our thinking.

    Reply
  •  Paul Kostel says:

    January 9, 2013 at 4:11 pm

    The one issue left out of most economic discussions is human psychology which along with history explains economics better than any theory.
    Central planning, no matter what the label, avoids accepting feedback because the planners are always right.
    A free market is always dangerous to an empire because it requires rule of law, and the emperor never accepts restraints on his/her power.
    Our US empire started to go down this path with the election of 1912: Creation of Federal Reserve (not Federal and never had any reserves); Income taxes (The US Gov’t supported itself with duties and tariffs. Income tax was supposed to be a tax on the “rentier” class that Adam Smith said made money while sleeping); US no longer avoided foreign entanglements but became involved in a European war (All previous presidents had listened to George Washington’s warning to “avoid foreign entanglements); Before the Federal Reserve US $ was not fiat currency and was a means to store wealth.
    Does this article suggest that Central Planning actually works, that now central planners are no longer connected to some special interest group and in general “This time is different”? This time is NEVER different and the phrase is a bad answer created to releive cognitive dissonance.
    The world needs a resource based system that is not based on continuous growth. Money could be tied to grain which cannot increase exponentially like interest.
    Anselm Meyer Rothschild said “Give control over issuing a nations currency and I care not who makes the laws”. This sums up the result of creating the Federal Reserve, a private bank that issues our currency as a debt.
    Does anyone know if this member of the Rothschild banking empire said this in secret or was this said publicly as a warning.

    Reply
  •  digi_owl says:

    January 9, 2013 at 4:30 pm

    It seems that neoliberalism has bastardized the old republican (As in French republic, not US Republican party!) idea of freedom from coercion, be it economic or force, via the protection of a strong state, into freedom from interference.

    The real insanity comes in that the interference they focus on is that of government regulation. Regulation often in place because of the older notion of freedom from coercion. Never mind that in this day and age, corporations have as much a power to interfere. But supposedly you can just walk away from that interference by choosing to not commercially interact with said corporations. Err, yea right…

    Reply
  •  Hugh says:

    January 9, 2013 at 5:16 pm

    Discussing free markets is a snipe hunt. There has never been nor will there ever be a free market. It is always about who controls the market and for whose benefit. The reason why this sort of terminology is attractive to the rich and elites (our kleptocratic classes) is that it allows them to minimize or remove completely the idea of the social good. Such excision does not create a free market. It merely allows them greater latitude in their looting.

    This is not to say that the rich and elites do not invoke the social good when it suits their purposes. As Niebuhr observed a long time ago, they simply substitute their good for the social good. Their good becomes the social good. Do they really believe this? Of course, they do because it is so useful, convenient, and profitable for them to.

    Reply
  •  Tom c says:

    January 9, 2013 at 5:48 pm

    What a miserable bunch…(the central planning type)

    Reply
  •  Ms G says:

    January 9, 2013 at 9:08 pm

    Though not covered in this scholarly article about delusions in Hayek’s economics,
    the first thing that jumped into my mind when I read “Hayek’s Delusion” was the mind-boggling truth about Hayek and Medicare. That’s the story about how Hayek initially declined Koch’s invitation to emigrate from Austria to the US to become a “distinguished scholar” for Koch’s “Humane Society Institute” (my paraphrase) because he’d had gallbladder surgery in Austria (which had full-on single payer fabulous health care) and was concerned about the costs of private health insurance in the US. Koch then tipped him off to the wonders of Social Security and Medicare … and voila, the great New Deal program caused Hayek to change his mind and come to the US after all (to preach the wonders of “laissez faire”, of course.)

    When a fellow, scholar or not, embodies such shocking cognitive dissonance (actually, hypocrisy) in his real life, how can anything he thinks, writes or says about any subject (other than himself) be considered in the least bit legitimate?

    From the Nation: http://www.thenation.com/article/163672/charles-koch-friedrich-hayek-use-social-security

    And also previously noted here at NC: http://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2011/09/friedrich-hayek-joins-ayn-rand-as-a-hypocritical-user-of-medicare.html

    Here’s excerpts from the Nation article — they were just too good not to post:

    “Hayek initially declined Koch’s offer [to come to the US as a Koch-funded scholar on Austrian economics]. In a letter to IHS secretary Kenneth Templeton Jr., dated June 16, 1973, Hayek explains that he underwent gall bladder surgery in Austria earlier that year, which only heightened his fear of “the problems (and costs) of falling ill away from home.” (Thanks to waves of progressive reforms, postwar Austria had near universal healthcare and robust social insurance plans that Hayek would have been eligible for.)

    IHS vice president George Pearson (who later became a top Koch Industries executive) responded three weeks later, conceding that it was all but impossible to arrange affordable private medical insurance for Hayek in the United States. However, thanks to research by Yale Brozen, a libertarian economist at the University of Chicago, Pearson happily reported that “social security was passed at the University of Chicago while you [Hayek] were there in 1951. You had an option of being in the program. If you so elected at that time, you may be entitled to coverage now.”

    A few weeks later, the institute reported the good news: Professor Hayek had indeed opted into Social Security while he was teaching at Chicago and had paid into the program for ten years. He was eligible for benefits. On August 10, 1973, Koch wrote a letter appealing to Hayek to accept a shorter stay at the IHS, hard-selling Hayek on Social Security’s retirement benefits, which Koch encouraged Hayek to draw on even outside America. He also assured Hayek that Medicare, which had been created in 1965 by the Social Security amendments as part of Lyndon Johnson’s Great Society programs, would cover his medical needs.

    Koch writes: “You may be interested in the information that we uncovered on the insurance and other benefits that would be available to you in this country. Since you have paid into the United States Social Security Program for a full forty quarters, you are entitled to Social Security payments while living anywhere in the Free World. Also, at any time you are in the United States, you are automatically entitled to hospital coverage.”

    Reply
  •  Cyrus Rex says:

    January 9, 2013 at 9:28 pm

    It took far too long in this thread of comments for this truth to rise to the surface. The whole concept of “free markets” has been pushed to benefit those in control of the mechanisms of society. The method for controlling the mechanisms of society always and everywhere involve the use of government. As said, markets, at least in the sense which we know them, cannot exist in the absence of government regulation — without it they are inherently self-eviscerating in that they will always eat their young and then themselves.

    This, however, is not an argument for libertarianism since if it could exist at all, it would always evolve almost at once into some form of totalitarianism. These is no such thing as “doctrinaire freedom” and that is what libertarianism proposes as its model of society. Total personal freedom is nothing more than anarchy — another utopian concept.

    Reply
  •  bh2 says:

    January 9, 2013 at 10:40 pm

    Ah, yes, the “science” of economics. Less competent than astrology as a predictive tool, but perhaps marginally more competent than phrenology.

    Reply
  •  nothing but the truth says:

    January 9, 2013 at 10:48 pm

    the reason why hayek/mises/”austrians” is not that they are correct – rather they are clearly able to show the economics establishment emperor has no clothes.

    also the deductive approach to economics by the austrians is far more intuitively appealing than unnecessary but sufficient math on mainstream economics where math is used to confuse and deceive rather than to enlighten.

    austrians show clearly that economics is humanities, not some engineering or physics type of discipline.

    since (macro) economics is primarily about public policy it is inseparable from politics, and that is why (convenient) monetary economists are darlings of the establishment. they provide (math based) cover for deception in the political economy.

    i would venture so far to say that after keynes there has been no futher advancement in economics. to understand economics is to understand classical political economy, and that the last practitioner of that was keynes… what we have now are political hacks who can spin some math based lies.

    Reply
  •  steve from virginia says:

    January 9, 2013 at 11:16 pm

    Sorry kids, I’m sick as a dog … my balloon head spews foul-smelling greenish slime instead of entertaining word-play.

    I hope to be feeling better next week … In the meantime I’m reading Keynes’ “Economic Consequences of Peace”, where he relates his time in Paris after World War One and the (insufficient, short-sighted) efforts that led to the Treaty of Versailles.

    http://www.gutenberg.org/files/15776/15776-h/15776-h.htm

    I read it once a long time ago, of all Keynes’ work it is the most accessible, has the least ‘economic jargon’ to it. Keynes is horrified by the politicians, particularly Clemenceau and Wilson.

    Believe it or not, many of the resource/population/real-capital/real-output issues we discuss here (and avoid discussing elsewhere) are Keynes’ peripheral subject. He wasn’t ‘rigorous’ in the sense of MIT/Club of Rome and their ‘Limits to Growth’ but the seed was there. He was observing the period of massive economic (and population) growth that occurred during the last of the 19th century and the beginning of the 20th.

    I wanted to read it after making my way through Philip Pilkingon’s (well-deserved) hit job on hack-ish Friedrich Hayek. For some reason, reading about Hayek pushed me to read Keynes instead … and take note of his ‘sensible humanity’ …

    Institutionalized cruelty is both the foundation of modernity and our fatal flaw.

    Reply
  •  TiPs says:

    January 10, 2013 at 8:34 am

    Given your trashing of The Road to Serfdom, I’m curious as to why Keynes would then say he was in complete agreement with it?

    Reply  

    Read more at http://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2013/01/philip-pilkington-the-origins-of-neoliberalism-part-i-hayeks-delusion.html#fqLdRJcVuxRcC1S5.99



  • Etc

    Society

    Groupthink : Two Party System as Polyarchy : Corruption of Regulators : Bureaucracies : Understanding Micromanagers and Control Freaks : Toxic Managers :   Harvard Mafia : Diplomatic Communication : Surviving a Bad Performance Review : Insufficient Retirement Funds as Immanent Problem of Neoliberal Regime : PseudoScience : Who Rules America : Neoliberalism  : The Iron Law of Oligarchy : Libertarian Philosophy

    Quotes

    War and Peace : Skeptical Finance : John Kenneth Galbraith :Talleyrand : Oscar Wilde : Otto Von Bismarck : Keynes : George Carlin : Skeptics : Propaganda  : SE quotes : Language Design and Programming Quotes : Random IT-related quotesSomerset Maugham : Marcus Aurelius : Kurt Vonnegut : Eric Hoffer : Winston Churchill : Napoleon Bonaparte : Ambrose BierceBernard Shaw : Mark Twain Quotes

    Bulletin:

    Vol 25, No.12 (December, 2013) Rational Fools vs. Efficient Crooks The efficient markets hypothesis : Political Skeptic Bulletin, 2013 : Unemployment Bulletin, 2010 :  Vol 23, No.10 (October, 2011) An observation about corporate security departments : Slightly Skeptical Euromaydan Chronicles, June 2014 : Greenspan legacy bulletin, 2008 : Vol 25, No.10 (October, 2013) Cryptolocker Trojan (Win32/Crilock.A) : Vol 25, No.08 (August, 2013) Cloud providers as intelligence collection hubs : Financial Humor Bulletin, 2010 : Inequality Bulletin, 2009 : Financial Humor Bulletin, 2008 : Copyleft Problems Bulletin, 2004 : Financial Humor Bulletin, 2011 : Energy Bulletin, 2010 : Malware Protection Bulletin, 2010 : Vol 26, No.1 (January, 2013) Object-Oriented Cult : Political Skeptic Bulletin, 2011 : Vol 23, No.11 (November, 2011) Softpanorama classification of sysadmin horror stories : Vol 25, No.05 (May, 2013) Corporate bullshit as a communication method  : Vol 25, No.06 (June, 2013) A Note on the Relationship of Brooks Law and Conway Law

    History:

    Fifty glorious years (1950-2000): the triumph of the US computer engineering : Donald Knuth : TAoCP and its Influence of Computer Science : Richard Stallman : Linus Torvalds  : Larry Wall  : John K. Ousterhout : CTSS : Multix OS Unix History : Unix shell history : VI editor : History of pipes concept : Solaris : MS DOSProgramming Languages History : PL/1 : Simula 67 : C : History of GCC developmentScripting Languages : Perl history   : OS History : Mail : DNS : SSH : CPU Instruction Sets : SPARC systems 1987-2006 : Norton Commander : Norton Utilities : Norton Ghost : Frontpage history : Malware Defense History : GNU Screen : OSS early history

    Classic books:

    The Peter Principle : Parkinson Law : 1984 : The Mythical Man-MonthHow to Solve It by George Polya : The Art of Computer Programming : The Elements of Programming Style : The Unix Hater’s Handbook : The Jargon file : The True Believer : Programming Pearls : The Good Soldier Svejk : The Power Elite

    Most popular humor pages:

    Manifest of the Softpanorama IT Slacker Society : Ten Commandments of the IT Slackers Society : Computer Humor Collection : BSD Logo Story : The Cuckoo's Egg : IT Slang : C++ Humor : ARE YOU A BBS ADDICT? : The Perl Purity Test : Object oriented programmers of all nations : Financial Humor : Financial Humor Bulletin, 2008 : Financial Humor Bulletin, 2010 : The Most Comprehensive Collection of Editor-related Humor : Programming Language Humor : Goldman Sachs related humor : Greenspan humor : C Humor : Scripting Humor : Real Programmers Humor : Web Humor : GPL-related Humor : OFM Humor : Politically Incorrect Humor : IDS Humor : "Linux Sucks" Humor : Russian Musical Humor : Best Russian Programmer Humor : Microsoft plans to buy Catholic Church : Richard Stallman Related Humor : Admin Humor : Perl-related Humor : Linus Torvalds Related humor : PseudoScience Related Humor : Networking Humor : Shell Humor : Financial Humor Bulletin, 2011 : Financial Humor Bulletin, 2012 : Financial Humor Bulletin, 2013 : Java Humor : Software Engineering Humor : Sun Solaris Related Humor : Education Humor : IBM Humor : Assembler-related Humor : VIM Humor : Computer Viruses Humor : Bright tomorrow is rescheduled to a day after tomorrow : Classic Computer Humor

    The Last but not Least Technology is dominated by two types of people: those who understand what they do not manage and those who manage what they do not understand ~Archibald Putt. Ph.D


    Copyright © 1996-2021 by Softpanorama Society. www.softpanorama.org was initially created as a service to the (now defunct) UN Sustainable Development Networking Programme (SDNP) without any remuneration. This document is an industrial compilation designed and created exclusively for educational use and is distributed under the Softpanorama Content License. Original materials copyright belong to respective owners. Quotes are made for educational purposes only in compliance with the fair use doctrine.

    FAIR USE NOTICE This site contains copyrighted material the use of which has not always been specifically authorized by the copyright owner. We are making such material available to advance understanding of computer science, IT technology, economic, scientific, and social issues. We believe this constitutes a 'fair use' of any such copyrighted material as provided by section 107 of the US Copyright Law according to which such material can be distributed without profit exclusively for research and educational purposes.

    This is a Spartan WHYFF (We Help You For Free) site written by people for whom English is not a native language. Grammar and spelling errors should be expected. The site contain some broken links as it develops like a living tree...

    You can use PayPal to to buy a cup of coffee for authors of this site

    Disclaimer:

    The statements, views and opinions presented on this web page are those of the author (or referenced source) and are not endorsed by, nor do they necessarily reflect, the opinions of the Softpanorama society. We do not warrant the correctness of the information provided or its fitness for any purpose. The site uses AdSense so you need to be aware of Google privacy policy. You you do not want to be tracked by Google please disable Javascript for this site. This site is perfectly usable without Javascript.

    Last modified: March, 18, 2019