Softpanorama

May the source be with you, but remember the KISS principle ;-)
Home Switchboard Unix Administration Red Hat TCP/IP Networks Neoliberalism Toxic Managers
(slightly skeptical) Educational society promoting "Back to basics" movement against IT overcomplexity and  bastardization of classic Unix

Mathiness -- Mathematical Masturbations in Economics

Are axioms and equations the last refuge of a scoundrels in economics?

News Short Introduction to Lysenkoism Recommended Links Economism and abuse of economic theory in American politics Number racket Phillips curve NAIRU
Supply Side or Trickle down economics Invisible Hand Hypothesys Efficient Market Hypothesis Lawrence Summers Financial Sector Induced Systemic Instability of Economy Corruption of Regulators Greenspan as the Chairman of Financial Politburo
Libertarian Philosophy Elite [Dominance] Theory And the Revolt of the Elite The Iron Law of Oligarchy Audacious Oligarchy and "Democracy for Winners" Ayn Rand and her Objectivism Cult Neoliberal Brainwashing -- Journalism in the Service of the Powerful Few Monetarism fiasco
Free Market Fundamentalism Friedman --founder of Chicago school of deification of market Lawrence Summers Corruption of Regulators Glass-Steagall repeal Rational expectations scam Free Markets Newspeak
In Goldman Sachs we trust: classic example of regulatory capture by financial system hackers Groupthink GDP as a false measure of a country economic output Introduction to Lysenkoism Republican Economic Policy Think Tanks Enablers  Small government smoke screen
Hyman Minsky John Kenneth Galbraith Philippics Dumbing down america  Cargo cult programming Humor Etc

All economic theories that excessively abuse mathematic apparatus belong to the class of  a common perversion that can be defined as  the search for a superior justification for selfishness

See also Boulding's critical review of Samuelson, discussing the limits of the mathematicization of economic theory. Of course Samuelson was the tip of the iceberg, and since then many overconfident economic mathematicians have led to very serious financial problems. I had one stats professor who called a complex theory on the blackboard "graffiti."

Mathiness is perfect tool for obfiscating facts and real goals. In the world of for-profit finance, the return to obfuscation in communication with regulators is much higher, so there is every reason to expect that mathiness would be used liberally, particularly in mandated disclosure.

Of course this is not limited to economics and Richard Feynman described similar phenomenon long ago.

http://neurotheory.columbia.edu/~ken/cargo_cult.html

Cargo Cult Science
By Richard Feynman

In the South Seas there is a cargo cult of people. During the war they saw airplanes with lots of good materials, and they want the same thing to happen now. So they've arranged to make things like runways, to put fires along the sides of the runways, to make a wooden hut for a man to sit in, with two wooden pieces on his head to headphones and bars of bamboo sticking out like antennas--he's the controller--and they wait for the airplanes to land. They're doing everything right. The form is perfect. It looks exactly the way it looked before. But it doesn't work. No airplanes land. So I call these things cargo cult science, because they follow all the apparent precepts and forms of scientific investigation, but they're missing something essential, because the planes don't land.

Now it behooves me, of course, to tell you what they're missing. But it would be just about as difficult to explain to the South Sea islanders how they have to arrange things so that they get some wealth in their system. It is not something simple like telling them how to improve the shapes of the earphones. But there is one feature I notice that is generally missing in cargo cult science. That is the idea that we all hope you have learned in studying science in school--we never say explicitly what this is, but just hope that you catch on by all the examples of scientific investigation. It is interesting, therefore, to bring it out now and speak of it explicitly. It's a kind of scientific integrity, a principle of scientific thought that corresponds to a kind of utter honesty--a kind of leaning over backwards. For example, if you're doing an experiment, you should report everything that you think might make it invalid--not only what you think is right about it: other causes that could possibly explain your results; and things you thought of that you've eliminated by some other experiment, and how they worked--to make sure the other fellow can tell they have been eliminated.

Details that could throw doubt on your interpretation must be given, if you know them. You must do the best you can--if you know anything at all wrong, or possibly wrong--to explain it. If you make a theory, for example, and advertise it, or put it out, then you must also put down all the facts that disagree with it, as well as those that agree with it. There is also a more subtle problem. When you have put a lot of ideas together to make an elaborate theory, you want to make sure, when explaining what it fits, that those things it fits are not just the things that gave you the idea for the theory; but that the finished theory makes something else come out right, in addition.

In summary, the idea is to give all of the information to help others to judge the value of your contribution; not just the information that leads to judgment in one particular direction or another....


Top Visited
Switchboard
Latest
Past week
Past month

NEWS CONTENTS

Old News ;-)

[Sep 15, 2019] Thomas Piketty's New Book Brings Political Economy Back to Its Sources

Sep 15, 2019 | economistsview.typepad.com

anne , September 13, 2019 at 06:38 PM

https://promarket.org/thomas-piketty-new-book-brings-political-economy-back-to-its-sources/

September 6, 2019

Thomas Piketty's New Book Brings Political Economy Back to Its Sources
In the same way that Capital in the Twenty-First Century transformed the way economists look at inequality, Piketty's new book Capital and Ideology will transform the way political scientists look at their own field.
By Branko Milanovic

Thomas Piketty's books are always monumental. Some are more monumental than others. His Top Incomes in France in the Twentieth Century: Inequality and Redistribution, 1901–1998 (published in French as Les hauts revenus en France au XXe siècle) covered more than two centuries of income and wealth inequality, in addition to social and political changes in France. His international bestseller Capital in the Twenty-First Century (Le capital au XXI siècle) broadened this approach to the most important Western countries (France, the United States, United Kingdom, and Germany). His new book Capital and Ideology (to be published in English in March 2020; already published in France as Capital et idéologie) broadens the scope even further, covering the entire world and presenting a historical panorama of how ownership of assets (including people) was treated, and justified, in various historical societies, from China, Japan, and India, to the European-ruled American colonies, and feudal and capitalist societies in Europe. Just the mention of the geographical and temporal scope of the book suffices to give the reader an idea of its ambition.

Before I review Capital and Ideology, it is worth mentioning the importance of Piketty's overall approach, present in all three of his books. His approach is characterized by the methodological return of economics to its original and key functions: to be a science that illuminates the interests and explains the behaviors of individuals and social classes in their quotidian (material) life. This methodology rejects the dominant paradigm of the past half-century, which increasingly ignored the role of classes and heterogeneous individuals in the process of production and instead treated all people as abstract agents that maximize their own income under certain constraints. The dominant paradigm has emptied almost all social content from economics and presented a view of society that was as abstract as it was false.

The reintroduction of actual life into economics by Piketty and several other economists (not entirely coincidentally, most of them are economists interested in inequality) is much more than just a return to the sources of political economy and economics. This is because today, we have vastly more information (data) than was available to economists a century ago, not only about our own contemporary societies but also about past societies. This combination between political economy's original methodology and big data is what I call "turbo-Annales," after the French group of historians that pioneered the view of history as a social science focusing on the broad social, economic, and political forces that shape the world. The topics that interested classical political economy and the authors associated with the Annales School can now be studied empirically, and even econometrically and experimentally -- things which they could not do, both because of the scarcity of data and unavailability of modern methodologies.

It is within this context that, I believe, we ought to consider Piketty's Capital and Ideology. How successful was his approach, applied now to the world and over a very long time-horizon?

"The dominant paradigm has emptied almost all social content from economics and presented a view of society that was as abstract as it was false."

For the purposes of this review, I divide Piketty's book into two parts: the first, which I already mentioned, looks at ideological justifications of inequality across different societies (Parts 1 and 2 of the book, and to some extent Part 3); the second introduces an entirely new way of studying recent political cleavages in modern societies (Part 4). I am somewhat skeptical about Piketty's success in the first part, despite his enormous erudition and his skills as a raconteur, because success in discussing something so geographically and temporally immense is difficult to reach, even by the best-informed minds who have studied different societies for the majority of their careers. Analyzing each of these societies requires an extraordinarily high degree of sophisticated historical knowledge regarding religious dogmas, political organization, social stratification, and the like. To take two examples of authors who have tried to do it, one older and one more recent: Max Weber, during his entire life (and more specifically in Economy and Society), and Francis Fukuyama in his two-volume masterpiece on the origins of the political and economic order. In both cases, the results were not always unanimously approved by specialists studying individual societies and religions.

In his analysis of some of these societies, Piketty had to rely on somewhat "straightforward" or simplified discussions of their structure and evolution, discussions which at times seem plausible but superficial. In other words, each of these historical societies, many of which lasted centuries, had gone through different phases in their developments, phases which are subject to various interpretations. Treating such evolutions as if they were a simple, uncontested story is reductionist. It is a choice of one plausible historical narrative where many exist. This compares unfavorably with Piketty's own rich and nuanced narrative in Top Incomes in France in the Twentieth Century.

While I am somewhat skeptical about that first part of the book, I am not skeptical about the second. In this part, we find the Piketty who plays to his strength: bold and innovative use of data which produces a new way of looking at phenomena that we all observe but were unable to define so precisely. Here, Piketty is "playing" on the familiar Western economic history "terrain" that he knows well, probably better than any other economist.

This part of the book looks empirically at the reasons that left-wing, or social democratic parties have gradually transformed themselves from being the parties of the less-educated and poorer classes to become the parties of the educated and affluent middle and upper-middle classes. To a large extent, traditionally left parties have changed because their original social-democratic agenda was so successful in opening up education and high-income possibilities to the people who in the 1950s and 1960s came from modest backgrounds. These people, the "winners" of social democracy, continued voting for left-wing parties but their interests and worldview were no longer the same as that of their (less-educated) parents. The parties' internal social structure thus changed -- the product of their own political and social success. In Piketty's terms, they became the parties of the "Brahmin left" (La gauche Brahmane), as opposed to the conservative right-wing parties, which remained the parties of the "merchant right" (La droite marchande).

To simplify, the elite became divided between the educated "Brahmins" and the more commercially-minded "investors," or capitalists. This development, however, left the people who failed to experience upward educational and income mobility unrepresented, and those people are the ones that feed the current "populist" wave. Quite extraordinarily, Piketty shows the education and income shifts of left-wing parties' voters using very similar long-term data from all major developed democracies (and India). The fact that the story is so consistent across countries lends an almost uncanny plausibility to his hypothesis.

It is also striking, at least to me, that such multi-year, multi-country data were apparently never used by political scientists to study this phenomenon. This part of Piketty's book will likely transform, or at least affect, how political scientists look at new political realignments and class politics in advanced democracies in the years to come. In the same way that Capital in the Twenty-First Century has transformed how economists look at inequality, Capital and Ideology will transform the way political scientists look at their own field.


Branko Milanovic is a senior scholar at the Stone Center on Socio-Economic Inequality at the Graduate Center, City University of New York.

[Jun 19, 2019] Bias bias the inclination to accuse people of bias by James Thompson

Highly recommended!
Notable quotes:
"... Early in any psychology course, students are taught to be very cautious about accepting people's reports. A simple trick is to stage some sort of interruption to the lecture by confederates, and later ask the students to write down what they witnessed. Typically, they will misremember the events, sequences and even the number of people who staged the tableaux. Don't trust witnesses, is the message. ..."
"... The three assumptions -- lack of rationality, stubbornness, and costs -- imply that there is slim chance that people can ever learn or be educated out of their biases; ..."
"... So, are we as hopeless as some psychologists claim we are? In fact, probably not. Not all the initial claims have been substantiated. For example, it seems we are not as loss averse as previously claimed. Does our susceptibility to printed visual illusions show that we lack judgement in real life? ..."
"... Well the sad fact is that there's nobody in the position to protect "governments" from their own biases, and "scientists" from theirs ..."
"... Long ago a lawyer acquaintance, referring to a specific judge, told me that the judge seemed to "make shit up as he was going along". I have long held psychiatry fits that statement very well. ..."
"... Here we have a real scientist fighting the nonsense spreading from (neoclassical) economics into other realms of science/academia. ..."
"... Behavioral economics is a sideline by-product of neoclassical micro-economic theory. It tries to cope with experimental data that is inconsistent with that theory. ..."
"... Everything in neoclassical economics is a travesty. "Rational choice theory" and its application in "micro economics" is false from the ground up. It basically assumes that people are gobbling up resources without plan, meaning or relevant circumstances. Neoclassical micro economic theory is so false and illogical that I would not know where to start in a comment, so I should like to refer to a whole book about it: Keen, Steve: "Debunking economics". ..."
"... As the theory is totally wrong it is really not surprising that countless experiments show that people do not behave the way neoclassical theory predicts. How do economists react to this? Of course they assume that people are "irrational" because they do not behave according to their studied theory. (Why would you ever change your basic theory because of some tedious facts?) ..."
"... The title of the 1st ed. of Keen's book was "Debunking Economics: The Naked Emperor of the Social Sciences" which was simply a perfect title. ..."
Jun 19, 2019 | www.unz.com

Early in any psychology course, students are taught to be very cautious about accepting people's reports. A simple trick is to stage some sort of interruption to the lecture by confederates, and later ask the students to write down what they witnessed. Typically, they will misremember the events, sequences and even the number of people who staged the tableaux. Don't trust witnesses, is the message.

Another approach is to show visual illusions, such as getting estimates of line lengths in the Muller-Lyer illusion, or studying simple line lengths under social pressure, as in the Asch experiment, or trying to solve the Peter Wason logic problems, or the puzzles set by Kahneman and Tversky. All these appear to show severe limitations of human judgment. Psychology is full of cautionary tales about the foibles of common folk.

As a consequence of this softening up, psychology students come to regard themselves and most people as fallible, malleable, unreliable, biased and generally irrational. No wonder psychologists feel superior to the average citizen, since they understand human limitations and, with their superior training, hope to rise above such lowly superstitions.

However, society still functions, people overcome errors and many things work well most of the time. Have psychologists, for one reason or another, misunderstood people, and been too quick to assume that they are incapable of rational thought?

Gerd Gigerenzer thinks so.

https://www.nowpublishers.com/article/OpenAccessDownload/RBE-0092

He is particularly interested in the economic consequences of apparent irrationality, and whether our presumed biases really result in us making bad economic decisions. If so, some argue we need a benign force, say a government, to protect us from our lack of capacity. Perhaps we need a tattoo on our forehead: Diminished Responsibility.

The argument leading from cognitive biases to governmental paternalism -- in short, the irrationality argument -- consists of three assumptions and one conclusion:

1. Lack of rationality. Experiments have shown that people's intuitions are systematically biased.

2. Stubbornness. Like visual illusions, biases are persistent and hardly corrigible by education.

3. Substantial costs. Biases may incur substantial welfare-relevant costs such as lower wealth, health, or happiness.

4. Biases justify governmental paternalism. To protect people from theirbiases, governments should "nudge" the public toward better behavior.

The three assumptions -- lack of rationality, stubbornness, and costs -- imply that there is slim chance that people can ever learn or be educated out of their biases; instead governments need to step in with a policy called libertarian paternalism (Thaler and Sunstein, 2003).

So, are we as hopeless as some psychologists claim we are? In fact, probably not. Not all the initial claims have been substantiated. For example, it seems we are not as loss averse as previously claimed. Does our susceptibility to printed visual illusions show that we lack judgement in real life?

In Shepard's (1990) words, "to fool a visual system that has a full binocular and freely mobile view of a well-illuminated scene is next to impossible" (p. 122). Thus, in psychology, the visual system is seen more as a genius than a fool in making intelligent inferences, and inferences, after all, are necessary for making sense of the images on the retina.

Most crucially, can people make probability judgements? Let us see. Try solving this one:

A disease has a base rate of .1, and a test is performed that has a hit rate of .9 (the conditional probability of a positive test given disease) and a false positive rate of .1 (the conditional probability of a positive test given no disease). What is the probability that a random person with a positive test result actually has the disease?

Most people fail this test, including 79% of gynaecologists giving breast screening tests. Some researchers have drawn the conclusion that people are fundamentally unable to deal with conditional probabilities. On the contrary, there is a way of laying out the problem such that most people have no difficulty with it. Watch what it looks like when presented as natural frequencies:

Among every 100 people, 10 are expected to have a disease. Among those 10, nine are expected to correctly test positive. Among the 90 people without the disease, nine are expected to falsely test positive. What proportion of those who test positive actually have the disease?

In this format the positive test result gives us 9 people with the disease and 9 people without the disease, so the chance that a positive test result shows a real disease is 50/50. Only 13% of gynaecologists fail this presentation.

Summing up the virtues of natural frequencies, Gigerenzer says:

When college students were given a 2-hour course in natural frequencies, the number of correct Bayesian inferences increased from 10% to 90%; most important, this 90% rate was maintained 3 months after training (Sedlmeier and Gigerenzer, 2001). Meta-analyses have also documented the "de-biasing" effect, and natural frequencies are now a technical term in evidence-based medicine (Akiet al., 2011; McDowell and Jacobs, 2017). These results are consistent with a long literature on techniques for successfully teaching statistical reasoning (e.g., Fonget al., 1986). In sum, humans can learn Bayesian inference quickly if the information is presented in natural frequencies.

If the problem is set out in a simple format, almost all of us can all do conditional probabilities.

I taught my medical students about the base rate screening problem in the late 1970s, based on: Robyn Dawes (1962) "A note on base rates and psychometric efficiency". Decades later, alarmed by the positive scan detection of an unexplained mass, I confided my fears to a psychiatrist friend. He did a quick differential diagnosis on bowel cancer, showing I had no relevant symptoms, and reminded me I had lectured him as a student on base rates decades before, so I ought to relax. Indeed, it was false positive.

Here are the relevant figures, set out in terms of natural frequencies

Every test has a false positive rate (every step is being taken to reduce these), and when screening is used for entire populations many patients have to undergo further investigations, sometimes including surgery.

Setting out frequencies in a logical sequence can often prevent misunderstandings. Say a man on trial for having murdered his spouse has previously physically abused her. Should his previous history of abuse not be raised in Court because only 1 woman in 2500 cases of abuse is murdered by her abuser? Of course, whatever a defence lawyer may argue and a Court may accept, this is back to front. OJ Simpson was not on trial for spousal abuse, but for the murder of his former partner. The relevant question is: what is the probability that a man murdered his partner, given that she has been murdered and that he previously battered her.

Accepting the figures used by the defence lawyer, if 1 in 2500 women are murdered every year by their abusive male partners, how many women are murdered by men who did not previously abuse them? Using government figures that 5 women in 100,000 are murdered every year then putting everything onto the same 100,000 population, the frequencies look like this:

So, 40 to 5, it is 8 times more probable that abused women are murdered by their abuser. A relevant issue to raise in Court about the past history of an accused man.

Are people's presumed biases costly, in the sense of making them vulnerable to exploitation, such that they can be turned into a money pump, or is it a case of "once bitten, twice shy"? In fact, there is no evidence that these apparently persistent logical errors actually result in people continually making costly errors. That presumption turns out to be a bias bias.

Gigerenzer goes on to show that people are in fact correct in their understanding of the randomness of short sequences of coin tosses, and Kahneman and Tversky wrong. Elegantly, he also shows that the "hot hand" of successful players in basketball is a real phenomenon, and not a stubborn illusion as claimed.

With equal elegance he disposes of a result I had depended upon since Slovic (1982), which is that people over-estimate the frequency of rare risks and under-estimate the frequency of common risks. This finding has led to the belief that people are no good at estimating risk. Who could doubt that a TV series about Chernobyl will lead citizens to have an exaggerated fear of nuclear power stations?

The original Slovic study was based on 39 college students, not exactly a fair sample of humanity. The conceit of psychologists knows no bounds. Gigerenzer looks at the data and shows that it is yet another example of regression to the mean. This is an apparent effect which arises whenever the predictor is less than perfect (the most common case), an unsystematic error effect, which is already evident when you calculate the correlation coefficient. Parental height and their children's heights are positively but not perfectly correlated at about r = 0.5. Predictions made in either direction will under-predict in either direction, simply because they are not perfect, and do not capture all the variation. Try drawing out the correlation as an ellipse to see the effect of regression, compared to the perfect case of the straight line of r= 1.0

What diminishes in the presence of noise is the variability of the estimates, both the estimates of the height of the sons based on that of their fathers, and vice versa. Regression toward the mean is a result of unsystematic, not systematic error (Stigler,1999).

Gigerenzer also looks at the supposed finding that people are over-confidence in predictions, and finds that it is another regression to the mean problem.

Gigerenzer then goes on to consider that old favourite, that most people think they are better than average, which supposedly cannot be the case, because average people are average.

Consider the finding that most drivers think they drive better than average. If better driving is interpreted as meaning fewer accidents, then most drivers' beliefs are actually true. The number of accidents per person has a skewed distribution, and an analysis of U.S. accident statistics showed that some 80% of drivers have fewer accidents than the average number of accidents (Mousavi and Gigerenzer, 2011)

Then he looks at the classical demonstration of framing, that is to say, the way people appear to be easily swayed by how the same facts are "framed" or presented to the person who has to make a decision.

A patient suffering from a serious heart disease considers high-risk surgery and asks a doctor about its prospects.

The doctor can frame the answer in two ways:

Positive Frame: Five years after surgery, 90% of patients are alive.
Negative Frame: Five years after surgery, 10% of patients are dead.

Should the patient listen to how the doctor frames the answer? Behavioral economists say no because both frames are logically equivalent (Kahneman, 2011). Nevertheless, people do listen. More are willing to agree to a medical procedure if the doctor uses positive framing (90% alive) than if negative framing is used (10% dead) (Moxeyet al., 2003). Framing effects challenge the assumption of stable preferences, leading to preference reversals. Thaler and Sunstein (2008) who presented the above surgery problem, concluded that "framing works because people tend to be somewhat mindless, passive decisionmakers" (p. 40)

Gigerenzer points out that in this particular example, subjects are having to make their judgements without knowing a key fact: how many survive without surgery. If you know that you have a datum which is more influential. These are the sorts of questions patients will often ask about, and discuss with other patients, or with several doctors. Furthermore, you don't have to spin a statistic. You could simply say: "Five years after surgery, 90% of patients are alive and 10% are dead".

Gigerenzer gives an explanation which is very relevant to current discussions about the meaning of intelligence, and about the power of intelligence tests:

In sum, the principle of logical equivalence or "description invariance" is a poor guide to understanding how human intelligence deals with an uncertain world where not everything is stated explicitly. It misses the very nature of intelligence, the ability to go beyond the information given (Bruner, 1973)

The key is to take uncertainty seriously, take heuristics seriously, and beware of the bias bias.

One important conclusion I draw from this entire paper is that the logical puzzles enjoyed by Kahneman, Tversky, Stanovich and others are rightly rejected by psychometricians as usually being poor indicators of real ability. They fail because they are designed to lead people up the garden path, and depend on idiosyncratic interpretations.

For more detail: http://www.unz.com/jthompson/the-tricky-question-of-rationality/

Critics of examinations of either intellectual ability or scholastic attainment are fond of claiming that the items are "arbitrary". Not really. Scholastic tests have to be close to the curriculum in question, but still need to a have question forms which are simple to understand so that the stress lies in how students formulate the answer, not in how they decipher the structure of the question.

Intellectual tests have to avoid particular curricula and restrict themselves to the common ground of what most people in a community understand. Questions have to be super-simple, so that the correct answer follows easily from the question, with minimal ambiguity. Furthermore, in the case of national scholastic tests, and particularly in the case of intelligence tests, legal authorities will pore over the test, looking at each item for suspected biases of a sexual, racial or socio-economic nature. Designing an intelligence test is a difficult and expensive matter. Many putative new tests of intelligence never even get to the legal hurdle, because they flounder on matters of reliability and validity, and reveal themselves to be little better than the current range of assessments.

In conclusion, both in psychology and behavioural economics, some researchers have probably been too keen to allege bias in cases where there are unsystematic errors, or no errors at all. The corrective is to learn about base rates, and to use natural frequencies as a guide to good decision-making.

Don't bother boosting your IQ. Boost your understanding of natural frequencies.


res , says: June 17, 2019 at 3:29 pm GMT

Good concrete advice. Perhaps even more useful for those who need to explain things like this to others than for those seeking to understand for themselves.
ThreeCranes , says: June 17, 2019 at 3:34 pm GMT
"intelligence deals with an uncertain world where not everything is stated explicitly. It misses the very nature of intelligence, the ability to go beyond the information given (Bruner, 1973)"

"The key is to take uncertainty seriously, take heuristics seriously, and beware of the bias bias."

Why I come to Unz.

Tom Welsh , says: June 18, 2019 at 8:36 am GMT
@Cortes Sounds fishy to me.

Actually I think this is an example of an increasingly common genre of malapropism, where the writer gropes for the right word, finds one that is similar, and settles for that. The worst of it is that readers intuitively understand what was intended, and then adopt the marginally incorrect usage themselves. That's perhaps how the world and his dog came to say "literally" when they mean "figuratively". Maybe a topic for a future article?

Biff , says: June 18, 2019 at 10:16 am GMT
In 2009 Google finished engineering a reverse search engine to find out what kind of searches people did most often. Seth Davidowitz and Steven Pinker wrote a very fascinating/entertaining book using the tool called Everybody Lies

https://www.goodreads.com/book/show/28512671-everybody-lies

Everybody Lies offers fascinating, surprising, and sometimes laugh-out-loud insights into everything from economics to ethics to sports to race to sex, gender, and more, all drawn from the world of big data. What percentage of white voters didn't vote for Barack Obama because he's black? Does where you go to school effect how successful you are in life? Do parents secretly favor boy children over girls? Do violent films affect the crime rate? Can you beat the stock market? How regularly do we lie about our sex lives, and who's more self-conscious about sex, men or women?

Investigating these questions and a host of others, Seth Stephens-Davidowitz offers revelations that can help us understand ourselves and our lives better. Drawing on studies and experiments on how we really live and think, he demonstrates in fascinating and often funny ways the extent to which all the world is indeed a lab. With conclusions ranging from strange-but-true to thought-provoking to disturbing, he explores the power of this digital truth serum and its deeper potential – revealing biases deeply embedded within us, information we can use to change our culture, and the questions we're afraid to ask that might be essential to our health – both emotional and physical. All of us are touched by big data every day, and its influence is multiplying. Everybody Lies challenges us to think differently about how we see it and the world.

dearieme , says: June 18, 2019 at 11:25 am GMT
I shall treat this posting (for which many thanks, doc) as an invitation to sing a much-loved song: everybody should read Gigerenzer's Reckoning with Risk. With great clarity it teaches what everyone ought to know about probability.

(It could also serve as a model for writing in English about technical subjects. Americans and Britons should study the English of this German – he knows how, you know.)

Inspired by "The original Slovic study was based on 39 college students" I shall also sing another favorite song. Much of Psychology is based on what small numbers of American undergraduates report they think they think.

Anon [410] • Disclaimer , says: June 18, 2019 at 3:47 pm GMT
" Gigerenzer points out that in this particular example, subjects are having to make their judgements without knowing a key fact: how many survive without surgery. "

This one reminds of the false dichotomy. The patient has additional options! Like changing diet, and behaviours such as exercise, elimination of occupational stress , etc.

The statistical outcomes for a person change when the person changes their circumstances/conditions.

Cortes , says: June 18, 2019 at 4:14 pm GMT
@Tom Welsh A disposition (conveyance) of an awkwardly shaped chunk out of a vast estate contained reference to "the slither of ground bounded on or towards the north east and extending two hundred and twenty four meters or thereby along a chain link fence " Not poor clients (either side) nor cheap lawyers. And who never erred?

Better than deliberately inserting "errors" to guarantee a stream of tidy up work (not unknown in the "professional" world) in future.

Tom Fix , says: June 18, 2019 at 4:25 pm GMT
Good article. 79% of gynaecologists fail a simple conditional probability test?! Many if not most medical research papers use advanced statistics. Medical doctors must read these papers to fully understand their field. So, if medical doctors don't fully understand them, they are not properly doing their job. Those papers use mathematical expressions, not English. Converting them to another form of English, instead of using the mathematical expressions isn't a solution.
SafeNow , says: June 18, 2019 at 5:49 pm GMT
Regarding witnesses: When that jet crashed into Rockaway several years ago, a high percentage of witnesses said that they saw smoke before the crash. But there was actually no smoke. The witnesses were adjusting what they saw to conform to their past experience of seeing movie and newsreel footage of planes smoking in the air before a crash. Children actually make very good witnesses.

Regarding the chart. Missing, up there in the vicinity of cancer and heart disease. The third-leading cause of death. 250,000 per year, according to a 2016 Hopkins study. Medical negligence.

Anon [724] • Disclaimer , says: June 18, 2019 at 9:48 pm GMT

1. Lack of rationality. Experiments have shown that people's intuitions are systematically biased.

2. Stubbornness. Like visual illusions, biases are persistent and hardly corrigible by education.

3. Substantial costs. Biases may incur substantial welfare-relevant costs such as lower wealth, health, or happiness.

4. Biases justify governmental paternalism. To protect people from theirbiases, governments should "nudge" the public toward better behavior.

Well the sad fact is that there's nobody in the position to protect "governments" from their own biases, and "scientists" from theirs.

So, behind the smoke of all words and rationalisations, the law is unchanged: everyone strives to gain and exert as much power as possible over as many others as possible. Most do that without writing papers to say it is right, others write papers, others books. Anyway, the fundamental law would stay as it is even if all this writing labour was spared, wouldn't it? But then another fundamental law, the law of framing all one's drives as moral and beneffective comes into play the papers and the books are useful, after all.

Curmudgeon , says: June 19, 2019 at 1:42 am GMT
An interesting article. However, I think that the only thing we have to know about how illogical psychiatry is this:

In 1973, the American Psychiatric Association (APA) asked all members attending its convention to vote on whether they believed homosexuality to be a mental disorder. 5,854 psychiatrists voted to remove homosexuality from the DSM, and 3,810 to retain it.

The APA then compromised, removing homosexuality from the DSM but replacing it, in effect, with "sexual orientation disturbance" for people "in conflict with" their sexual orientation. Not until 1987 did homosexuality completely fall out of the DSM.

(source https://www.psychologytoday.com/ca/blog/hide-and-seek/201509/when-homosexuality-stopped-being-mental-disorder )

The article makes no mention of the fact that no "new science" was brought to support the resolution.

It appears that the psychiatrists were voting based on feelings rather than science. Since that time, the now 50+ genders have been accepted as "normal" by the APA. My family has had members in multiple generations suffering from mental illness. None were "cured". I know others with the same circumstances.

How does one conclude that being repulsed by the prime directive of every living organism – reproduce yourself – is "normal"? That is not to say these people are horrible or evil, just not normal. How can someone, who thinks (s)he is a cat be mentally ill, but a grown man thinking he is a female child is not?

Long ago a lawyer acquaintance, referring to a specific judge, told me that the judge seemed to "make shit up as he was going along". I have long held psychiatry fits that statement very well.

Paul2 , says: June 19, 2019 at 8:08 am GMT
Thank you for this article. I find the information about the interpretation of statistical data very interesting. My take on the background of the article is this:

Here we have a real scientist fighting the nonsense spreading from (neoclassical) economics into other realms of science/academia.

Behavioral economics is a sideline by-product of neoclassical micro-economic theory. It tries to cope with experimental data that is inconsistent with that theory.

Everything in neoclassical economics is a travesty. "Rational choice theory" and its application in "micro economics" is false from the ground up. It basically assumes that people are gobbling up resources without plan, meaning or relevant circumstances. Neoclassical micro economic theory is so false and illogical that I would not know where to start in a comment, so I should like to refer to a whole book about it:
Keen, Steve: "Debunking economics".

As the theory is totally wrong it is really not surprising that countless experiments show that people do not behave the way neoclassical theory predicts. How do economists react to this? Of course they assume that people are "irrational" because they do not behave according to their studied theory. (Why would you ever change your basic theory because of some tedious facts?)

We live in a strange world in which such people have control over university faculties, journals, famous prizes. But at least we have some scientists who defend their area of knowledge against the spreading nonsense produced by economists.

The title of the 1st ed. of Keen's book was "Debunking Economics: The Naked Emperor of the Social Sciences" which was simply a perfect title.

Dieter Kief , says: June 19, 2019 at 8:22 am GMT
@Curmudgeon Could it be that you expect psychiatrists in the past to be as rational as you are now?

Would the result have been any different, if members of a 1973 convention of physicists or surgeons would have been asked?

[Apr 05, 2019] I felt mathematicians were not examining the role of their discipline in the crisis; they were not behaving ethically.

Apr 05, 2019 | magic-maths-money.blogspot.com
I frequently refer to Gillian Tett's Fools' Gold as an account of ethical mathematical practice. Tett explains how J.P. Morgan came out of the 2008-2009 Financial Crisis because it used mathematics critically rather than blindly accepting the outputs of "black boxes". I felt the approach Tett described was oddly discordant with the attitude of mathematicians. During the crisis, I co-ordinated a response from UK mathematicians, through the Council of Mathematical Sciences, to criticism of the use of mathematics in finance, this information was also passed onto the UK Science Minister of the time.

The standard response from (senior) UK mathematicians was along the lines that finance hadn't used mathematics but abused it.

The solution was to have "more" and "better" mathematicians. This was underpinned by some adopting a logical positivist line, attributed to Hume, that the role of mathematicians is to describe the world as it is, not as it ought to be.

At the time I felt mathematicians were not examining the role of their discipline in the crisis; they were not behaving ethically. This was the start of my journey that transformed me from an "uncritical" (unethical?) mathematician to someone who feels mathematics is vital, so long as it is critical.

[Feb 13, 2019] Mathiness and game thoery

Any good mathematical theory can be misapplied and perverted if there is social pressure and money to do so..
Feb 13, 2019 | www.alternet.org

Game Theory:

A glossary of exploitive economics 'Lean in' and 8 other bad business buzzwords that should be phased out – Alternet.org

The use of mathematics to model human reality; one of the more bizarre offshoots that followed the mathematization of economic thought in the 20th century.

Game theory focuses on strategies used by competing actors to make rational decisions. What should I do given my opponent may subsequently decide A, B, C, or D? It was pioneered by John von Neumann, John Nash, and Oskar Morgenstern. The assumption that social life is a game of logic between conniving actors is foundational to this view of economics. But do we really behave in such a "me versus you" manner?

Game Theory's rational individualism closely resonates with neoliberal capitalism because it reconceptualizes everyone as mini corporations who are totally selfish.

Individuals compete rather than share; seek to outsmart the next person rather than empathize. Proponents of the approach often use the "as if" defense. The model might not perfectly match reality, but we can approximate how someone behaves in the real world by assuming they act "as if" they're Nashian plotters.

It's the normative assumptions underlying this "as if" that are problematic that at bottom we're all greedy and impatient bankers. One could just as well argue that people act "as if" they're trusting and altruistic socialists, but Game Theory won't have any of that.

[Nov 29, 2017] Economics is a Belief System - and We are Ruled by Fundamentalists

Highly recommended!
Notable quotes:
"... During the two decades following the neoliberal economists' take-over of Western governments in the 1980s, many felt that the almost mystical terms of economics - such as derivatives, hedging, leverage, contangos, etc - were beyond the understanding of most ordinary people. ..."
"... They pursued them as a matter of faith in the market and its processes, despite the apparent warning signs of their imminent failure. ..."
"... as within many custom or belief systems, what economics enshrines is a social order. One where a dominant minority are able to take a small quantity of wealth from each member of the majority in order to maintain their higher status. ..."
"... idea of economics as an exploitative mechanism is echoed in the cover picture of the book, Bosch's The Conjurer ..."
"... Within its exposition of economics as a quasi-religious theory, Brian Davey's book helps us to understand why economic theory is driving us toward a global system failure - and why politics and economics are incapable of responding to the pressing ecological crisis which the pursuit of economic growth has spawned. ..."
Nov 09, 2015 | resilience.org

by Paul Mobbs, originally published by The Ecologist |

Brian Davey's new book, Credo: Economic Beliefs in a World in Crisis, is an analysis of economic theory as if it were a system of religious belief.

It's a timely book. The simplistic, perhaps 'supernatural' assumptions which underpin key parts of economic theory demand far more attention. It's a debate we've failed to have as a society.

... ... ...

During the two decades following the neoliberal economists' take-over of Western governments in the 1980s, many felt that the almost mystical terms of economics - such as derivatives, hedging, leverage, contangos, etc - were beyond the understanding of most ordinary people.

And without understanding those terms, irrespective of our gut feeling that there was something wrong, how could we challenge the political lobby those theories had put into power? In the end it took the financial crash of 2007/8 to demonstrate that those in charge of this system didn't understand the complexity and risk of those practices either.

They pursued them as a matter of faith in the market and its processes, despite the apparent warning signs of their imminent failure. Those outside 'orthodox' economics could already see where the economy was heading in the longer-term.

Question is, did economists learn anything from that failure? Or, through austerity, have they once again committed us to their dogmatic belief system, unchanged by that experience?

... ... ...

However, through simple hubris or optimism bias, the political class has been convinced that 'fracking' is a solution to our economic woes - even though there is a paucity of verifiable evidence to demonstrate those claims, and it has already lost billions of investors money.

Economics is a reflection of power

Ultimately though, as within many custom or belief systems, what economics enshrines is a social order. One where a dominant minority are able to take a small quantity of wealth from each member of the majority in order to maintain their higher status.

This idea of economics as an exploitative mechanism is echoed in the cover picture of the book, Bosch's The Conjurer - where a magician distracts the public with a sleight of hand trick so that they can be more easily robbed by his associate.

Again, in a world where we're hitting the limits to human material growth, political models of well-being based upon wealth and consumption are damaging to human society in the long-term. The evidence that we're heading for a longer-term failure is there, as was the case with the warning signs before the 2007 crash. The problem is that those in positions of power do not wish to see it.

... ... ...

Within its exposition of economics as a quasi-religious theory, Brian Davey's book helps us to understand why economic theory is driving us toward a global system failure - and why politics and economics are incapable of responding to the pressing ecological crisis which the pursuit of economic growth has spawned.

Contrary to the economic hubris of many world leaders, set alongside the reality of ecological limits humanity is not 'too big to fail'.

[Sep 18, 2017] Critical Realism: Mathematics versus Mythematics in Economics

Highly recommended!
Notable quotes:
"... I argue here that it's the abuse of mathematics by Neoclassical economists -- who practice what I have dubbed "Mythematics" rather than Mathematics--and that some phenomena are uncovered by mathematical logic that can't be discovered by verbal logic alone. ..."
"... A lady in the audi­ence named Barb Jacobson suggested that using the name Neo-Classical gives it a cer­tain degree of cache and wants you guys to start call­ing it for what it is: "Scorched Earth Economics." What a great name to use and doesn't it ring true? ..."
Oct 02, 2015 | www.debtdeflation.com

This is the brief talk I gave at a conference celebrating 25 years of the Critical Realist seminar series at Cambridge University. Critical realists argue against the use of mathematics in economics; I argue here that it's the abuse of mathematics by Neoclassical economists -- who practice what I have dubbed "Mythematics" rather than Mathematics--and that some phenomena are uncovered by mathematical logic that can't be discovered by verbal logic alone.

I give the example of my own model of Minsky's Financial Instability Hypothesis, which revealed the possibility of a "Great Moderation" preceding a "Great Recession" before either event had happened.

David Milburn, September 12, 2015 at 9:38 am

Steve,

Last week Prof Bill Mitchell was in London where he gave a talk on re-framing the language used in the media that carried on the myth of the main­stream groupthink. A lady in the audi­ence named Barb Jacobson suggested that using the name Neo-Classical gives it a cer­tain degree of cache and wants you guys to start call­ing it for what it is: "Scorched Earth Economics." What a great name to use and doesn't it ring true? Barb Jacobson is spot on!

Sue Madden, September 13, 2015 at 8:28 am

Hi Steve,
I was really amused to see an inter­view a while back in the New Sci­en­tist, with the "research chief" (!!) at the B of E. If you haven't seen it, you really must:

Opinion Interview with Andy Haldane: "Sackcloth and Ashes on Thread needle Street" New Scientist 25 March 2015

Corbyn was elected leader!!!! Now the sparks will fly. At least a pub­lic debate wor­thy of the name might at last be heard in our sad country.

Thanks for your work in trying to enlighten us!!
Sue.

[Jul 04, 2017] Critical Realism: Mathematics versus Mythematics in Economics

Notable quotes:
"... I argue here that it's the abuse of mathematics by Neoclassical economists -- who practice what I have dubbed "Mythematics" rather than Mathematics--and that some phenomena are uncovered by mathematical logic that can't be discovered by verbal logic alone. ..."
"... A lady in the audi­ence named Barb Jacobson suggested that using the name Neo-Classical gives it a cer­tain degree of cache and wants you guys to start call­ing it for what it is: "Scorched Earth Economics." What a great name to use and doesn't it ring true? ..."
Oct 02, 2015 | www.debtdeflation.com

This is the brief talk I gave at a conference celebrating 25 years of the Critical Realist seminar series at Cambridge University. Critical realists argue against the use of mathematics in economics; I argue here that it's the abuse of mathematics by Neoclassical economists -- who practice what I have dubbed "Mythematics" rather than Mathematics--and that some phenomena are uncovered by mathematical logic that can't be discovered by verbal logic alone.

I give the example of my own model of Minsky's Financial Instability Hypothesis, which revealed the possibility of a "Great Moderation" preceding a "Great Recession" before either event had happened.

David Milburn, September 12, 2015 at 9:38 am

Steve,

Last week Prof Bill Mitchell was in London where he gave a talk on re-framing the language used in the media that carried on the myth of the main­stream groupthink. A lady in the audi­ence named Barb Jacobson suggested that using the name Neo-Classical gives it a cer­tain degree of cache and wants you guys to start call­ing it for what it is: "Scorched Earth Economics." What a great name to use and doesn't it ring true? Barb Jacobson is spot on!

Sue Madden, September 13, 2015 at 8:28 am

Hi Steve,
I was really amused to see an inter­view a while back in the New Sci­en­tist, with the "research chief" (!!) at the B of E. If you haven't seen it, you really must:

Opinion Interview with Andy Haldane: "Sackcloth and Ashes on Thread needle Street" New Scientist 25 March 2015

Corbyn was elected leader!!!! Now the sparks will fly. At least a pub­lic debate wor­thy of the name might at last be heard in our sad country.

Thanks for your work in trying to enlighten us!!
Sue.

[Jul 04, 2017] We should reject masked by mathiness typical neoclassical junk that is mainstream now.

Notable quotes:
"... That is exactly what makes macro a pseudoscience (as Cassidy called it "Utopian economics".) You can't talk about economics ignoring existence of finance, because finance is an elephant in the room. A church of efficient stochastic equilibrium and an invisible hand that drives economics to it (the hand of God) is junk science, and always was. ..."
Mar 03, 2017 | economistsview.typepad.com
libezkova : March 02, 2017 at 07:14 PM , 2017 at 07:14 PM
"macro rightly got a lot of stick by largely ignoring the role of finance,"

That is exactly what makes macro a pseudoscience (as Cassidy called it "Utopian economics".) You can't talk about economics ignoring existence of finance, because finance is an elephant in the room. A church of efficient stochastic equilibrium and an invisible hand that drives economics to it (the hand of God) is junk science, and always was.

As much as I admire the mathematics, its use in macro is perverted and unscientific because it relies on unrealistic assumptions. Its all pure mathiness.

Most of terminology that neoclassical economy introduced smells "fraud" or at least is detached from reality. "Output gap" and related notion "potential output" can serve as an example. Look at WWII production. For example, even potential output of a single plant (let's say three shift work and full utilization of equipment) is pretty convoluted notion as there is a high level of dependence on suppliers and somewhere typically "bottleneck" exists that prevent the factory achieving this input. Still Hjalmar Schacht achieved wonders during WWII by just ordering German factories to continue producing without waiting for orders to come.

Also it looks like Simon Wren-Lewis equalizes Keynes with Paul Samuelson simplification (or perversion if you wish) of Keynes thoughts ( http://econ.bus.utk.edu/department/emeritus/samuelson'sarrogance100%20final.pdf )

== quote ==
Moreover, Keynes [1936, p. 177, 179] had denounced Walras's approach as wrong when he wrote "Now the analysis of the previous chapters [of The General Theory] made it plain that this account [in Walras] of the matter must be erroneous .this [Walrasian system] is a nonsense theory".
== end of quote ==

And even worse, like most neoliberal economists, he tends to ignore Hyman Minsky important contribution to understanding of source of instability in capitalist economics.

That fact alone IMHO makes his lectures junk science.

libezkova -> libezkova... , March 02, 2017 at 07:14 PM
I remember that during 2008 events somebody called Bernanke not a specialist on Great Depression, but a charlatan, who tried to explain Great Depression using neoclassic economics.

I think that was an apt definition.

Mr. Bill : , March 02, 2017 at 10:21 PM
"I acknowledge that macro rightly got a lot of stick by largely ignoring the role of finance, but I also point out that the poor recovery has involved a vindication of the core macro model: austerity is a bad idea at the ZLB, QE was not inflationary and interest rates on government debt did not rise but fell."

No shit Dick Tracy. Look at the devastation of the US of O (The United States of Oligarchy). Let's join the Military in defending the shipping lanes, 3 hots and a cot.

I'm glad the core macro-model has been vindicated.

Sanjait : , March 02, 2017 at 11:29 PM
Is it my imagination or are the crazies around here getting crazier, and becoming increasingly unable to even begin talking about macro in a serious way.

I mean, I don't mind a bit of vituperation or even limited amounts of incoherence and insanity, if it is accompanied by at least earnest attempts to have substantive discussions. But it just feels like the essential substance has become increasingly rare.

libezkova -> Sanjait... , -1
"Is it my imagination or are the crazies around here getting crazier, and becoming increasingly unable to even begin talking about macro in a serious way."

If you think that neoliberal economists and their low-level supporters like some members of this blog are crazy you are wrong. They are corrupt the same way as Mafia members are corrupt. That's why they are unable to discuss economics in a serious way. Only "religious dogma" based way is permitted.

Neoliberal Jesuits will defend their "flat earth" theory and ostracize heretics as long as financial oligarchy is in power, because their well being is dependent on it, and they are paid by financial oligarchy to do the job.

When neoliberalism was hatched it deliberately emulated methods of influence used by Communists (and Austrians were intimately aware of them, because the country experienced communist revolution, which failed) in trying to expand their influence at university departments and by creating think tanks. Those subversive methods proved way too successful and they are now really entrenched: neoclassic economic thinking permeates the society to the same or higher degree as Marx political economy in the USSR.

See LSE discussion "Masters of the Universe: Hayek, Friedman, and the Birth of Neoliberal Politics "

https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=ehrjP2_ffPc

libezkova : , March 03, 2017 at 08:48 AM
I think that that one of the few better and more productive pathway of discussing economic events is the one that stems from Hyman Minsky work with its idea of positive feedback loops in economics with one from financial system that periodically destabilizes the capitalist economy and create a financial crisis.

The neoclassical concept of equilibrium is way too primitive and attempts to build economics as branch of physics. It should be discarded for good, as the way it is used now is close to pure charlatanism.

We also have an uncertainty principle here as even the suggestion of the intervention can change the dynamics of the system (look at "Fed talk" )

The role of the state now is so huge that any talk about the economy achieving equilibrium by itself is fraud outside few special cases. And actually the introduction of neoliberalism was the "revolution from above" -- a coup d'état, if you wish.

== quote ==

In microeconomic theory, cost-minimization by consumers and by firms implies the existence of supply and demand correspondences for which market clearing equilibrium prices exist, if there are large numbers of consumers and producers. Under convexity assumptions or under some marginal-cost pricing rules, each equilibrium will be Pareto efficient: In large economies, non-convexity also leads to quasi-equilibria that are nearly efficient.

However, the concept of market equilibrium has been criticized by Austrians, post-Keynesians and others, who object to applications of microeconomic theory to real-world markets, when such markets are not usefully approximated by microeconomic models. Heterodox economists assert that micro-economic models rarely capture reality.
== end of quote ==

Steve Keen in one who uses and try to develop further Minsky concepts and he was one of the few who predicted the financial crash on 2008. IMHO he should get more respect and coverage at the expense of neoliberal stooges like Krugman.

Ha-Joon Chang, Philip Mirowski, Joseph Stiglitz, Richard Koo, Yanis Varoufakis, Noam Chomsky all have interesting and IMHO more realistic ideas about how the modern economy really function and what can be more appropriate ways to model it.

We should reject masked by mathiness typical neoclassical junk that is mainstream now.

[Mar 23, 2017] Usually the problem is misuse of statistical methods, for example by data dredging or other data-dependent activities, rather than say misinterpreting the results of a significance

Mar 23, 2017 | economistsview.typepad.com
John Williams : Reply Wednesday, March 22, 2017 at 08:14 AM , March 22, 2017 at 08:14 AM
Empirical studies reporting false reports are an unfortunate fact of life. I'm surprised that Noah Smith did not cite John Ioannnidis's paper on biomedical studies: "Why most published research findings are false." journals.plos.org/plosmedicine/article?id=10.1371/journal.pmed.0020124

The reasons have to do with poor statistics and human nature. Andrew Gelman also has a lot to say on this topic. For example, on the famous Deaton/Case result on the mortality rate of middle aged white males: http://andrewgelman.com/2015/11/10/death-rates-have-been-increasing-for-middle-aged-white-women-decreasing-for-men/

reason -> John Williams... , March 22, 2017 at 08:22 AM
Mostly (not always) the statistics are not wrong, it is the interpretation that is the problem.
John Williams -> reason ... , March 22, 2017 at 09:08 AM
Usually the problem is misuse of statistical methods, for example by data dredging or other data-dependent activities, rather than say misinterpreting the results of a significance test.

[Mar 06, 2017] Too much Maths, too little History The problem of Economics - YouTube

Mar 06, 2017 | www.youtube.com
Edward Dodson 10 months ago The first presenter (Professor Skidensky?) has described very clearly my own experience as a student and subsequently as a teacher. Decades ago when I began my work on a master's degree I initially chose economics but soon became very disillusioned by the reliance on mathematics and the absence of investigation into historical experience and societal norms. Nor was there any serious investigation into the validity of propositions put forward as economic theory. At once time in class I engaged my economics professor in a long exchange over the impact of land hoarding and land speculation in the U.S. economy. After about twenty minutes he simply ended our exchanged exasperated because he could not counter the observations made by evidence offered by real world observations. Fortunately, my university offered an interdisciplinary alternative, a Master of Liberal Arts degree and I switched programs. My course of study permitted me to read and study the great political economists, who were all historians and all moral philosophers. They examined markets, market forces, and government as a primary externality, and they reached moral judgments based on the principles of justice they embraced. Along the way, I was introduced to the writings of the great French school of political economists, the Physiocrats, and to the American Henry George. George's theory of the business cycle, based on the classical three factor model of how economies and societies function, provided to be quite useful in my later work as a market analyst in the real estate sector. When I retired from my professional work in the mid-2000s I gave some thought to entering a doctorate program in order to acquire the credentials for college instruction. The very low probablility of ever securing a full-time teaching position pushed me in a different direction. Instead, I developed two courses to teach to senior adults in a non-credit environment. One is titled "Understanding our Political Economy." The other is "The History of Economic Thought." Although I do introduce basic economic concepts, such as factor of production and wealth distribution in these two courses, my students are not required to know or use mathematics in order to understand such concepts. I found an introductory economics textbook written by Professor Harry Gunnison Brown used to teach basic economics without even one equation in the book. Each course is two semesters in length is discussion oriented. My view is that the more I am required to lecture, the less the students are learning. I am more than happy to share this course material with any teacher who is attracted to the interdisciplinary approach offered by the study of political economy and by reliance on the classical three factor model of wealth production and distribution. I can be reached by email at [email protected].

[Feb 19, 2017] These Professors Make More Than a Thousand Bucks an Hour Peddling Mega-Merger

Feb 19, 2017 | economistsview.typepad.com
pgl : , February 18, 2017 at 02:21 AM
Here is the story Noah Smith writes about:

https://www.propublica.org/article/these-professors-make-more-than-thousand-bucks-hour-peddling-mega-mergers

"These Professors Make More Than a Thousand Bucks an Hour Peddling Mega-Mergers - The economists are leveraging their academic prestige with secret reports justifying corporate concentration. Their predictions are often wrong and consumers pay the price."

That is just the headline. Way down in the discussion comes the most damning statement:

"These complex mathematical formulations carry weight with the government because they purport to be objective. But a ProPublica examination of several marquee deals found that economists sometimes salt away inconvenient data in footnotes and suppress negative findings, stretching the standards of intellectual honesty to promote their clients' interests."

Of course the government is supposed to hire its own world class economists to review the evidence as well. The problem, however, is that these government agencies are often underfunded. It is hard to compete with the mega-firms who pay $1000 an hour for a consultant when the entire budget for the government review agency is only $100,000. Penny wise, pound foolish.

[Feb 01, 2017] Regression analysis and heteroskedasticity

Feb 01, 2017 | economistsview.typepad.com
Chris G : , January 31, 2017 at 03:37 AM
Good post by Bellamare on heteroskedasticity. Heteroskedasticity and Its Content - Marc Bellemare Anyone doing regression analysis needs to keep it in mind.
RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> Chris G ... , January 31, 2017 at 04:27 AM
No, no, no, no, I don't do it no more. Sometimes in the mornings waiting for the sun to rise then I actually miss my work in SAS language programming. I was always a bigger fan of PROC FASTCLUS than PROC REG, but definitely PROC FASTCLUS with PROC GPLOT presentation color coding the cluster group number assignments in an overlay scatter plot. That is because I could estimate the expected degree of change in activity from the expected change in natural business units or hardware or software making historical data of use only for establishing a baseline, hopefully a clean baseline, rather than for estimating the degree of change itself. I used PROC REG to generate 95% confidence intervals around the linear regression means of predicted data points.
RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , January 31, 2017 at 04:40 AM
In my cases the heteroskedasticity was merely considered in the application of outliers from the central cluster(s). Outliers that constituted some type of risk had to be considered discretely, one by one, but only those that with predicted change would overshoot capacity limits. Undershooting was just an isolated outage or collapse in demand and certainly not a capacity risk.
Chris G -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , January 31, 2017 at 04:56 AM
Outlier detection is a whole other kettle of fish. Once upon a time I spent most of my time finding outliers in multivariate data and trying to figure out more effective methods for finding them. (Turns out the world isn't multivariate-normal distributed. Who knew?)
RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> Chris G ... , January 31, 2017 at 05:40 AM
For system performance data, which was my domain, an outlier could be an effect on the response variable at the extreme range of the independent variable, or just an unordinary event. The heteroskedasticity type outliers were things like increased CPU overhead at high utilizations, a feature of the MVS IBM mainframe operating system, or elongated service times for Fiber channels and Ethernet or elongated response times for a device having excessive utilization and queueing delays. Outliers could also be bugs or system recovery events as well as work scheduled outside its normal window of operation including systems programmers screwing around in production logical partitions. The heteroskedasticity type outliers were actually my job to prevent and I did a good job of that. My occasional undoing was almost always because of application changes that exceeded the developers expected resource requirements. A couple of times my system programmer coworker that controlled MVS performance misinterpreted a software constraint until it manifested itself in extreme ways for long enough until I was consulted for analysis.

So what I am getting at is that all exceptions to normal expectations can be considered as outliers, but then those that demonstrate only a difference in the reaction function of the response variable accorded by the range of the independent variable can also be considered heteroskedasticity.

In any case, I am about at the end of my analysis of outliers on my daffodil bulb planting now. I sure hope that I don't encounter any heteroskedasticity with the chain saw later this week.

RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , January 31, 2017 at 06:29 AM
The authors are using a study of heteroskedasticity to inform their forecasting ability. In such a case outliers would be very different from heteroskedasticity in the response variable over certain ranges of the independent variable. In other applications, such as large computer system performance, heteroskedasticity exists as something to be avoided because elongation of response variables follow a hyperbolic curve and we don't want to be kneed by the curve. Classic outliers are to ignored for forecasting even if not solved by protective measures but heteroskedasticity occurs as a response to demand in excess to expected and provisioned. Either resources per business unit of work must be reduced or more resources must be provisioned. In the former case then the historical baseline must be readjusted and in the later capacity limits must be increased.
RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , January 31, 2017 at 06:32 AM
I would think that there would be an analog to this in money supply and interest rates, but that is outside my domain.
Chris G -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , January 31, 2017 at 04:47 AM
:-)

[Dec 25, 2016] Why Central Bank Models Failed and How to Repair Them

Notable quotes:
"... Popular pre-financial crisis versions of the model excluded banking and finance, taking as given that finance and asset prices were merely a by-product of the real economy. ..."
"... The centre-piece of Paul Romer's scathing attack on these models is on the 'pretence of knowledge' ..."
"... he is critical of the incredible identifying assumptions and 'pretence of knowledge' in both Bayesian estimation and the calibration of parameters in DSGE models. ..."
"... A further symptom of the 'pretence of knowledge' is the assumed 'knowledge' that these parameters are constant over time. A milder critique by Olivier Blanchard (2016) points to a number of failings of DSGE models and recommends greater openness to more eclectic approaches. ..."
"... The equation is based on the assumption of inter-temporal optimising by consumers and that every consumer faces the same linear period-to-period budget constraint, linking income, wealth, and consumption. ..."
"... In the basic form, consumption every period equals permanent non-property income plus permanent property income defined as the real interest rate times the stock of wealth held by consumers at the beginning of each period. Permanent non-property income converts the variable flow of labour and transfer incomes a consumer expects over a lifetime into an amount equally distributed over time. ..."
"... However, consumers actually face idiosyncratic (household-specific) and uninsurable income uncertainty, and uncertainty interacts with credit or liquidity constraints. ..."
"... The 2000 Commodity Futures Modernization Act (CFMA) made derivatives enforceable throughout the US with priority ahead of claims by others (e.g. workers) in bankruptcy. ..."
"... 2004 SEC decision to ease capital requirements on investment banks increased gearing to what turned out to be dangerous levels ..."
"... Similar measures to lower required capital on investment grade PMBS increased leverage at commercial banks. These changes occurred in the political context of pressure to extend credit to poor. ..."
"... The importance of debt was highlighted in the debt-deflation theory of the Great Depression of Fisher (1933). 5 Briefly summarised, his story is that when credit availability expands, it raises spending, debt, and asset prices; irrational exuberance raises prices to vulnerable levels, given leverage; negative shocks can then cause falls in asset prices, increased bad debt, a credit crunch, and a rise in unemployment. ..."
"... In the financial accelerator feedback loops that operated in the US sub-prime crisis, falls in house prices increased bad loans and impaired the ability of banks to extend credit. As a result, household spending and residential investment fell, increasing unemployment and reducing incomes, feeding back further into lower asset prices and credit supply. ..."
"... The transmission mechanism that operated via consumption was poorly represented by the Federal Reserve's FRB-US model and similar models elsewhere. ..."
"... Reminds me of a young poseur at engineering school, who exclaimed during a group study session, "I've got it all jocked out. Now I just need the equations!" ..."
"... I have been aware of that for a few years now, but I doubt that one person in a hundred (or a thousand) knows when they listen to some economist on a news program or a business channel that the person speaking thinks that how much debt people have does not substantively affect their spending. ..."
"... If I used or invented an econ model that left out the "consumer", and modeled it with a "consumption agent object" having a single independent input variable being the Fed zero term, zero risk interest rate, I'd be too embarrassed to admit it. I would probably just very quietly make a career change into one of the softer sciences. Maybe writing fictional romance novels, or some such thing. ..."
"... The worst thing about these types of mea culpas from the mainstream is the cited criticisms from other mainstream economists only. It can only be a valid criticism if it was published in a mainstream journal ..."
"... That 'political pressure' turned out to be the bait and switch for a system that shifted power via debt creation. ..."
"... What we have not yet come to terms with are the implications of David Graeber's anthropological insights: how does debt affect social relationships, alter social norms, and affect relationships among individuals? ..."
"... Debt is a form of power, but by failing to factor this into their equations, the Central Bankers are missing the social, political, and cultural consequences of the profound shifts in 'credit market architecture'. In many respects, this is not about 'money'; it's about power. ..."
"... The Central Bankers' models can include all the parameters they can dream up, but until someone starts thinking more clearly about the role and function of money, and the way that 'different kinds of money' create 'different kinds of social relationships', we are all in a world of hurt. ..."
"... Now, maybe it is just a coincidence, but it is hard for me not to notice that the explosion in consumer credit matches up nicely with the rise in inequality. ..."
"... " .. debt does not make society as a whole poorer: one person's debt is another person's asset. So total wealth is unaffected by the amount of debt out there. This is, strictly speaking true only for the world economy as a whole .. " Paul Krugman "End this Depression Now". ..."
Dec 25, 2016 | www.nakedcapitalism.com
By John Muellbauer, Professor of Economics, Oxford University. Originally published at VoxEU

The failure of the New Keynesian dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models to capture interactions of finance and the real economy has been widely recognised since the Global Crisis. This column argues that the flaws in these models stem from unrealistic micro-foundations for household behaviour and from wrongly assuming that aggregate behaviour mimics a fully informed 'representative agent'. Rather than 'one-size-fits-all' monetary and macroprudential policy, institutional differences between countries imply major differences for monetary policy transmission and policy.

The New Keynesian DSGE models that dominated the macroeconomic profession and central bank thinking for the last two decades were based on several principles.

  1. The first was formal derivation from micro-foundations, assuming optimising behaviour of consumers and firms with rational or 'model-consistent' expectations of future conditions. For such derivation to result in a tractable model, it was assumed that the behaviour of firms and of consumers corresponded to that of a 'representative' firm and a 'representative' consumer. In turn, this entailed the absence of necessarily heterogeneous credit or liquidity constraints. Another important assumption to obtain tractable solutions was that of a stable long-run equilibrium trend path for the economy. If the economy was never far from such a path, the role of uncertainty would necessarily be limited. Popular pre-financial crisis versions of the model excluded banking and finance, taking as given that finance and asset prices were merely a by-product of the real economy.
  2. Second, a competitive economy was assumed but with a number of distortions, including nominal rigidities – sluggish price adjustment – and monopolistic competition. This is what distinguished New Keynesian DSGE models from the general equilibrium real business cycle (RBC) models that preceded them. It extended the range of stochastic shocks that could disturb the economy from the productivity or taste shocks of the RBC model. Finally, while some models calibrated (assumed) values of the parameters, where the parameters were estimated, Bayesian system-wide estimation was used, imposing substantial amounts of prior constraints on parameter values deemed 'reasonable'.

The 'Pretence of Knowledge'

The centre-piece of Paul Romer's scathing attack on these models is on the 'pretence of knowledge' (Romer 2016); echoing Caballero (2010), he is critical of the incredible identifying assumptions and 'pretence of knowledge' in both Bayesian estimation and the calibration of parameters in DSGE models. 1

A further symptom of the 'pretence of knowledge' is the assumed 'knowledge' that these parameters are constant over time. A milder critique by Olivier Blanchard (2016) points to a number of failings of DSGE models and recommends greater openness to more eclectic approaches.

Unrealistic Micro-Foundations

As explained in Muellbauer (2016), an even deeper problem, not seriously addressed by Romer or Blanchard, lies in the unrealistic micro-foundations for the behaviour of households embodied in the 'rational expectations permanent income' model of consumption, an integral component of these DSGE models. Consumption is fundamental to macroeconomics both in DSGE models and in the consumption functions of general equilibrium macro-econometric models such as the Federal Reserve's FRB-US. At the core of representative agent DSGE models is the Euler equation for consumption, popularised in the highly influential paper by Hall (1978). It connects the present with the future, and is essential to the iterative forward solutions of these models. The equation is based on the assumption of inter-temporal optimising by consumers and that every consumer faces the same linear period-to-period budget constraint, linking income, wealth, and consumption. Maximising expected life-time utility subject to the constraint results in the optimality condition that links expected marginal utility in the different periods. Under approximate 'certainty equivalence', this translates into a simple relationship between consumption at time t and planned consumption at t +1 and in periods further into the future.

Under these simplifying assumptions, the rational expectations permanent income consumption function can be derived. In the basic form, consumption every period equals permanent non-property income plus permanent property income defined as the real interest rate times the stock of wealth held by consumers at the beginning of each period. Permanent non-property income converts the variable flow of labour and transfer incomes a consumer expects over a lifetime into an amount equally distributed over time.

However, consumers actually face idiosyncratic (household-specific) and uninsurable income uncertainty, and uncertainty interacts with credit or liquidity constraints. The asymmetric information revolution in economics in the 1970s for which Akerlof, Spence and Stiglitz shared the Nobel prize explains this economic environment. Research by Deaton (1991,1992), 2 several papers by Carroll (1992, 2000, 2001, 2014), Ayigari (1994), and a new generation of heterogeneous agent models (e.g. Kaplan et al. 2016) imply that household horizons then tend to be both heterogeneous and shorter – with 'hand-to-mouth' behaviour even by quite wealthy households, contradicting the textbook permanent income model, and hence DSGE models. A second reason for the failure of these DSGE models is that aggregate behaviour does not follow that of a 'representative agent'. Kaplan et al. (2016) show that, with these better micro-foundations, quite different implications follow for monetary policy than in the New Keynesian DSGE models. A third reason is that structural breaks, as shown by Hendry and Mizon (2014), and radical uncertainty further invalidate DSGE models, illustrated by the failure of the Bank of England's DSGE model both during and after the 2008-9 crisis (Fawcett et al. 2015). The failure of the representative agent Euler equation to fit aggregate data 3 is further empirical evidence against the assumptions underlying the DSGE models, while evidence on financial illiteracy (Lusardi 2016) is a problem for the assumption that all consumers optimise.

The Evolving Credit Market Architecture

Of the structural changes, the evolution and revolution of credit market architecture was the single most important. In the US, credit card ownership and instalment credit spread between the 1960s and the 2000s; the government-sponsored enterprises – Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac – were recast in the 1970s to underwrite mortgages; interest rate ceilings were lifted in the early 1980s; and falling IT costs transformed payment and credit screening systems in the 1980s and 1990s. More revolutionary was the expansion of sub-prime mortgages in the 2000s, driven by rise of private label securitisation backed by credit default obligations (CDOs) and swaps.

The 2000 Commodity Futures Modernization Act (CFMA) made derivatives enforceable throughout the US with priority ahead of claims by others (e.g. workers) in bankruptcy. This permitted derivative enhancements for private label mortgage-backed securities (PMBS) so that they could be sold on as highly rated investment grade securities. A second regulatory change was the deregulation of banks and investment banks. In particular, the 2004 SEC decision to ease capital requirements on investment banks increased gearing to what turned out to be dangerous levels and further boosted PMBS, Duca et al (2016). Similar measures to lower required capital on investment grade PMBS increased leverage at commercial banks. These changes occurred in the political context of pressure to extend credit to poor.

The Importance of Debt

A fourth reason for the failure of the New Keynesian DSGE models, linking closely with the previous, is the omission of debt and household balance sheets more generally, which are crucial for understanding consumption and macroeconomic fluctuations. Some central banks did not abandon their large non-DSGE econometric policy models, but these were also defective in that they too relied on the representative agent permanent income hypothesis which ignored shifts in credit constraints and mistakenly lumped all elements of household balance sheets, debt, liquid assets, illiquid financial assets (including pension assets) and housing wealth into a single net worth measure of wealth. 4 Because housing is a consumption good as well as an asset, consumption responds differently to a rise in housing wealth than to an increase in financial wealth (see Aron et al. 2012). Second, different assets have different degrees of 'spendability'. It is indisputable that cash is more spendable than pension or stock market wealth, the latter being subject to asset price uncertainty and access restrictions or trading costs. This suggests estimating separate marginal propensities to spend out of liquid and illiquid financial assets. Third, the marginal effect of debt on spending is unlikely just to be minus that of either illiquid financial or housing wealth. The reason is that debt is not subject to price uncertainty and it has long-term servicing and default risk implications, with typically highly adverse consequences.

The importance of debt was highlighted in the debt-deflation theory of the Great Depression of Fisher (1933). 5 Briefly summarised, his story is that when credit availability expands, it raises spending, debt, and asset prices; irrational exuberance raises prices to vulnerable levels, given leverage; negative shocks can then cause falls in asset prices, increased bad debt, a credit crunch, and a rise in unemployment.

In the 1980s and early 1990s, boom-busts in Norway, Finland, Sweden, and the UK followed this pattern. In the financial accelerator feedback loops that operated in the US sub-prime crisis, falls in house prices increased bad loans and impaired the ability of banks to extend credit. As a result, household spending and residential investment fell, increasing unemployment and reducing incomes, feeding back further into lower asset prices and credit supply.

The transmission mechanism that operated via consumption was poorly represented by the Federal Reserve's FRB-US model and similar models elsewhere. A more relevant consumption function for modelling the financial accelerator is needed, modifying the permanent income model with shorter time horizons, 6 incorporating important shifts in credit lending conditions, and disaggregating household balance sheets into liquid and illiquid elements, debt and housing wealth.

Implications for Macroeconomic Policy Models

To take into account all the feedbacks, a macroeconomic policy model needs to explain asset prices and the main components of household balance sheets, including debt and liquid assets. This is best done in a system of equations including consumption, in which shifts in credit conditions – which have system-wide consequences, sometimes interacting with other variables such as housing wealth – are extracted as a latent variable. 7 The availability of home equity loans, which varies over time and between countries – hardly available in the US of the 1970s or in contemporary Germany, France or Japan – and the also the variable size of down-payments needed to obtain a mortgage, determine whether increases in house prices increase (US and UK) or reduce (Germany and Japan) aggregate consumer spending. This is one of the findings of research I review in Muellbauer (2016). Another important finding is that a rise in interest rates has different effects on aggregate consumer spending depending on the nature of household balance sheets. Japan and Germany differ radically from the US and the UK, with far higher bank and saving deposits and lower household debt levels so that lower interest rates reduce consumer spending. A crucial implication of these two findings is that monetary policy transmission via the household sector differs radically between countries – it is far more effective in the US and UK, and even counterproductive in Japan (see Muellbauer and Murata 2011).

Such models, building in disaggregated balance sheets and the shifting, interactive role of credit conditions, have many benefits: better interpretations of data on credit growth and asset prices helpful for developing early warning indicators of financial crises; better understandings of long-run trends in saving rates and asset prices; and insights into transmission for monetary and macro-prudential policy. Approximate consistency with good theory following the information economics revolution of the 1970s is better than the exact consistency of the New Keynesian DSGE model with bad theory that makes incredible assumptions about agents' behaviour and the economy. Repairing central bank policy models to make them more relevant and more consistent with the qualitative conclusions of the better micro-foundations outlined above is now an urgent task.

Endnotes

[1] Part of the problem of identification is that the DSGE models throw away long-run information. They do this by removing long-run trends with the Hodrick-Prescott filter, or linear time trends specific to each variable. Identification, which rests on available information, then becomes more difficult, and necessitates 'incredible assumptions'. Often, impulse response functions tracing out the dynamic response of the modelled economy to shocks are highly sensitive to the way the data have been pre-filtered.

[2] This important research was highly praised in Angus Deaton's 2015 Nobel prize citation: http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/2015/advanced.html

[3] See Campbell and Mankiw (1989, 1990) and for even more powerful evidence from the UK, US and Japan; Muellbauer (2010); and micro-evidence from Shea (1995).

[4] Net worth is defined as liquid assets minus mortgage and non-mortgage debt plus illiquid financial assets plus housing assets, and this assumes that the coefficients are all the same.

[5] In recent years, several empirical contributions have recognised the importance of the mechanisms described by Fisher (1933). Mian and Sufi (2014) have provided extensive micro-economic evidence for the role of credit shifts in the US sub-prime crisis and the constraining effect of high household debt levels. Focusing on macro-data, Turner (2015) has analysed the role of debt internationally with more general mechanisms, as well as in explaining the poor recovery from the global financial crisis. Jorda et al. (2016) have drawn attention to the increasing role of real estate collateral in bank lending in most advanced countries and in financial crises.

[6] The FRB-US model does build in shorter average horizons than text-book permanent income. It also has a commendable flexible treatment of expectations, Brayton et al (1997).

[7] The use of latent variables in macroeconomic modelling has a long vintage. Potential output, and the "natural rate" of unemployment or of interest are often treated as latent variables, for example in the FRB-US model and in Laubach and Williams (2003), and latent variables are often modelled using state space methods. Flexible spline functions can achieve similar estimates. Interaction effects of latent with other variables seem not to have been considered, however. We use the term 'latent interactive variable equation system' (LIVES) to describe the resulting format.

Jim Haygood , December 24, 2016 at 9:08 am

'the omission of debt and household balance sheets more generally'

putting these eclownometric [sic] models at about the same level of technical sophistication as the Newcomen steam engine of 1712, which achieved about one (1) percent thermodynamic efficiency.

'a macroeconomic policy model needs to explain asset prices and household balance sheets. This is best done in a system of equations.'

Yes indeedy. Reminds me of a young poseur at engineering school, who exclaimed during a group study session, "I've got it all jocked out. Now I just need the equations!"

fresno dan , December 24, 2016 at 12:37 pm

Jim Haygood
December 24, 2016 at 9:08 am

' the omission of debt and household balance sheets more generally '

You beat me to it. I have been aware of that for a few years now, but I doubt that one person in a hundred (or a thousand) knows when they listen to some economist on a news program or a business channel that the person speaking thinks that how much debt people have does not substantively affect their spending.

Really, 5 year olds describing how they get toys from Santa have a better grasp of economics than most "economists"

craazyboy , December 24, 2016 at 2:04 pm

If I used or invented an econ model that left out the "consumer", and modeled it with a "consumption agent object" having a single independent input variable being the Fed zero term, zero risk interest rate, I'd be too embarrassed to admit it. I would probably just very quietly make a career change into one of the softer sciences. Maybe writing fictional romance novels, or some such thing.

TiPs , December 24, 2016 at 9:41 am

The worst thing about these types of mea culpas from the mainstream is the cited criticisms from other mainstream economists only. It can only be a valid criticism if it was published in a mainstream journal

readerOfTeaLeaves , December 24, 2016 at 11:14 am

Of the structural changes, the evolution and revolution of credit market architecture was the single most important . In the US, credit card ownership and instalment credit spread between the 1960s and the 2000s; the government-sponsored enterprises – Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac – were recast in the 1970s to underwrite mortgages; interest rate ceilings were lifted in the early 1980s; and falling IT costs transformed payment and credit screening systems in the 1980s and 1990s. More revolutionary was the expansion of sub-prime mortgages in the 2000s, driven by rise of private label securitisation backed by credit default obligations (CDOs) and swaps. The 2000 Commodity Futures Modernization Act (CFMA) made derivatives enforceable throughout the US with priority ahead of claims by others (e.g. workers) in bankruptcy. This permitted derivative enhancements for private label mortgage-backed securities (PMBS) so that they could be sold on as highly rated investment grade securities. A second regulatory change was the deregulation of banks and investment banks . Similar measures to lower required capital on investment grade PMBS increased leverage at commercial banks. These changes occurred in the political context of pressure to extend credit to poor.

That 'political pressure' turned out to be the bait and switch for a system that shifted power via debt creation.

What we have not yet come to terms with are the implications of David Graeber's anthropological insights: how does debt affect social relationships, alter social norms, and affect relationships among individuals?

Debt is a form of power, but by failing to factor this into their equations, the Central Bankers are missing the social, political, and cultural consequences of the profound shifts in 'credit market architecture'. In many respects, this is not about 'money'; it's about power.

After Brexit, Trump, and the emerging upheaval in the EU, it's no longer enough to just 'build better economic models'.

The Central Bankers' models can include all the parameters they can dream up, but until someone starts thinking more clearly about the role and function of money, and the way that 'different kinds of money' create 'different kinds of social relationships', we are all in a world of hurt.

At this point, Central Bankers should also ask themselves what happens - socially, personally - when 'debt' (i.e., financialization) shifts from productivity to predation. That shift accelerated from the 1970s, through the 1990s, into the 2000s.

Allowing anyone to charge interest that is usurious is the modern equivalent of turning a blind eye to slavery.

By enabling outrageous interest, any government hands their hard working taxpayers over to what is essentially unending servitude.

This destroys the political power of any government that engages in such blind stupidity.

Frankly, I'm astonished that it has taken so long for taxpayers to show signs of outrage and revolt.

jsn , December 24, 2016 at 11:45 am

Voters in the U.S. react under radical new action retarding constraints:

  1. IT enhanced agnatology: kick ass propaganda
  2. Suburbanization: deportation of the working class from the collective action friendly urban geography
fresno dan , December 24, 2016 at 12:51 pm

readerOfTeaLeaves

December 24, 2016 at 11:14 am

I think you have come up with a good insight – I very much agree its about power and not money.

Now, maybe it is just a coincidence, but it is hard for me not to notice that the explosion in consumer credit matches up nicely with the rise in inequality.

And one other thing I would point out – it doesn't take usurious interest rates. If squillionaires have access to unlimited, essentially cost free money in which the distributors of money are guaranteed a profit, NO MATTER HOW MUCH THEY HAVE LOST, while the debts on non-squillionaires are collected with fees, penalties, and to the last dime, than it doesn't matter if interest rates are essentially zero.

Who gets bailed out is not due to logic or accounting that says that the banks' losses have to be made whole, but not home owners – that is an ideology called economics .

craazyboy , December 24, 2016 at 2:23 pm

I wouldn't downplay how cool the money part is, however. It's no fun making questionable, dodgy loans unless you can charge fees up front and then sell the risk off to a large crowd of suckers. Hence the importance of securitization and other "insurance" type derivatives. Then, if you run out of willing suckers, you need a place to stuff it all, say pension plans and maybe even privatized social security.

But if they allow this to happen in the real world, shouldn't the models have a piece reflecting this behavior as well? Full circle of course, where the "consumer balance sheet" contains his bad debt investment and savings assets* offsetting his liabilities. Then everyone would be more like a bank?

* we still need to model bubble assets – like real estate and stocks. This sounds like it's starting to get tricky!

José , December 24, 2016 at 12:19 pm

"Another important finding is that a rise in interest rates has different effects on aggregate consumer spending depending on the nature of household balance sheets".

This is a point that Warren Mosler and other MMTers have been making since the 1990s: depending on circumstances, lower interest rates may well have contractionary effects and higher interest rates may stimulate the economy.

The tool of choice to fight recessions and control inflation should thus be fiscal instead of monetary policy.

Again, MMT had the analysis right long before mainstream theory started to admit there might be serious problems with its favorite approaches (without ever giving appropriate credit to MMT, of course!).

Very sad!

craazyboy , December 24, 2016 at 2:50 pm

I think the Samarians knew that 5000 years ago. The Templars certainly knew it 1300 years ago. And most definitely, "modern" European banking knew it 300 years ago.

susan the other , December 24, 2016 at 12:25 pm

of note to me is just how simplistic Keynesian statistics were/are, based on almost fantasy-assumptions. And that was followed by Stiglitz et al's theory of asymmetric information models. And this above does give us a dose of all the different variables involved in accurately analyzing an economy – an economy that exploded with financialization, but nobody could keep up. As was proven in 2008. It shouldn't be this confusing. "Repairing CB policies to make them more relevant is now an urgent task." I think it is urgent enough to nationalize the banks and start over using a sovereign money model.

OpenThePodBayDoorsHAL , December 24, 2016 at 2:10 pm

Let's take an infinitely complex system (the economy) that is widely affected by human emotion, then we'll leave out the mechanism by which money itself is created and distributed and then let's "model" it.
We'll have two fans of Stalin's communist "command and control" economy (Keynes and Harry Dexter White) pretend they could create a stable system based on Ph.Ds divining future economic and trade flows and then "managing" them by price fixing the price of money. We'll set policy based on the national conditions of the country with the global reserve currency despite the fact that 2/3 of that currency is outside that country. And with a system where trade never settles so massive imbalances can persist indefinitely. Then let's put self-interested private institutions in charge of all money creation and distribution .and we'll be sure their system operates in secret and is never audited. When the system blows up we'll have these central overlords step in as uneconomic buyers of assets with no consideration for asset quality or price, with no economic need to ever sell, and with "unlimited" funds with which to buy more such assets. At the end we'll continue to call the system "capitalism" and we'll continue to call the scrip "money" and hope nobody notices.

End the Fed.

Plenue , December 24, 2016 at 5:32 pm

*sigh*

Congress creates the money when it passes budget legislation. The Fed merely enacts their decree.

Sound of the Suburbs , December 24, 2016 at 2:21 pm

Economics has long been known as the dismal science.

The IMF forecast Greek GDP would have recovered by 2015 with austerity.
By 2015 it was down 27% and still falling.

The IMF can attract some of the best economists in the world but a technocrat elite trained in a dismal science aren't up to much.

In 2008 the Queen visited the revered economists of the LSE and said "If these things were so large, how come everyone missed it?"

The FED is full of PhDs from America's finest universities but a technocrat elite trained in a dismal science aren't up to much.

The FED will have been looking at the US money supply, let me show you what they missed:

http://www.whichwayhome.com/skin/frontend/default/wwgcomcatalogarticles/images/articles/whichwayhomes/US-money-supply.jpg

Everything is reflected in the money supply.

The money supply is flat in the recession of the early 1990s.

Then it really starts to take off as the dot.com boom gets going which rapidly morphs into the US housing boom, courtesy of Alan Greenspan's loose monetary policy.

When M3 gets closer to the vertical, the black swan is coming and you have a credit bubble on your hands (money = debt).

The mainstream are all trained in neoclassical economics which is spectacularly dismal.

Steve Keen sits outside the mainstream and saw the credit bubble forming in 2005, you can see it in the
US money supply (money = debt).

In 2007, Ben Bernanke could see no problems ahead (dismal).

Irving Fisher looked at the debt inflated asset bubble after the 1929 crash when ideas that markets reached stable equilibriums were beyond a joke.

Fisher developed a theory of economic crises called debt-deflation, which attributed the crises to the bursting of a credit bubble.

Hyman Minsky came up with "financial instability hypothesis" in 1974 and Steve Keen carries on with this work today. The theory is there outside the mainstream.

To understand the theory you have to understand money:

" .. debt does not make society as a whole poorer: one person's debt is another person's asset. So total wealth is unaffected by the amount of debt out there. This is, strictly speaking true only for the world economy as a whole .. " Paul Krugman "End this Depression Now".

This is the neoclassical economic view of money and it's totally wrong and will always leave you blind to events like 2008, e.g.

1929 – US (margin lending into US stocks)
1989 – Japan (real estate)
2008 – US (real estate bubble leveraged up with derivatives for global contagion)
2010 – Ireland (real estate)
2012 – Spain (real estate)
2015 – China (margin lending into Chinese stocks)

Norway, Sweden, Canada and Australia have been letting their real estate bubbles inflate because their mainstream economists and Central Bankers don't know what's coming.

Money and debt are opposite sides of the same coin.
If there is no debt there is no money.
Money is created by loans and destroyed by repayments of those loans.

If you want to understand how money really works:

From the BoE:
http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/quarterlybulletin/2014/qb14q1prereleasemoneycreation.pdf

Advanced:
"Where does money come from" available from Amazon

You need to understand how money works to understand why austerity doesn't work in balance sheet recessions, the cause of the dire prediction from the IMF that I started with.

You can look at the money supply/debt levels (the same thing) to see how well the economy is doing.

The money supply is contracting – the economy will be doing badly and the risk of this turning into debt deflation is high, there is positive feedback tending to make the situation worse. Debt repayments are larger than the new debt being taken out, the overall level of debt is decreasing.

The money supply is stable – this is stagnation, in the ideal world the money supply should be growing at a steady pace.

The money supply is growing steadily – the ideal.

The money supply is growing very rapidly – you've got a credit bubble on your hands and the "black swan" is near. The FED didn't understand money and debt before 2008 so they missed it.

Richard Koo explains:
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=8YTyJzmiHGk

Mario is still doing austerity now, no wonder those Italian banks are full of NPLs.

It's too late for Norway, Sweden, Canada and Australia's mainstream economists and Central Bankers, but we need to get this dismal neoclassical economics updated before the whole world descends into debt deflation.

It's almost here, there isn't much time.

Chuck another trillion in to keep this sinking ship afloat Central Bankers, we need to get our technocrat elite up to speed.

Sound of the Suburbs , December 24, 2016 at 2:23 pm

In brief:

Just look at the rate of change of the money supply/debt.

When it's rising rapidly you're in trouble as a credit bubble is forming.

A negative gradient is also a bad sign as it means your money supply is contracting, your economy is in trouble and debt deflation could be on its way.

Economists do waffle.

Sound of the Suburbs , December 24, 2016 at 2:50 pm

Now Mrs. Yellen, put that on a Post-It note on your desk and you won't make the same mistake as your predecessor.

Skip Intro , December 24, 2016 at 2:38 pm

I am shocked, shocked I tell you, that a model with 'Equilibrium' right in the name fails to predict crises. They could probably do better just aggregating results from a big multi-player version of The Sims.

Dick Burkhart , December 25, 2016 at 2:26 am

Better models should start from scratch, assuming non-linearity. They could take the Limits-to-Growth system of nonlinear pde's as a starting point, for example, to get a good handle on long range dynamics. Then add detailed submodels for money and debt, for different countries, for trade, for different economic sectors, etc. Use realistic agent based models where standard models are inadequate.

To do all, start by sending all those economics Ph.D.s back to school in other fields where they know how to do modern applied mathematics.

See original post for references

[Nov 26, 2016] EconoSpeak Comments on Milanovic on Marx

Nov 26, 2016 | econospeak.blogspot.com

I am a Marxist economist (Professor of Economics, Mount Holyoke College) and I appreciate Branko Milanovic's open-mindedness and his efforts in a recent post on his blog to educate economists who often have a crude and superficial misunderstanding of Marx's labor theory of value.

For context for my comments on Milanovic, I will first say a few words about my interpretation of Marx's labor theory of value (LTV). In my view, Marx's LTV is primarily a macro theory and the main question addressed in Marx's macro LTV is the determination of the total profit (or surplus-value) produced in the capitalist economy as a whole. Profit is the main goal of capitalist economies and should be a key variable in any theory of capitalism. Marx's theory of the total profit is that profit is the difference between the value produced by workers and the wages they are paid, i.e. that profit is produced by the "surplus labor" of workers.

I argue that Marx's "surplus labor" theory of profit has very significant and wide-ranging explanatory power. Marx's theory provides straight-forward and robust explanations of the following important phenomena of capitalist economies: conflicts between capitalists and workers over wages, and over the length of the working day, and over the intensity of labor (i.e. how hard workers work, which determines in part how much value they produce); endogenous technological change (in order to reduce necessary labor and increase surplus labor and surplus-value); increasing concentration of capital and income(i.e. increasing inequality); the trend and fluctuations in the rate of profit over time; and endogenous cycles due to fluctuations in the rate of profit rate of profit. (A more complete discussion of the explanatory power of Marx's theory of profit is provided in my " Marx's Economic Theory: True or False? A Marxian Response to Blaug's Appraisal, " in Moseley (ed.), Heterodox Economic Theories: True or False?, Edward Elgar, 1995).

This wide-ranging explanatory power of Marx's surplus labor theory of profit is especially impressive when compared to mainstream economics. In mainstream macroeconomics, there is no theory of profit at all; profit (or the rate of profit) is not even a variable in the theory! I was shocked when I realized in graduate school this absence of profit in mainstream macro, and am still shocked that there is no effort to include profit. Indeed, DSGE models go in the opposite direction and many models do not even have firms!

Mainsteam micro does have a theory of profit (or interest) – the marginal productivity theory of distribution – but it is a weak and largely discredited theory. Marginal productivity theory has been shown by the capital controversy and other criticisms to have insoluble logical problems (the aggregation problem, reswitching, cannot integrate intermediate goods, etc.). And marginal productivity theory has very meager explanatory power and explains none of the important phenomena listed above that are explained by Marx's theory.

Milanovic agrees that Marx's LTV is primarily a macro theory, but he interprets it in this post as only the assumption that "sum of values will be equal to sum of production prices". And he continues: "The former is an unobservable quantity so Marx's contention is not falsifiable. It is therefore an extra-scientific statement that we have to take on faith.

I argue, to the contrary, that Marx's macro LTV is primarily a theory of profit and my conclusion that Marx's theory is the best theory of profit we have is not based on faith but is instead based on the standard scientific criterion of empirical explanatory power. It is much more accurate to say that marginal productivity theory is accepted by mainstream economists on faith, as Charles Ferguson famously said in his conclusion to the capital controversy.

Now to my comments on Milanovic's three main points:

1. Milanovic's main point is that the LTV is often misinterpreted as a simple micro theory that assumes that the prices of individual commodities are proportional to the labor-times required to produce them. Milanovic argues that is not true in a capitalist economy because of the equalization of the profit rate across industries with unequal ratios of capital to labor, so that according to Marx's theory, long-run equilibrium prices are determined by the equation: w + d + rK, where w is wages, d is depreciation and r is the economy-wide rate of profit (missing in this equation is the cost of intermediate goods, but I will ignore this).

Milanovic emphasizes that Walras and Marshall had essentially the same equation for long-run equilibrium prices. I agree that all three theories of long-run equilibrium prices have this same form, but there is an important difference. Marx's theory provides a logically rigorous theory of the rate of profit in this equation (based on his theory of the total profit discussed above) and Walras and Marshall just take the rate of profit as given , disguised as an "opportunity cost", and thus provides no theory of profit at all . Therefore, I think Marx's theory of long-run equilibrium prices is superior to Walras' and Marshall's in this important sense.

2. Milanovic's second main point is that Marx's theory of long-run equilibrium prices are "clearly very, very far from derisive statements that the labor theory of value means that people are just paid for their labor input regardless of what is the 'socially necessary labor' required to produce a good." I presume that this derisive statement means that workers produce more value than they are paid and thus are exploited in capitalism. But Branko is mistaken about this. Marx's theory of long-run equilibrium prices is based on his macro theory of profit according to which the source of profit is the surplus labor of workers. This conclusion is indeed derisive and that is the main (non-scientific) reason that Marx's theory of profit is rejected by mainstream economists in spite of its superior explanatory power.

I know from previous correspondence that Milanovic understands well Marx's "exploitation" theory of profit, but he seems to overlook the connection between Marx's micro theory of prices of production and his macro theory of profit.

3. Milanovic's third point is that Marx's labor theory of value is most helpful in understanding pre-capitalist economies and the relation between capitalism and non-capitalist economies today. I argue, to the contrary, that Marx's labor theory of value and profit is the best theory we have to understand the most important phenomena of capitalist economies, including 21 st century capitalism.

It would be one thing if mainstream economics had a robust theory of profit with significant explanation power. But it has almost no theory of profit. Therefore it would seem to be appropriate from a scientific point of view that Marx's surplus labor theory of profit should be given more serious consideration.

Thanks again to Milanovic and I look forward to further discussion.

[Nov 21, 2016] Bill Black Bloomberg Notices Paul Romers Indictment of Macroeconomics naked capitalism

Notable quotes:
"... For more than three decades, macroeconomics has gone backwards," the paper began. Romer closed out his argument, some 20 pages later, by accusing a cohort of economists of drifting away from science, more interested in preserving reputations than testing their theories against reality, "more committed to friends than facts." In between, he offers a wicked parody of a modern macro argument: "Assume A, assume B, blah blah blah and so we have proven that P is true ..."
"... The idea that consumers and businesses always make rational choices pervades mainstream economics. Romer thinks that's not only wrong, but may lead to the misleading conclusion that government action can't fix big problems. ..."
"... There is no better place to be writing this than from (nearly) Minneapolis, for the University of Minnesota's economics department is the most devoted coven worshipping the most extreme form of "rational expectations." The most famous cultists have now relocated, but the U. Minnesota economics department remains fanatical in its devotion to rational expectations theory. ..."
"... All of this means that Romer's denunciations were sure to hit home far harder with mainstream and theoclassical economists than anything a heterodox economist could write. ..."
"... What this paragraph reveals is the classic tactic of theoclassical economists – they simply ignore real criticism. Lucas, Prescott, and Sargent all care desperately about Romer's criticism – but they all refuse to engage substantively with his critique. One has to love the arrogance of Sargent in "responding" – without reading – to Romer's critique. Sargent cannot, of course, respond to a critique he has never read so he instead makes a crude attempt to insult Romer, asserting that Romer has not done any scientific work in three decades. ..."
"... The rational expectations purists have been unable to come up with a response to their predictive failures and their false model of human behavior for thirty years. The Bloomberg article does not understand a subtle point about their non-defense defense, as shown in these key passages. ..."
"... What the rational expectations devotees are actually saying is their standard line, which is a radical departure from the scientific method. Their mantra is "it takes a model to beat a model." That mantra violates the scientific method. Their models are designed to embody their rational expectations theory. Those models' predictive ability is pathetic, which means that their theory and models are both falsified and should be rejected. The academic proponents of modern macro models, however, assert that their models are incapable of falsification by testing and predictive failure. This is not science, but theology. ..."
"... V.V. Chari's criticism of Romer is revealing. He complains that Romer does not want to "build on [rational expectation theory's] foundations." Why would Romer want to commit such a pointless act? Romer's point is that rational expectations is a failed theory that needs to be rejected so macroeconomics can move on to useful endeavors. ..."
"... Rational expectations theory has no such empirical foundations. ..."
"... Further, the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models routinely fail the predictive test and, as Romer details, fail despite the use of dozens of ways in which the models are "gamed" with arbitrary inputs and restrictions that have no theoretical or empirical basis. Chari is right to describe the modern macro model as an "edifice." I would add that it is a baroque edifice top heavy with ornamental features designed to hide its lack of a foundation. Modern macro collapsed as soon as its devotees tried to build without an empirical foundation. ..."
"... The rational expectation devotees respond that predictive failures – no matter how extreme or frequent – cannot falsify their models or their theories. The proponents claim that only a better model, with superior predictive ability can beat their model. ..."
"... Kocherlakota's summary description is appropriately terse. He later explains the dogmatic gloss that devotees place on each of these five points. The "budget constraint," for example, means that nations with sovereign currencies such as the U.S. cannot run deficits, even to fight severe recessions or depressions. Why? Because theoclassical economists are enormous believers in austerity. As Kocherlakota archly phrased the matter, "freshwater" DSGE models were so attractive to theoclassical macro types because their model perfectly tracked their ideology. ..."
"... Specifying household preferences and firm objectives is equally erroneous, as Akerlof and Romer's 1993 article on "Looting" demonstrated. "Firms" do not have "objectives." Employees have "objectives," and the controlling officers' "objectives" are the most powerful drivers of employee behavior. ..."
"... Kocherlakota unintentionally highlighted modern macros' inability to incorporate even massive frauds driving national scandals and banking crises, despite the efforts of Akerlof (1970) (a market for "lemons") and Akerlof and Romer 1993: ("looting") in this passage. ..."
"... If macroeconomics, outside the cult of modern macro, were a car, it would not be "broken." It would be episodically broken when the rational expectations devotees got hold of monetary or fiscal policy. The rational expectations model fails the most fundamental test of a financial model – people trying to make money by anticipating the macroeconomics consequences of changes in monetary and fiscal policy overwhelmingly do not use their models because they are known to have pathetic predictive ability. The alternative models that embrace Keynesian analysis and are not dependent on the fiction of rational expectations function pretty well. The real world macro car, when driven by real world drivers, works OK. Essentially, the rational expectations devotees say that we can never drive the macro "car" because the public will defeat any effort to drive the economy in any direction. Instead, the economy will lurch about n response to random technological "shocks" that cannot be predicted because they occur without any relationship to any public policy choices. ..."
"... I am completely confused about the prediction of "rational choices". Do they include going bankrupt on purpose and letting your investors take the hit, burning your building down for the insurance money, hostile takeover behavior where businesses are run into the ground on purpose, tax strategies, people going on unemployment when they want a vacation from work, and on and on? These are decisions that have a rationale for the people who make them, and they have not been uncommon. Perhaps "economists" are best off observing not predicting "human behavior". ..."
"... I majored in economics. as you go up higher up into the dismal science, the more deranged it gets. The reason they are vague is because they don't know what they are talking about. They don't consider the real world, and as Bill Black's so brilliantly points out, they are in no hurry to out themselves as frauds. ..."
"... thanks, Simon. there must be something in those mental masturbation models for some people. justification for something the 99 % are all paying for most likely ..."
"... In some natural sciences, abandoning equilibrium models and replacing them with dynamic models have led to great progress, and looking at the actual time evolution of economies, there is a great deal of dynamics, such as growth, recessions, demography, natural catastrophes, immigration/emigration, resource discovery and depletion, technological progress. ..."
"... Since our economy has been gradually going casino for so many years, it makes sense that the folks who hold the reigns would make every effort to assure that all their key players adhere to their singular perspectives. ..."
"... The Nobel Memorial Prize in economics promotes the illusion that economics is a science. It is better conceptualized as a literary genre, and economists should be forced to compete with other writers for the prize in literature. ..."
"... Bill Black has a fascinating opinion on unnecessary complexity and I agree with him 200 percent. ..."
"... interesting about Kocherlakota formerly being a rational expectations devotee just the phrase 'rational expectations' is mind boggling as if there were no reaction to any action anywhere. Jack Bogle was on the news this morning laughing about stock picking and saying that every stock picker that makes money is balanced out by another one who loses money and so the only thing that makes money net-net is the long term progress of the market, (or society I would say – and that requires planning). ..."
"... Not one mention of Chaos or Catastrophe Theory, which are theories of systems with non linear feedback (aka: Fear and Greed), which appear to me to be fundamental aspects of Economics, especially the humans who are the Economy. ..."
"... Two slogans I read somewhere recently seem appropriate for theoclassical economics: Ideology is easy, thinking is hard. Belief is belonging. ..."
"... One doesn't have to have read any Reformation theology, but only to have observed more or less casually that human being are scarcely rational even about their own self-interest, and then only self-deceptively. Thomas Frank has commented effectively on that point in the political arena in What's the Matter with Kansas. To wit: Republicans have, he points out, diverted voters attention to social/cultural issues while picking their pockets. Perhaps one might sense an intersection of politics and economics on the latter point. ..."
Nov 21, 2016 | www.nakedcapitalism.com

By Bill Black, the author of The Best Way to Rob a Bank is to Own One and an associate professor of economics and law at the University of Missouri-Kansas City. Jointly published at New Economic Perspectives

Bloomberg has written an article about the origins of Paul Romer's increasingly famous critique of modern macroeconomics.

His intention actually had been to write a paper that would celebrate advances in the understanding of what drives economic growth. But when he sat down to write it in the months before taking over as the World Bank's chief economist, Romer quickly found his heart wasn't in it. The world economy wasn't growing much anyway; and the math that many colleagues were using to model it seemed unrealistic. He watched a documentary about the Church of Scientology, and was struck by how groupthink can operate.

So, Romer said in an interview at the Bank's Washington headquarters, "I just thought, OK, I'm going to say what I think. I don't know if I'm the right person, but no one else is going to say it. So I said it."

The upshot was "The Trouble With Macroeconomics," a scathing critique that landed among Romer's peers like a grenade.

A bit of background makes the first paragraph more understandable. Romer's specialty is developmental economics.

There are many economists who have said for years that modern macroeconomics is an abject failure. But all economists are not equal, and Romer is both an extremely distinguished economist and the World Bank's chief economist. When he writes that macroeconomics is absurd his position gets vastly more attention from the field.

The Bloomberg article humorously summarizes Romer's article.

"For more than three decades, macroeconomics has gone backwards," the paper began. Romer closed out his argument, some 20 pages later, by accusing a cohort of economists of drifting away from science, more interested in preserving reputations than testing their theories against reality, "more committed to friends than facts." In between, he offers a wicked parody of a modern macro argument: "Assume A, assume B, blah blah blah and so we have proven that P is true."

The idea that consumers and businesses always make rational choices pervades mainstream economics. Romer thinks that's not only wrong, but may lead to the misleading conclusion that government action can't fix big problems.

There is no better place to be writing this than from (nearly) Minneapolis, for the University of Minnesota's economics department is the most devoted coven worshipping the most extreme form of "rational expectations." The most famous cultists have now relocated, but the U. Minnesota economics department remains fanatical in its devotion to rational expectations theory.

A belief that consumers and businesses always make rational choices does not "pervade mainstream economics." Mainstream economics is increasingly influenced by reality, particularly in the form of behavioral economics. Behavioral economics, which has led to multiple Nobel awards, has many currents, but each of them agrees that consumers and business people typically do not make rational decisions even in simpler tasks, much less demonstrate the ability to predict the future required by rational expectations theory. Similarly, even the proponents of modern macroeconomics admit that its predictive ability – and predictive ability is supposed to be their holy grail of legitimacy – is beyond pathetic. What is true is that mainstream economics' most egregious errors have come from assuming contrary to reality in a wide range of contexts that corporate officers, consumers, and investors make optimal decisions that maximize the firm or the household's utility.

In any real scientific field modern macro would, decades ago, have been abandoned as an abject failure. Romer, therefore, is not storming some impregnable bulwark of economics. He is calling an obvious, abject failure an obvious, abject failure. Private sector finance participants typically believe the academic proponents of rational expectations theory are delusional. Romer is calling out elites in his profession who have ignored these failures and doubled and tripled-down on their failed dogmas for decades. This makes the Bloomberg article's title deeply misleading: "The Rebel Economist Who Blew Up Macroeconomics."

Romer is not a rebel. He did not blow up academic, mainstream macroeconomics – the academic proponents of modern macroeconomics blew it up decades ago. Romer is mainstream, and he is sympathetic on personal and ideological grounds to the theoclasscial economist most famous for developing rational expectations theory. Romer has strongly libertarian views and did his doctoral work under Robert Lucas. Romer has long been appreciative of Lucas. All of this means that Romer's denunciations were sure to hit home far harder with mainstream and theoclassical economists than anything a heterodox economist could write.

The same Bloomberg article made a key factual claim that is literally true but misleading.

What's at stake far exceeds hurt feelings in the ivory tower. Central banks and other policy makers use the models that Romer says are flawed.

Central banks and private economic forecasters rarely use modern macro models, though they have begun to use New Keynesian models that are hybrids. They do not do use "freshwater" models because they are known to have terrible predictive ability and because alternative models not based on rational expectations have far superior predictive ability. The private financial sector typically does not rely on modern macro models, even the New Keynesian hybrids. Romer is not saying that the models are "flawed" – he is explaining that they are inherently failed models. Worse, he is saying that the designers of the models know they are failed and respond by gimmicking the models by littering them with myriad assumptions that have no empirical or theoretical basis and are designed to try to make the models produce less absurd results.

I explained that Romer was far from the first to call out modern academic macroeconomics as a failure but that he is a prominent mainstream economist. The Bloomberg article's most interesting reveal was the response by the troika of economists must associated with rational expectations theory to Romer's article decrying their dogmas.

Lucas and Prescott didn't respond to requests for comments on Romer's paper. Sargent did. He said he hadn't read it, but suggested that Romer may be out of touch with the ways that rational-expectations economists have adapted their models to reflect how people and firms actually behave. Sargent said in an e-mail that Romer himself drew heavily on the school's insights, back when he was "still doing scientific work in economics 25 or 30 years ago."

What this paragraph reveals is the classic tactic of theoclassical economists – they simply ignore real criticism. Lucas, Prescott, and Sargent all care desperately about Romer's criticism – but they all refuse to engage substantively with his critique. One has to love the arrogance of Sargent in "responding" – without reading – to Romer's critique. Sargent cannot, of course, respond to a critique he has never read so he instead makes a crude attempt to insult Romer, asserting that Romer has not done any scientific work in three decades.

The rational expectations purists have been unable to come up with a response to their predictive failures and their false model of human behavior for thirty years. The Bloomberg article does not understand a subtle point about their non-defense defense, as shown in these key passages.

Allies of the three Nobelists have been more outspoken, and many of them point out that Romer - unlike Keynes in the 1930s - doesn't offer a new framework to replace the one he says has failed.

"Burning down the edifice, and saying we'll figure out what we'll build on its foundations later, just does not seem like a constructive way to proceed," said V. V. Chari, an economics professor at the University of Minnesota.

Romer's heard that line often, and bristles at it: "I'm saying, 'the car is broken.' And everyone's saying, 'Romer's a terrible guy, because he couldn't fix the car'."

What the rational expectations devotees are actually saying is their standard line, which is a radical departure from the scientific method. Their mantra is "it takes a model to beat a model." That mantra violates the scientific method. Their models are designed to embody their rational expectations theory. Those models' predictive ability is pathetic, which means that their theory and models are both falsified and should be rejected. The academic proponents of modern macro models, however, assert that their models are incapable of falsification by testing and predictive failure. This is not science, but theology.

V.V. Chari's criticism of Romer is revealing. He complains that Romer does not want to "build on [rational expectation theory's] foundations." Why would Romer want to commit such a pointless act? Romer's point is that rational expectations is a failed theory that needs to be rejected so macroeconomics can move on to useful endeavors.

A "foundation" in such a building metaphor is the deep, well-grounded stone or reinforced concrete beneath the visible building that is attached to solid bedrock. Rational expectations theory has no such empirical foundations. It was not based on testing that found that people behaved in accordance with the theory. Behavioral economics and finance, by contrast, is based on a growing empirical base – virtually all of which refutes the first three assumptions of the models. Similarly, the work of Akerlof (1970), Akerlof & Romer (1993), and the work of white-collar criminologists has falsified each of the first three assumptions of the models.

Further, the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models routinely fail the predictive test and, as Romer details, fail despite the use of dozens of ways in which the models are "gamed" with arbitrary inputs and restrictions that have no theoretical or empirical basis. Chari is right to describe the modern macro model as an "edifice." I would add that it is a baroque edifice top heavy with ornamental features designed to hide its lack of a foundation. Modern macro collapsed as soon as its devotees tried to build without an empirical foundation.

The rational expectation devotees respond that predictive failures – no matter how extreme or frequent – cannot falsify their models or their theories. The proponents claim that only a better model, with superior predictive ability can beat their model. That might sound acceptable to some, but there is a critical unstated twist. The many rival models actually used by the private sector and central banks that produce far superior predictive ability can never be treated as "better models" to these devotees because the models with far superior predictive powers reject rational expectations theory, rational decision-making, and the "budget constraint." To the devotees, only DSGE models that accept this trio of market fictions are eligible to be acceptable "models." Dr. Kocherlakota states that acceptable models "share five key features." These five characteristics define DSGE models.

They specify budget constraints for households, technologies for firms, and resource constraints for the overall economy. They specify household preferences and firm objectives. They assume forward-looking behavior for firms and households. They include the shocks that firms and households face. They are models of the entire macroeconomy.

Kocherlakota's summary description is appropriately terse. He later explains the dogmatic gloss that devotees place on each of these five points. The "budget constraint," for example, means that nations with sovereign currencies such as the U.S. cannot run deficits, even to fight severe recessions or depressions. Why? Because theoclassical economists are enormous believers in austerity. As Kocherlakota archly phrased the matter, "freshwater" DSGE models were so attractive to theoclassical macro types because their model perfectly tracked their ideology.

[A]lmost coincidentally-in these models, all government interventions (including all forms of stabilization policy) are undesirable.

Yes, "almost coincidentally."

Specifying household preferences and firm objectives is equally erroneous, as Akerlof and Romer's 1993 article on "Looting" demonstrated. "Firms" do not have "objectives." Employees have "objectives," and the controlling officers' "objectives" are the most powerful drivers of employee behavior.

As Akerlof and Romer (and every modern crisis) demonstrated, this frequently leads to firm practices that harm the firm, the consumer, and the shareholders. Such behavior, however, is impossible under the second assumption, so any model (such as control fraud or "looting") that violates the assumption is not eligible to be a rival model because it these superior models do not produce "general equilibrium." The "GE" in a "DSGE" model is general equilibrium, so rival models from economics and criminology that note that the economy is not a self-correcting apparatus that produces general equilibrium are ruled out as superior models even though they are superior in that they have an empirical and theoretical basis and demonstrate far superior predictive results.

Kocherlakota unintentionally highlighted modern macros' inability to incorporate even massive frauds driving national scandals and banking crises, despite the efforts of Akerlof (1970) (a market for "lemons") and Akerlof and Romer 1993: ("looting") in this passage.

In the macro models of the 1980s, all mutually beneficial trades occur without delay. This assumption of frictionless exchange made solving these models easy. However, it also made the models less compelling.

He then goes on to a delighted description of macro economists now sometimes building in (arbitrary) lags ("frictions") in the time required to accomplish "all mutually beneficial trades." But what of the three great fraud epidemics that produced the U.S. financial crisis and the Great Recession? Sorry, that's not allowed into the "friction" canon. The market model is still one of perfection (albeit slightly delayed). It does not matter how many massive financial scandals occur in which the largest UK banks and Wells Fargo deliberately abuse their customers by encouraging them to engage in transactions that will harm them and make the bankers rich. It doesn't not matter that over ten million Americans were induced by bankers and their agents to pay excessive interest rates in return for yield spread premiums (YSP) to the bankers and brokers. None of these things are allowed to happen in these models. Your better model, which includes such frauds and abuses, is not allowed precisely because it (a) is better and (b) falsifies the theoclassical ideology underlying "rational expectations" theory.

The assumption of "forward looking behavior" produces "expectations," which are assumed to be accurate and rational. Theoclassical proponents claim that we all have the ability to predict vast aspects of the financial future. While we are not perfect, we are optimal in our forecasts given the state of knowledge. If your rival model lacks rational expectations, it isn't a real model. Romer rejects the rational expectations myth, so he is incapable of presenting a superior model to the devotees of rational expectations.

If macroeconomics, outside the cult of modern macro, were a car, it would not be "broken." It would be episodically broken when the rational expectations devotees got hold of monetary or fiscal policy. The rational expectations model fails the most fundamental test of a financial model – people trying to make money by anticipating the macroeconomics consequences of changes in monetary and fiscal policy overwhelmingly do not use their models because they are known to have pathetic predictive ability. The alternative models that embrace Keynesian analysis and are not dependent on the fiction of rational expectations function pretty well. The real world macro car, when driven by real world drivers, works OK. Essentially, the rational expectations devotees say that we can never drive the macro "car" because the public will defeat any effort to drive the economy in any direction. Instead, the economy will lurch about n response to random technological "shocks" that cannot be predicted because they occur without any relationship to any public policy choices.

Romer takes particular delight in shredding the pretension to "science" in the model's abuse of shocks. Again, however, the Bloomberg article seriously misleads in making it appear that his critique of shocks is novel. Then Minneapolis Fed Chair Dr. Kocherlakota (formerly chair of the U. Minnesota economics department, where he was a "rational expectations" devotee) forcefully owned up to the egregious predictive failures of the models. He acknowledged that "macro models are driven by patently unrealistic shocks."

It is unfortunate that Bloomberg article about Romer's article is weak. It is useful, however, because its journalistic inquiry allows us to know how deep in their bunker Sargent, Lucas, and Prescott remain. They still refuse to engage substantively with Romer's critique of not only their failures but their intellectual dishonesty and cowardice. It is astonishing that multiple economists were awarded Nobel prizes for creating the increasingly baroque failure of modern macro. In any other field it would be a scandal that would shake the discipline to the core and cause it to reexamine how it conducted research and trained faculty. In economics, however, a huge proportion of Nobel awards have gone to theoclassical economists whose predictions have been routinely falsified and whose policy recommendations have proven disastrous. Theoclassical economists, with only a handful of exceptions, express no concern about these failures.

This entry was posted in Dubious statistics , Economic fundamentals , Guest Post , Macroeconomic policy , Market inefficiencies , Ridiculously obvious scams , The dismal science

Portia November 21, 2016 at 11:32 am

I am completely confused about the prediction of "rational choices". Do they include going bankrupt on purpose and letting your investors take the hit, burning your building down for the insurance money, hostile takeover behavior where businesses are run into the ground on purpose, tax strategies, people going on unemployment when they want a vacation from work, and on and on? These are decisions that have a rationale for the people who make them, and they have not been uncommon. Perhaps "economists" are best off observing not predicting "human behavior".

shinola November 21, 2016 at 11:47 am

I was fortunate enough to have an econ. prof. (mid 70's) who was also my student counselor tell me that unless I intended to work for the gov't or teach the subject, a degree in econ. was pointless. What's taught in class has very little to do with the real world.

Anyone who contends that econ is a "science" rather than philosophy is deluded or just trying to protect their place in the hierarchy. Seems that "physics envy" is never going away.

I'll see your DSGE model & raise with with the IBGYBG* model; in theory, you should win that hand but I'll be walking away with the actual money.

*(by the time this blows up) I'll Be Gone & You'll Be Gone

Simon November 21, 2016 at 12:17 pm

Portia,

I majored in economics. as you go up higher up into the dismal science, the more deranged it gets. The reason they are vague is because they don't know what they are talking about. They don't consider the real world, and as Bill Black's so brilliantly points out, they are in no hurry to out themselves as frauds.

Portia November 21, 2016 at 12:37 pm

thanks, Simon. there must be something in those mental masturbation models for some people. justification for something the 99 % are all paying for most likely

diptherio November 21, 2016 at 3:14 pm

The reason they are vague is because they don't know what they are talking about

Which also explains about 90% of the math

beth November 21, 2016 at 12:43 pm

Thanks again, Bill. A thanks to Paul Romer and Bloomberg too. How long will it take for the NYT , FT, The Guardian and WSJ to understand?

Do $$$ make one "smart?" /sarc

Ruben November 21, 2016 at 12:51 pm

I am not sure which is the greatest shortcoming of the macro-economy theory described by Black: rational expectations or global equilibrium?

In some natural sciences, abandoning equilibrium models and replacing them with dynamic models have led to great progress, and looking at the actual time evolution of economies, there is a great deal of dynamics, such as growth, recessions, demography, natural catastrophes, immigration/emigration, resource discovery and depletion, technological progress.

Jim A November 21, 2016 at 1:14 pm

I sometimes like to use the analogy of the famous failure of the Tacoma Narrows bridge failure. The engineers calculated the maximum force that the wind would have on the bridge, but didn't calculate the dynamic aerodynamic effect as the bridge deck swayed in the wind. The result was a spectacular failure.

Watt4Bob November 21, 2016 at 1:01 pm

Since our economy has been gradually going casino for so many years, it makes sense that the folks who hold the reigns would make every effort to assure that all their key players adhere to their singular perspectives.

The most important of these perspectives is that there is no higher human purpose than to make a lot of money, in essence, that greed is good.

Thus the problem facing economists worshiping at the altar of "rational expectations" is that the only rational expectation that is accepted as 'truly rational', is first and foremost, the love of money.

This leads to problems for businesses, as truly selfish, and money-motivated people are actually rare, as most people have a wide range of possible motivations working in their lives.

This is why business 'leaders' give prospective employees tests to find the people they can 'trust', which is to say find those who are motivated by money, which is the only motivating factor our masters find useful.

Of course those who are motivated exclusively by the love of money are also those who believe that austerity is the proper medicine for the rest of us.

There's one more thing about people who are motivated only by the need to accumulate money, they also tend to steal anything that isn't tied down.

This doesn't bother FIRE sector employers since they are only concerned to ferret-out those whose motivations might be polluted by inclinations other than greed.

Anyway, it seems to me that the importance of 'rational expectations' is in predicting the behavior of FIRE sector employees, not the economy as a whole.

As far as the bulk of humanity goes, the only true 'rational expectation' is that people have many and varied motivations that make it hard to predict their behavior.

shinola November 21, 2016 at 1:21 pm

Speaking of "going casino"

Hey Econ. Prof. – I'll see your DSGE model & raise with my IBGYBG** model. In theory, you'll win the hand but we'll see who actually walks away the money.

**(by the time this thing blows up) I'll Be Gone, You'll Be Gone

shinola November 21, 2016 at 1:41 pm

sorry for the repeat – prior disappeared then re-appeared nearly 2 hour later ???

dutch November 21, 2016 at 1:04 pm

The Nobel Memorial Prize in economics promotes the illusion that economics is a science. It is better conceptualized as a literary genre, and economists should be forced to compete with other writers for the prize in literature.

Disturbed Voter November 21, 2016 at 1:10 pm

We need to get back to basics, to the real economy of people and necessary supplies to support people. Model a simple city, with a simple agricultural hinterland. You can know how many bushels of grain equivalent are necessary for subsistence economy. You can know how many people you have in the countryside and in the city. You can know how many bushels of grain equivalent are in storage. You can estimate how much of the economy is barter and how much is cash purchase. You can know how much money is in circulation, and from those determine what velocity the money needs to have, to pay for all that bushels of grain equivalent. You don't need calculus, just arithmetic. End the sophistry and obscurity thru unnecessary complexity.

madame de farge November 21, 2016 at 3:20 pm

Bill Black has a fascinating opinion on unnecessary complexity and I agree with him 200 percent.

susan the other November 21, 2016 at 1:11 pm

interesting about Kocherlakota formerly being a rational expectations devotee just the phrase 'rational expectations' is mind boggling as if there were no reaction to any action anywhere. Jack Bogle was on the news this morning laughing about stock picking and saying that every stock picker that makes money is balanced out by another one who loses money and so the only thing that makes money net-net is the long term progress of the market, (or society I would say – and that requires planning).

Synoia November 21, 2016 at 1:45 pm

Not one mention of Chaos or Catastrophe Theory, which are theories of systems with non linear feedback (aka: Fear and Greed), which appear to me to be fundamental aspects of Economics, especially the humans who are the Economy.

To me that is a large omission.

Another Anon November 21, 2016 at 1:55 pm

Two slogans I read somewhere recently seem appropriate for theoclassical economics: Ideology is easy, thinking is hard. Belief is belonging.

Robin Kash November 21, 2016 at 1:57 pm

Perhaps an approach to a solution for economists who are rightly disgusted with the continuing failures of macroeconomics is to confess that economics is theology/philosophy and not science. Economics lands on the "mammon" side of serving God or mammon.

One doesn't have to have read any Reformation theology, but only to have observed more or less casually that human being are scarcely rational even about their own self-interest, and then only self-deceptively. Thomas Frank has commented effectively on that point in the political arena in What's the Matter with Kansas. To wit: Republicans have, he points out, diverted voters attention to social/cultural issues while picking their pockets. Perhaps one might sense an intersection of politics and economics on the latter point.

There is less need to moralize about "sin" than to see it as an heuristic. That is, one might begin by assuming that businesses and individuals are not only guided by rationality, but to the contrary are aided by economists, say, of the U of Minnesota ilk, to rely upon the myth of rationality to cloak fundamental selfishness, which economists have neutered by casting it as "self-interest." Selfishness is the root of continuing, destructive "irrationality," because it is part of what defines a root of sin, i.e., missing the mark.

An economics of gratitude for shared abundance would be closer to the mark.

diptherio November 21, 2016 at 4:28 pm

Here's the link to the paper by Romer:

http://www.law.yale.edu/system/files/area/workshop/leo/leo16_romer.pdf

[Nov 12, 2016] Do Economists Promote Ideology as Science?

Nov 12, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com
Economist's View Do Economists Promote Ideology as Science

My latest column:

Do Economists Promote Ideology as Science? : Which is more important in determining the policy positions of economists, ideology or evidence? Is economics, as some assert, little more than a means of dressing up ideological arguments in scientific clothing?
This certainly happens, especially among economists connected to politically driven think tanks – places like the Heritage Foundation come to mind. Economists who work for businesses also have a tendency to present evidence more like a lawyer advocating a particular position than a scientist trying to find out how the economy really works. But what about academic economists who are supposed to be searching for the truth no matter the political implications? Can we detect the same degree of bias in their research and policy positions? ...

rayward :

Thoma's assessment seems fair enough. I'd make the point that, for some academic economists, no amount of evidence is sufficient to overcome their bias. "Where's the proof" is the refrain one hears often. And then there's the question: what is evidence? The availability of lots of data is often used to "prove" this or that theory, even when the "proof" is contrary to the historical evidence one can see with her own eyes. Data used as obfuscation rather than clarification. I appreciate that one historical event following another historical event does not prove causation, but what's better proof than history.

RogerFox : , -1
"Shouldn't theory be a guide when the empirical evidence is unconvincing one way or the other?"

No - we don't allow MDs to prescribe or treat on the basis of theory alone. It's unethical for any professional practitioner to give advice that is not supported by compelling evidence demonstrating that the advise is both safe and effective - 'First, do no harm.'

To a man, professional economists shill for the view that they are morally free to treat real economies and real people as their personal lab rats. As a group, economists are an ethically challenged bunch in this respect, and probably in other respects too.

anne -> RogerFox... , -1
To a man, professional economists shill...

[ This phrase begins a mean-spirited lie, no matter how the sentence is finished. The point of the malicious post however is only to be destructive. ]

Avraam Jack Dectis : , -1
.
Economics is the most interesting science because it is not settled and has great effect upon the affairs of man.

One of the things that make it interesting is the number of variables that exist in most economic situations as well as the strong psychological and sociological component to the science, due to its attempts to predict the actions of humans, a hierarchical herd based status insane animal.

Undoubtedly, the desire to promote personally attractive policies is something everyone must fight.

On a side note, having seen this blog referenced elsewhere and finally starting to read it regularly, truly a nice thing, I notice that Dr. Thoma and I are the same age for about three months per year. I suspect that is about all we have in common since I just spent the last 18+ years getting openly and notoriously poisoned by a stalker gang, have hit men following me and am so unpopular and poorly connected that I seem remarkably unable to engage any law enforcement on the issue.

Which leads into the next point-> Is the dynamism of an economy a function of freedom of speech, riule of law, security of the citizen and so forth. For decades the USA, as it fought two opposing powerful systems, made that case yet now that no longer seems to be the case in the USA and in fact this is confirmed by the fact that nobody makes that case convincingly anymore.

Can this deterioration of culture and embrace of expediency have a stifling economic effect?

DeDude : , -1
Economics as a science is mainly hurt by two things.

1. The rich plutocrats have a major stake in advocating very specific narratives, so they will throw large sums behind those narratives (and the fight against anything conflicting with them).

2. Economics does not have anything resembling the double blind placebo controlled trials that help medicine fight off the narratives of those with money and power.

RGC : , -1
What sort of opinions are economists allowed to have if they want tenure, want to be published in the major journals or want to make a living?

Keynes concluded that government direction was necessary for a viable economy. Keynes' "interpreters" in the US buried that idea, and thus became very important economists - guys like Paul Samuelson. The first ( and only) US book to faithfully represent Keynes' ideas faded away soon after publication.

http://news.stanford.edu/pr/93/931011Arc3112.html

pete : , -1
I did not know there was a debate. Krugman summed it all up in Peddling Prosperity. Folks know who pays the rent, and opine accordingly.
Syaloch : , -1
I think problems arise when economists are called upon by politicians or the media to give expert advice.

Within the sciences, "We don't know the answer to that" is a perfectly acceptable response, and in scientific fields where the stakes are low that response is generally accepted by the public as well. "What is dark matter made of?" "We don't know yet, but we're working on it." But in politics, where the stakes are higher, not having a definitive answer is viewed as a sign of weakness. How often do you hear a politician responding to a "gotcha" question admit that they don't know the answer rather than trying to BS their way through?

Given the timeliness of news coverage the media prefer to consult experts who offer definitive answers, especially given their preference for pro/con type interviews which require experts on both sides of an issue. Economists who are put on the spot this way feel pressured to ditch the error bars and give unambiguous answers, even answers based purely on theory with little to no empirical backing, and the more often they do this the more often they're invited back.

Sandwichman : , November 03, 2015 at 08:47 AM
It is impossible to talk about economics without making essentially ideological distinctions. Private property and wage labor are not "natural" categories. Their adequacy as human practices therefore needs to be either defended or criticized. To simply take them "as given" is an ideological waffle that begs THE question.

Economists thus SHOULD have, acknowledge and fully disclose their ideological biases. When evaluating evidence they should make every effort to set aside and overcome their biases. And they need to stay humble about how Sisyphean, incongruous and incomplete their attempts at objectivity are.

Let's not forget that "The End of Ideology" was a polemical tract aimed at designating the ideology of the managers and symbol manipulators "above" and beyond ideology. Similarly, Marx's brilliant critique of ideology degenerated into polemic as its practitioners adopted the mantle of "science."

anne -> Sandwichman ... , November 03, 2015 at 08:56 AM
Really excellent, and why I am immediately wary of self-described "technocrats."
anne -> Sandwichman ... , November 03, 2015 at 08:58 AM
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_End_of_Ideology

The End of Ideology: On the Exhaustion of Political Ideas in the Fifties is a collection of essays published in 1960 by Daniel Bell, who described himself as a "socialist in economics, a liberal in politics, and a conservative in culture". He suggests that the older, grand-humanistic ideologies derived from the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries had been exhausted, and that new, more parochial ideologies would soon arise. He argues that political ideology has become irrelevant among "sensible" people, and that the polity of the future would be driven by piecemeal technological adjustments of the extant system.

anne -> Sandwichman ... , November 03, 2015 at 09:00 AM
What precisely is "Marx's critique of ideology ?"
Sandwichman said in reply to anne... , November 03, 2015 at 09:54 AM
A very big question! Like "what is the meaning of life?" At least a semester-long upper division seminar course. ;-)

In a nutshell (to put it crudely), Marx labelled as ideologists a cohort of German followers of Hegel's philosophy who envisioned historical progress as the result of the progressive refinement of intellectual ideas. Marx argued instead that historical change resulted from struggle between social classes over the material conditions of life, fundamental to which was the transformation of nature through human intervention into means of subsistence.

anne -> Sandwichman ... , November 03, 2015 at 10:26 AM
Marx labelled as ideologists a cohort of German followers of Hegel's philosophy who envisioned historical progress as the result of the progressive refinement of intellectual ideas. Marx argued instead that historical change resulted from struggle between social classes over the material conditions of life, fundamental to which was the transformation of nature through human intervention into means of subsistence.

[ What a superb introductory or summary explanation. I could not be more impressed or grateful. ]

anne -> Sandwichman ... , November 03, 2015 at 10:27 AM
I intend to quote this passage, crediting and thanking you.
DrDick -> Sandwichman ... , November 03, 2015 at 11:02 AM
Well said. I would add "markets" to that list of rleatively recent cultural constructs that needs greater scrutiny.
Chuck : , November 03, 2015 at 09:10 AM
"And so - though we proceed slowly because of our ideologies, we might not proceed at all without them."
- Joseph Schumpeter, "Science and Ideology," The American Economic Review 39:2 (March 1949), at 359
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1812737
Sandwichman said in reply to Chuck... , November 03, 2015 at 10:09 AM
Indeed.
Ignacio : , November 03, 2015 at 10:11 AM
Many guys are not driven by ideology, rather than evidence. The problem with this article is that we cannot compare with other professions and say "economists are more/less prone to promote ideology than the average".
DrDick -> Ignacio... , November 03, 2015 at 11:04 AM
All human endeavors are shaped by "ideology" in many different ways. What is important is to be aware of and explicit about their influences on our thought and action.
RC AKA Darryl, Ron : , November 03, 2015 at 11:12 AM
Yes.
RC AKA Darryl, Ron said in reply to RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , November 03, 2015 at 11:24 AM
If there are two sides to an argument that radically disagree then it is possible that both sides may be ideology, but both sides cannot be science. Only the correct argument can be science. Of course ideology is a bit too kind of a word since the incorrect argument is actually just a con game by people out to lay claim on greater unearned wealth.
ken melvin : , November 03, 2015 at 11:22 AM
Economists seem content with trying to figure out how to make 'it' work. Far better, I think, to try and figure out how it should be.
It was philosophers such as Hume, Locke, Marx, Smith, Rawls, ... who asked the right questions. Laws and economics come down to us according to how we think about such things; they change when we change the way we think. Seems we're in a bit of a philosophical dry patch, here. Someday, we will have to develop a better economic system, might be now. Likewise, there are laws rooted in antiquity that were wrong then and are wrong still.
RC AKA Darryl, Ron said in reply to ken melvin... , November 03, 2015 at 11:25 AM
Exactly! They all know what they are doing. Some of them are just trying to do the wrong thing.
Arne : , November 03, 2015 at 12:12 PM
"Ideology certainly influences which questions academic researchers believe are the most important, but there is nothing wrong with that."

No "experiment" in economics comes with the degree of control that experiments in physical sciences take for granted, so there is tremendous room for ideology to come into the discussion of whether a data set really represents the conditions the model is supposed to consider. Since reviewing another economist's study entails asking questions those questions...

DrDick -> Arne... , -1
Please describe the "experimentation" which takes place in astronomy and geology. Ideologies also play important roles in experimental sciences, such as biology (for which we have a lot of evidence.

http://www.amazon.com/Anne-Fausto-Sterling/e/B001ILMB3E

http://www.nature.com/news/let-s-think-about-cognitive-bias-1.18520

http://annals.org/article.aspx?articleid=733696

[Nov 06, 2016] Michael Hudson on Meet the Renegades

Notable quotes:
"... In fact, I would posit that the Ivy League, especially Yale, Princeton, Harvard and MIT, are the principal crime factories in America today. ..."
"... Brownback is in Kansas; UMKC is in Missouri. There is a Kansas City in Kansas, and another Kansas City in Missouri. Missouri is not as red as KS, but it's still a red state. ..."
"... UMKC is part of the state system and most likely receives no funding from the city. It was home to New Letters, a respected literary magazine edited by poet John Ciardi. I hail from Kanasa City and always thought of UMKC as a decent commuter school, mostly catering to the educational needs of adult city dwellers. But the evolution of both the Econ and jazz studies departments lead me to suspect things have changed. Whether that's by design or through organic happenstance I don't know. ..."
"... Couldn't a Marxian analysis of capitalism as a whole also shed some light on this issue? I think Hudson is pretty much right but I think, like Sanders, he's offering a reformist option as opposed to a full on critique of the entire system. ..."
"... Not that a revolution is the option you necessarily want to go with, I just think that Marx's criticism of capitalism has useful information that could help with shaping the perspective here. ..."
Nov 05, 2016 | www.nakedcapitalism.com
Michael Hudson spends a half hour with Meet the Renegades explaining his views on money, finance, economic training, rentier capitalism, and how debt overhangs operate. Hudson fans will recognize his regular themes. This is a good segment for introducing people you know to Hudson and to heterodox economic ideas.

EndOfTheWorld November 5, 2016 at 5:52 am

I've always found it interesting that both Hudson and Bill Black are on the faculty of UMKC, which is a state university in a pretty conservative state. It's possible that some of the funding for UMKC comes from the municipality of Kansas City, MO, but that town has never been known as a hotbed of radical intellectuality either.

Distrubed Voter November 5, 2016 at 6:21 am

Joseph Campbell didn't teach at an Ivy League either. Conformity starts with the faculty in your own department … and the Ivy League is as status quo and status conscious as it gets.

craazyboy November 5, 2016 at 8:43 am

The Ivy League are not much different than privately held corporations when you consider who their alma materi are, how much money the alma materi have, and where Ivy League endowments come from.

sgt_doom November 5, 2016 at 1:31 pm

In fact, I would posit that the Ivy League, especially Yale, Princeton, Harvard and MIT, are the principal crime factories in America today.

Please recall that the dood who financed Liberty Lobby and other white supremacist nonsense was Koch family patriarch, Fred Koch, who was a trustee at MIT. (Ever hear Noam Chomsky complain about that????? Of course not!)

a different chris November 5, 2016 at 8:40 am

Ah but is it really an inherently conservative state fiscally, or just socially? That is, are the people like Brownback appealing to one sort of conservatism and using that to do a "trust me" on the other sort?

I would say it's not unreasonable for anybody to delegate something they are not so sure of to somebody they trust for other reasons.

EndOfTheWorld November 5, 2016 at 11:11 am

Brownback is in Kansas; UMKC is in Missouri. There is a Kansas City in Kansas, and another Kansas City in Missouri. Missouri is not as red as KS, but it's still a red state.

Randy November 5, 2016 at 8:53 am

UMKC is part of the state system and most likely receives no funding from the city. It was home to New Letters, a respected literary magazine edited by poet John Ciardi. I hail from Kanasa City and always thought of UMKC as a decent commuter school, mostly catering to the educational needs of adult city dwellers. But the evolution of both the Econ and jazz studies departments lead me to suspect things have changed. Whether that's by design or through organic happenstance I don't know.

Moneta November 5, 2016 at 8:59 am

If you are not on the money makers' distribution list, it would make sense to find other ways to get some of that loot if you can't the traditional way…

You can be conservative in your social values but want change, i.e. liberalism, in the way the monetary system distributes the money.

Steve H. November 5, 2016 at 10:47 am

Thank Warren Mosler, wouldn't be there without his direct support.

EndOfTheWorld November 5, 2016 at 7:32 am

Well, little UMKC can claim to be pretty much "cutting edge" in economics with these two stalwarts on their faculty.

Benedict@Large November 5, 2016 at 9:32 am

The UMKC is also the home of the Kansas City School of Economics, more commonly known as the MMT School. Neither Hudson nor Black are MMTers per se, but both have grown by their affiliation with the school.

Amateur Socialist November 5, 2016 at 9:14 am

Thanks for sharing this excellent interview. Watching it I realized the people I actually admire more than Hudson are his students. They must care more about learning the truth than securing wealth and job prospects on wall street.

susan the other November 5, 2016 at 11:04 am

fun to learn how Hudson fired Greenspan way back when

EndOfTheWorld November 5, 2016 at 11:08 am

lol "Free trade" is Orwellian word usage.

King Arthur November 5, 2016 at 11:49 am

Couldn't a Marxian analysis of capitalism as a whole also shed some light on this issue? I think Hudson is pretty much right but I think, like Sanders, he's offering a reformist option as opposed to a full on critique of the entire system.

Not that a revolution is the option you necessarily want to go with, I just think that Marx's criticism of capitalism has useful information that could help with shaping the perspective here.

BecauseTradition November 5, 2016 at 12:29 pm

The solution is write down the debt. Michael Hudson

Why not Steve Keen's "A Modern Jubilee" since non-debtors have been cheated by the system too?

Steve in Dallas November 5, 2016 at 12:46 pm

I asked Yves Smith at the Dallas meetup last week (paraphrasing) "Do you meet with Michael Hudson and Bill Black… is the independent media community, or any community, organizing around Michael Hudson and Bill Black… to not only support and promote Hudson's and Black's perspectives but to help develop their concepts and 'fine tune' their messaging?" I said to Yves "Hudson and Black are clearly the leaders we desperately need to rally behind and push into Washington… they clearly know what needs to be done… a PR machine needs to be developed… to get their messages out to our families, friends, and acquaintances… unfortunately, the current messaging is not good enough… I can't get my family, friends, and others to engage and echo the messaging to their family, friends, etc."

Michael Hudson has been good at repeating his central message… 'by increasing land, monopoly, and finance rent costs… the 1% are a highly organized mafia methodically looting our economy… effectively raping, pillaging and consequently destroying every component of our social structures'.

Very unfortunately, Bill Blacks central message seems to have been lost for years now… he doesn't repeat his central message… 'the crimes must be stopped… there is no alternative… looting criminals MUST be publicly exposed, investigated, indicted, prosecuted, convicted, punished and their loot returned to society… by letting cheaters prosper, organized white-collar crime, perpetrated by the top-most leaders of our public and private institutions, has become an epidemic… the very fabric of civil society is being destroyed… we have no choice… the criminals must be stopped… and the only way to do that is to publicly expose, investigate, indict, prosecute, punish, and take back what is ours'.

In 2008, when I tuned out of the mainstream media and tuned into the independent media, I thought the messages from Michael Hudson ("they are organized criminals… this is what they're doing…") and Bill Black ("the criminals must be stopped… here's how we stopped the Savings & Loan criminals…) would resonate and become common knowledge. I quickly discovered that it didn't even resonate with close family and friends. Why???

I will send out this video… Michael Hudson at his best, speaking-wise. I don't expect to get any reaction… why?… very frustrated…

Ivy November 5, 2016 at 1:35 pm

Amen. Once you start noticing, it becomes hard to stop. In looking hard for a silver lining to the current election storm clouds, public awareness of the MSM seems to have nudged a few toward slightly more objectivity, although I may just be wishing for that after media fatigue ;)

[Oct 29, 2016] Output gap is is subject to two big measurement problems

Oct 29, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com

Peter K. : October 29, 2016 at 07:11 AM

David Beckworth on the "knowledge problem."

"...That is, even central banks that follow some kind of Taylor rule in a flexible inflation-targeting regime are susceptible to the knowledge problem...

The biggest information challenge comes from attempting to measure the output gap in real time. The output gap is the difference between the economy's actual and potential level of output and is subject to two big measurement problems.

  1. First, real-time output data generally get revised and often on the same order of magnitude as the estimated output gap itself.
  2. Second, potential output estimates are based on trends that rely on ever-changing endpoints.

Orphanides finds the latter problem to be the biggest contributor to real-time misperceptions of the output gap. This means that even if real-time data improved such that there were fewer revisions, there would still be a sizable problem measuring the real-time output gap."

Conservative ideologues tell us government/central planners are inefficient because of the "knowledge problem." Well so are private sector central planners. See the big banks and the housing bubble/financial crisis. Or Samsung and its exploding Note 7. Or Volkswagon and its cheating on benchmark tests.

RGC -> Peter K.... , October 29, 2016 at 08:23 AM

This "output gap" is another rightwing diversion. It is useful to them precisely because it is impossible to measure and therefore people can argue about it ad infinitum.

Meanwhile we have a lot of people who can't get a decent job at a living wage. That can be easily measured and it could be easily remedied. And it is what average people actually care about. So they want to make sure that isn't discussed. They want to discuss something with no clear answer instead.

Peter K. -> RGC... , October 29, 2016 at 09:31 AM
There is a clear answer. Inflation is low and there's an output gap. Yes maybe it's hard to get a precise number but we have a general idea.

I suppose you want us on the Gold Standard, another rightwing diversion, because according to you monetary policy doesn't work at all.

Peter K. -> RGC... , October 29, 2016 at 09:45 AM
I find it much more telling:

"Former Fed Vice Chairman Alan Blinder said he's skeptical that fiscal policy will be loosened a great deal if Clinton wins the election, as seems likely based on recent voter surveys.

"She is promising not to make budget deficits bigger by her programs," said Blinder, who is now a professor at Princeton University. "Whatever fiscal stimulus there is ought to be small enough for the Fed practically to ignore it.""

http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-10-25/fed-inclined-to-raise-rates-if-next-president-pumps-up-budget

Blinder is skeptical that Clinton will do enough to force the Fed to modulate their plans, even though PGL and Sanjait tell us otherwise.

Clinton's infrastructure plans should be "substantially" larger as Krugman and Summers write. This would help close the output gap. This would help with the job market and increasing incomes and lowering personal debt loads.

But PGL can't admit this because he's a petulant child who thinks Germany still uses the Deutsche Mark.

Peter K. -> Peter K.... , October 29, 2016 at 09:46 AM
As Bernie Sanders wrote last December:

"The recent decision by the Fed to raise interest rates is the latest example of the rigged economic system. Big bankers and their supporters in Congress have been telling us for years that runaway inflation is just around the corner. They have been dead wrong each time. Raising interest rates now is a disaster for small business owners who need loans to hire more workers and Americans who need more jobs and higher wages. As a rule, the Fed should not raise interest rates until unemployment is lower than 4 percent. Raising rates must be done only as a last resort - not to fight phantom inflation."

http://www.nytimes.com/2015/12/23/opinion/bernie-sanders-to-rein-in-wall-street-fix-the-fed.html

[Oct 27, 2016] Being Honest about Ideological Influence in Economics

Notable quotes:
"... An important essay indeed in that ideological influence is pervasive in writing by economists, which should be no problem as such, but economists should be aware of ideological influence in the work that they do. The problem is being unaware that work is ideological, so that the work is presented as simple truth allowing for no alternative presentation and argument. ..."
"... RBC economists are very well compensated for saying that no government intervention is needed in the economy, as are those saying that minimum wages harm employment. ..."
"... Actually a lot of academics are not exactly paid that well. This crowd does this sort as a religion. The problem is that those of us who never accepted perfect markets and instant market clearing were closed out of publications for 30 years. Now if RBC explained the real world - fine. But it had zero explanation for the last 9 years. ..."
"... Mankiw is paid well. ..."
"... Krugman is paid well. ..."
"... Speaking as an academic, in the university system with the lowest paid faculty in the nation, I am well aware of that. It is not the academic salaries, but the research grants and consulting contracts that matter here. ..."
"... Upton Sinclair is always right. ..."
"... "I suspect there is a reluctance among the majority of economists to admit that some among them may not be following the scientific method but may instead be making choices on ideological grounds." ..."
"... The RBC crowd is arrogant enough to argue that Keynes was practicing junk science. They knew his writings and just ignored it. ..."
"... That US economists are completely clueless is obvious to anyone who travels around the world. That free trade economies such as the US are complete basket cases is obvious to anyone who visits mercantilist economies such as Singapore, Japan, Israel etc. US trained economists only have prestige because the masses don't know how backward and poverty-stricken the US has become under the policies they relentlessly justify and apologize for. ..."
Oct 27, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com
Simon Wren-Lewis:
Being honest about ideological influence in economics : Noah Smith has an article that talks about Paul Romer's recent critique of macroeconomics. ... He says the fundamental problem with macroeconomics is lack of data, which is why disputes seem to take so long to resolve. That is not in my view the whole story.

If we look at the rise of Real Business Cycle (RBC) research a few decades ago, that was only made possible because economists chose to ignore evidence about the nature of unemployment in recessions. There is overwhelming evidence that in a recession employment declines because workers are fired rather than choosing not to work, and that the resulting increase in unemployment is involuntary (those fired would have rather retained their job at their previous wage). Both facts are incompatible with the RBC model.

In the RBC model there is no problem with recessions, and no role for policy to attempt to prevent them or bring them to an end. The business cycle fluctuations in employment they generate are entirely voluntary. RBC researchers wanted to build models of business cycles that had nothing to do with sticky prices. Yet here again the evidence was quite clear...

Why would researchers try to build models of business cycles where these cycles required no policy intervention, and ignore key evidence in doing so? The obvious explanation is ideological. I cannot prove it was ideological, but it is difficult to understand why - in an area which as Noah says suffers from a lack of data - you would choose to develop theories that ignore some of the evidence you have. The fact that, as I argue here , this bias may have expressed itself in the insistence on following a particular methodology at the expense of others does not negate the importance of that bias. ...

I suspect there is a reluctance among the majority of economists to admit that some among them may not be following the scientific method but may instead be making choices on ideological grounds. This is the essence of Romer's critique, first in his own area of growth economics and then for business cycle analysis. Denying or marginalizing the problem simply invites critics to apply to the whole profession a criticism that only applies to a minority.

anne : October 26, 2016 at 10:52 AM
An important essay indeed in that ideological influence is pervasive in writing by economists, which should be no problem as such, but economists should be aware of ideological influence in the work that they do. The problem is being unaware that work is ideological, so that the work is presented as simple truth allowing for no alternative presentation and argument.
anne -> anne... , October 26, 2016 at 11:03 AM
From the influence of The Economist:

http://www.bradford-delong.com/2016/04/must-read-i-do-not-understand-china-but-it-now-looks-more-likely-than-not-to-me-that-xi-jinpings-rule-will-lose-china.html

April 5, 2016

I do not understand China. But it now looks more likely than not to me that Xi Jinping's rule will lose China a decade, if not half a century... *

* http://www.economist.com/news/china/21695923-his-exercise-power-home-xi-jinping-often-ruthless-there-are-limits-his

-- Brad DeLong

anne -> anne... , October 26, 2016 at 11:04 AM
Again, on the influence of The Economist:

https://twitter.com/barryeisler/status/789620951663063040

Barry Eisler ‏@barryeisler

This could be a poster for a horror movie. But it's just the sane, sober, centrist @TheEconomist, doing what they do best

https://pbs.twimg.com/media/CvVLw8PVYAAaLQX.jpg

5:14 PM - 21 Oct 2016

anne -> kthomas... , October 26, 2016 at 11:32 AM
The point of Sophocles Oedipus cycle for Sophocles and for Freud was found in the Oracle at Delphi with which the cycle begins. The inscription at Delphi read "Know Thyself."

Know your ideological bent or leaning. The tragedy of Oedipus was in not knowing himself.

kthomas -> anne... , October 26, 2016 at 11:59 AM
The original "know thyself" was for warriors. For if you do not know yourself (or your limitations), how can you possibly defeat an enemy?

The later Greek philosophers took it to heart, I suppose.

anne -> kthomas... , October 26, 2016 at 05:23 PM
Interesting, but Freud surely took "know thyself" to heart.
anne -> anne... , October 26, 2016 at 02:09 PM
http://www.bradford-delong.com/2016/08/fidel-castros-85th-birthday.html

August 14, 2016

It's Fidel Castro's 90th Birthday!

Under Fidel Castro's rule Cuba bucked the historical trend--moving not toward but far away from political democracy.

Under Fidel Castro it looks as though Cuba lost two generations of economic growth -- generations that other neighboring economies like Mexico, Costa Rica, and Puerto Rico made very good use of. The only good thing you can say about Castro is that Cuba continued to have the social indicators of a middle-income country even as it became a poor one.

It was always incomprehensible that an anti-Democratic dictator who managed to turn a middle-income country into a poor one would have fans. Yet there are still people in the class not of stooges looking for their Stalin, but fools who have found their Fidel.

-- Brad DeLong

[ Importantly, the economics here happen to be wildly wrong but is there any concern about how Cuba actually fared in real per capita growth relative to Mexico, Costa Rica or Puerto Rico since 1971 when record keeping begins?

The concern seem to be entirely ideological. ]

anne -> anne... , October 26, 2016 at 02:11 PM
https://fred.stlouisfed.org/graph/?g=6Ea6

August 4, 2014

Real per capita Gross Domestic Product for Brazil, Mexico and Cuba, 1971-2013

(Percent change)


https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/graph/?g=2P3h

August 4, 2014

Real per capita Gross Domestic Product for Mexico and Cuba, 1971-2013

(Indexed to 1971)

anne -> anne... , October 26, 2016 at 03:05 PM
Since 1971, real per capita GDP in Cuba has grown faster than real per capita GDP in Mexico, Guatemala, El Salvador, Nicaragua, Costa Rica and Panama, faster than in Puerto Rico, Jamaica, Trinidad and Bermuda, faster than in Colombia, Venezuela, Brazil and Argentina, faster than in Ecuador, Bolivia, Uruguay and Paraguay, faster than in Spain and Portugal.

Real per capita growth in the Dominican Republic and Chile alone among Spanish or Portuguese language countries has been faster than in Cuba.

anne -> anne... , October 26, 2016 at 03:13 PM
Being forgetful:

Since 1971, real per capita GDP in Cuba has also grown faster than real per capita GDP in Honduras...

Data for Haiti begin in 1999, but sadly Haiti has been continually beset since then.

anne -> anne... , October 26, 2016 at 03:36 PM
Being forgetful again:

Since 1971, real per capita GDP in Cuba has also grown faster than real per capita GDP in Peru...

Correcting:

Since 1971, real per capita GDP in Cuba has grown slightly slower than real per capita GDP in Paraguay...

Completing:

Since 1971, real per capita GDP in Cuba has grown faster than real per capita GDP in Mexico, Guatemala, El Salvador, Honduras, Nicaragua, Costa Rica and Panama, faster than in Puerto Rico, Jamaica, Trinidad and Bermuda, faster than in Colombia, Venezuela, Peru, Brazil and Argentina, faster than in Ecuador, Bolivia and Uruguay, faster than in Spain and Portugal.

Real per capita growth in the Dominican Republic, Chile and Paraguay alone among Spanish or Portuguese language countries has been faster than in Cuba.

DrDick : , October 26, 2016 at 11:08 AM
RBC economists are very well compensated for saying that no government intervention is needed in the economy, as are those saying that minimum wages harm employment.
pgl -> DrDick... , October 26, 2016 at 12:33 PM
Actually a lot of academics are not exactly paid that well. This crowd does this sort as a religion. The problem is that those of us who never accepted perfect markets and instant market clearing were closed out of publications for 30 years. Now if RBC explained the real world - fine. But it had zero explanation for the last 9 years.
Peter K. -> pgl... , October 26, 2016 at 12:58 PM
"RBC economists are very well compensated for saying that no government intervention is needed in the economy"

"Actually a lot of academics are not exactly paid that well."

Mankiw is paid well.

pgl -> Peter K.... , October 26, 2016 at 02:49 PM
I write "a lot" and you read "all". More evidence that my internet stalker flunked pre-K. BTW - Mankiw is not part of the RBC crowd but PeterK is too stupid to know that. Geesh.
JohnH -> pgl... , October 26, 2016 at 01:17 PM
Krugman is paid well. At least his ideological basis is clear...'liberal.'
http://nypost.com/2014/04/17/cuny-to-pay-economist-paul-krugman-225000/
pgl -> JohnH... , October 26, 2016 at 01:51 PM
Lord - what a stupid comment. Krugman does make his believes against evidence. I see this is another post you did not bother to read before posting one of your patented pointless rants.
JohnH -> pgl... , October 26, 2016 at 02:27 PM
Love it: "Krugman does make his believes against evidence."

pgl doesn't even bother to read his own rants before he sends them...

pgl -> JohnH... , October 26, 2016 at 02:49 PM
Make - mark. Wow - you actually read something finally.
DrDick -> pgl... , October 26, 2016 at 04:57 PM
Speaking as an academic, in the university system with the lowest paid faculty in the nation, I am well aware of that. It is not the academic salaries, but the research grants and consulting contracts that matter here.
anne -> DrDick... , October 26, 2016 at 05:25 PM
Speaking as an academic, in the university system with the lowest paid faculty in the nation, I am well aware of that. It is not the academic salaries, but the research grants and consulting contracts that matter here.

[ Understood and important. ]

anne -> pgl... , October 26, 2016 at 05:24 PM
The problem is that those of us who never accepted perfect markets and instant market clearing were closed out of publications for 30 years....

[ Interesting and important. ]

anne -> DrDick... , October 26, 2016 at 05:21 PM
RBC economists are very well compensated for saying that no government intervention is needed in the economy, as are those saying that minimum wages harm employment.

[ Important. ]

DrDick -> anne... , October 27, 2016 at 07:27 AM
Upton Sinclair is always right.
anne : , October 26, 2016 at 11:11 AM
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Real_business-cycle_theory

Real business-cycle theory (RBC theory) are a class of New Classical macroeconomics models in which business-cycle fluctuations to a large extent can be accounted for by real (in contrast to nominal) shocks. Unlike other leading theories of the business cycle, RBC theory sees business cycle fluctuations as the efficient response to exogenous changes in the real economic environment. That is, the level of national output necessarily maximizes expected utility, and governments should therefore concentrate on long-run structural policy changes and not intervene through discretionary fiscal or monetary policy designed to actively smooth out economic short-term fluctuations.

According to RBC theory, business cycles are therefore "real" in that they do not represent a failure of markets to clear but rather reflect the most efficient possible operation of the economy, given the structure of the economy.

Sandwichman : , October 26, 2016 at 11:40 AM
"I suspect there is a reluctance among the majority of economists to admit that some among them may not be following the scientific method but may instead be making choices on ideological grounds."

Cogito ergo [I suspect] sum.

Julio -> Sandwichman ... , October 26, 2016 at 12:42 PM
Wait, wait, it's not "sum". What is the Latin for "publish"?
Paul Mathis : , October 26, 2016 at 11:49 AM
How is the ridiculous RBC theory different from saying, as many prominent economists do, that presidents do not significantly influence economic growth and job creation?

Thus, I have heard repeatedly that FDR, Reagan, Clinton and Obama should not get credit for the economic recoveries and job creation that occurred during their presidencies. Likewise, Hoover, Carter and the Bushes should not be blamed for the economic debacles that occurred during their presidencies. Apparently, these were all just real business cycles that no president has responsibility for.

Of course voters do not agree at all, re-electing all of the "lucky" presidents while throwing out all of the "unlucky" ones. For example, Carter, who is now regarded as a good president, was buried in a massive landslide: 489-49 by a second rate actor who was regarded as a fool by many. (Trump will outperform Carter!)

Either RBC is correct or presidents and their policies do matter a lot. Economists have to decide where they stand.

pgl -> Paul Mathis... , October 26, 2016 at 12:31 PM
The RBC crowd never really got that much into politics. Of course assuming markets always clear and are perfect in every other way is a silly way to model a real world economy.
pgl : , October 26, 2016 at 12:29 PM
Trump bragged today that he built this Washington DC hotel under budget. It seems he did by hiring undocumented workers at less than minimum wages:

https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/post-politics/wp/2016/10/26/clinton-slams-trump-for-using-undocumented-labor-to-build-d-c-hotel/

Maybe Greg Mankiw now likes TrumpEconomics.

pgl : , October 26, 2016 at 12:37 PM
"you would choose to develop theories that ignore some of the evidence you have". It first this New Classical/RBC crowd put forth all sorts of fancy new econometrics thinking if you looked at the data the right way, their model would be confirmed. Only problem is their model says aggregate demand can have only very transitional effects but the data show persistent effects. Shocks in other words have sustained real effects.

So when their model was shown to be faulty by the evidence, they gave up on econometrics and turned to calibration which is just fancy math designed to hide the failure of their models.

pgl : , October 26, 2016 at 12:41 PM
SWL continues noting David Card's research on the effects of increases in minimum wages:

'As Card points out in the interview his research involved no advocacy, but was simply about examining empirical evidence. So the friends that he lost objected not to the policy position he was taking, but to him uncovering and publishing evidence. Suppressing or distorting evidence because it does not give the answer you want is almost a definition of an illegitimate science.'

Greg Mankiw searches high and low for anything that goes along with his view that higher wage floors lead to less employment demand. Of course this kind of bias favors people like Donald Trump who built that DC hotel under budget by ignoring the minimum wage laws.

Longtooth : , October 26, 2016 at 01:05 PM
Much of the economic models debates hinge on "sticky wages" which are irrefutable from all empirics. What I haven't seen yet though is a sound testable hypothesis that supports the empirical observation. In other words, we know by empirics it's true, but we really don't yet know why its true or true in most, but certainly not all cases -- e.g. Greece recently for example. Many suppositions have been described but none have to my knowledge been put into the form of testable hypothesis to suppot the suppositions with "scientific" methods..

How does the relate to RBC models and ideology embedded in models?

RBC ignores the empirics for what can be said to be ideological reasons. But models which include those observations have no hypothesis proven to support the observations either, so then those models are equally using unscientific methods in their construction, which just so happens to support a different ideological position.

I don't disagree at all that models must use observations in their construction but it doesn't put those models at any greater scientific method advantage.

Paul Mathis -> Longtooth... , October 26, 2016 at 01:39 PM
Keynes Explains Sticky Wages (and Inflation)

"It appears, therefore, that we have a sort of asymmetry on the two sides of the critical level above which true inflation sets in. For a contraction of effective demand below the critical level will reduce its amount measured in cost-units; whereas an expansion of effective demand beyond this level will not, in general, have the effect of increasing its amount in terms of cost-units.

"This result follows from the assumption that the factors of production, and in particular the workers, are disposed to resist a reduction in their money-rewards, and that there is no corresponding motive to resist an increase. This assumption is, however, obviously well founded in the facts, due to the circumstance that a change, which is not an all-round change, is beneficial to the special factors affected when it is upward and harmful when it is downward.

"If, on the contrary, money-wages were to fall without limit whenever there was a tendency for less than full employment, the asymmetry would, indeed, disappear. But in that case there would be no resting-place below full employment until either the rate of interest was incapable of falling further or wages were zero.

"In fact we must have some factor, the value of which in terms of money is, if not fixed, at least sticky, to give us any stability of values in a monetary system.

"The view that any increase in the quantity of money is inflationary (unless we mean by inflationary merely that prices are rising) is bound up with the underlying assumption of the classical theory that we are always in a condition where a reduction in the real rewards of the factors of production will lead to a curtailment in their supply." The General Theory, pp. 303-304.

pgl -> Paul Mathis... , October 26, 2016 at 01:53 PM
The RBC crowd is arrogant enough to argue that Keynes was practicing junk science. They knew his writings and just ignored it.
Longtooth -> Paul Mathis... , October 27, 2016 at 01:35 AM
yes, Keynes supposition, among other was precisely what I was referring to by knowing the observation is true but not why it is.

Everybody knows it is true by observation that the sun rises in the east and settles in the west 1x in roughly 24 hours give or take a winter/summer trend change. But it took an awfully long time before Copernicus figured out why that was the case... and from his theory testable hypothesis were developed to show that the hypothesis were confirmed.

With sticky wages we don't know why. E.G.

Wages will not go below [this level] because [insert testable hypothesis]. A testable hypothesis takes the form

Lower Bound of Wage = [insert independent measurable variables and their relationships here]

As I said, lower bounds to wages are empirically observed. Now show why in repeatable results with the equations using the independent variables that apply under the conditions imposed by he hypothesis.

Until that is the observation is used in models because it suits ones interest to do so... i.e. they like the results of the models better. It isn't a scientifically founded model... the assumption is no better than rational expectations.

Paul Mathis -> Longtooth... , October 27, 2016 at 06:30 AM
Keynes' Testable Hypothesis:

"If, on the contrary, money-wages were to fall without limit whenever there was a tendency for less than full employment, . . . there would be no resting-place below full employment until either the rate of interest was incapable of falling further or wages were zero."

Absent sticky wages, at ZLB interest, wages would fall to zero whenever there was a tendency for less than full employment and nobody works for zero wages.

Keynes says this proposition is true.

pgl -> Longtooth... , October 26, 2016 at 01:52 PM
RBC also ignores anything that would explain why we have recessions at all. Its assumption that markets instantly clear is key to their model but we know that markets are not so perfect.
rdy : , October 26, 2016 at 02:11 PM
This same problem (the near religious belief that markets are always perfect) occurs with anti-trust enforcement and regulatory issues.
pgl -> rdy... , October 26, 2016 at 02:53 PM
A few years ago I would have suggested otherwise. But recent research notes you are right. Obama's CEA is noting this but he will not be President for long. Our next President needs to take this head on. Trump won't. Will Clinton? We will see.
pgl : , October 26, 2016 at 03:07 PM
Now this is honest. LeBron and Nike tell us to "come out of nowhere". You are not supposed to be here. What an awesome statement:

http://thespun.com/nba/lebron-james-nike-commercial-new-here-i-am

djb : , October 26, 2016 at 03:38 PM
"There is overwhelming evidence that in a recession employment declines because workers are fired rather than choosing not to work, and that the resulting increase in unemployment is involuntary"

see Keynes called it involuntary unemployment NOT cyclical unemployment

as all the politicians are saying now a days, words mean something

David Condon : , October 26, 2016 at 03:51 PM
Simon-Wren Lewis is making a common mistake as I see it. The limitations and assumptions of a model should not be conflated with evidence against the model. Not considering certain types of data is a limitation of a model; not evidence against that model. If an RBC model does not include certain types of data, then the best approach is to try and understand that data and attempt to show how it fits into the existing model. Another model should be considered only when certain limitations appear intractable. Because there are almost always lots of ways to model the same problem, at least in the social sciences, if you create a new model every time you come across a limitation, you'll end up running around in circles.
ScentOfViolets -> David Condon... , October 26, 2016 at 04:14 PM
This makes no sense to me. So how about explaining what you meant with real world examples? I choose the examples of involuntary unemployment and wage stickiness, and the effects of raising the minimum wage.
RW -> David Condon... , October 26, 2016 at 04:21 PM
"The limitations and assumptions of a model should not be conflated with evidence against the model."

I don't think this is what SWL is saying and am fairly certain it is not what Romer is saying: The problem is not limitation or contradiction, it is central variables assumed to confer verisimilitude that cannot and assumptions considered true that are not.

David Condon -> RW... , October 27, 2016 at 10:27 AM
Or to put your argument another way:

The assumptions of the model are false and therefore should be construed as evidence against using the model. I'm saying that's faulty reasoning.

The "my model is better than your model" argument is not a good way to approach problems at a theoretical level. It's sometimes okay at an applied level. One thing that's hard to wrap one's head around is that a model can still be useful even when its assumptions are false. When data is sparse, all useful theories will have to rely on false or incomplete assumptions. Usually a better approach is to extend rather than start over to keep people from running in too many different directions.

Longtooth -> David Condon... , October 27, 2016 at 01:52 AM
Then what value the model?

Re: Your supposition / assertion:

"Not considering certain types of data is a limitation of a model; not evidence against that model. If an RBC model does not include certain types of data, then the best approach is to try and understand that data and attempt to show how it fits into the existing model"

Henry Carey - a real American economist, sadly forgotten to history : , -1
That US economists are completely clueless is obvious to anyone who travels around the world. That free trade economies such as the US are complete basket cases is obvious to anyone who visits mercantilist economies such as Singapore, Japan, Israel etc. US trained economists only have prestige because the masses don't know how backward and poverty-stricken the US has become under the policies they relentlessly justify and apologize for.

[Oct 22, 2016] Why Trade Deals Lost Legitimacy

Oct 22, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com

Dani Rodrik:

The Walloon mouse : ...Instead of decrying people's stupidity and ignorance in rejecting trade deals, we should try to understand why such deals lost legitimacy in the first place. I'd put a large part of the blame on mainstream elites and trade technocrats who pooh-poohed ordinary people's concerns with earlier trade agreements.

The elites minimized distributional concerns, though they turned out to be significant for the most directly affected communities. They oversold aggregate gains from trade deals, though they have been smallish since at least NAFTA. They said sovereignty would not be diminished though it clearly was in some instances. They claimed democratic principles would not be undermined, though they are in places. They said there'd be no social dumping though there clearly is at times. They advertised trade deals (and continue to do so) as "free trade" agreements, even though Adam Smith and David Ricardo would turn over in their graves if they read, say, any of the TPP chapters.

And because they failed to provide those distinctions and caveats now trade gets tarred with all kinds of ills even when it's not deserved. If the demagogues and nativists making nonsensical claims about trade are getting a hearing, it is trade's cheerleaders that deserve some of the blame.

One more thing. The opposition to trade deals is no longer solely about income losses. The standard remedy of compensation won't be enough -- even if carried out. It's about fairness, loss of control, and elites' loss of credibility. It hurts the cause of trade to pretend otherwise.

El Chapo Guapo -> DrDick... October 22, 2016 at 11:22 AM , 2016 at 11:22 AM

... ... ..
Trump would propose and/or enact, he listed the following six:

"A Constitutional Amendment to impose term limits on all members of Congress."
"A hiring freeze on all federal employees."
"A requirement that for every new federal regulation, 2 existing regulations must be eliminated."
"A 5-year ban on White House and Congressional officials becoming lobbyists after they leave government."
"A lifetime ban on White House officials lobbying on behalf of a foreign government."
"A complete ban on foreign lobbyists raising money for American elections."
"
~~WWW~

Lot of reform is needed but may be

The forgotten spirit of American protectionism : , -1
The free traders have human economic history precisely inverted. Countries that practice protectionism almost uniformly become wealthy and technologically advanced. Countries that don't become or remain terribly sad, poverty-stricken producers of worthless raw materials and desperate labor migrants. This has been true at least going back to Byzantium and its economic conquest by Genoa and Venice.

That the US thrived pre-1970 free trade is no coincidence. There is no alternative to protectionism. Free trade = no industry = no money = no future.

[Oct 22, 2016] Liberals Compete for the Soul of Economics

I think he is trying to talk about soft neoliberalism vs rejection of neoliberalism as discredited economics dogma and ideology. I think like Marxism neoliberalism has religious elements in it (as in "secular religion") so will not go away completely much like obscure religious cults does not dissapper they on a given date second coming of Christ did not happen.
Notable quotes:
"... new research showing that policies like public housing , welfare and public education spending are more beneficial than conservatives have recognized in decades past. ..."
"... But there are not one, but two big trends in liberal economic thinking. One wants to modify the economic thinking of the past few decades, and the other wants to rip it up. I expect to see a lot of the economic debate in the coming years play out not between the left and right, but between these two strains of thought. ..."
"... The New Center-Left Consensus is attractive to academics and policy wonks. It draws on an eclectic mix of mainstream economic theory, empirical studies and historical experience. It refuses to assume, as many conservatives and libertarians do, that free markets are always the best unless there is a glaring case for government intervention. ..."
Oct 22, 2016 | www.bloomberg.com
In 2015, Forbes writer Adam Ozimek suggested that a "new liberal consensus" is forming in the economic-policy world. The data back him up. Many economics professors now tend to favor government intervention in the economy more than the general public. And the profession's biggest public stars, from Paul Krugman to Thomas Piketty to Joseph Stiglitz, are now more likely to lean to the left than to the right. Meanwhile, I've tried to document the flood of new research showing that policies like public housing , welfare and public education spending are more beneficial than conservatives have recognized in decades past.

But there are not one, but two big trends in liberal economic thinking. One wants to modify the economic thinking of the past few decades, and the other wants to rip it up. I expect to see a lot of the economic debate in the coming years play out not between the left and right, but between these two strains of thought.

The research and people I've been writing about fit into what we might call the New Center-Left Consensus. This strain of thought is based on data and empiricism. Support for higher minimum wages, for example, has grown among economists because a large amount of careful empirical analysis has shown that minimum wage hikes don't usually cause sizable immediate disruptions in local labor markets. These economists aren't ignorant of the basic theory of labor supply and demand -- the kind that every undergrad econ student is forced to learn. They just realize that it might not be the right theory in this case.

The New Center-Left Consensus is attractive to academics and policy wonks. It draws on an eclectic mix of mainstream economic theory, empirical studies and historical experience. It refuses to assume, as many conservatives and libertarians do, that free markets are always the best unless there is a glaring case for government intervention. It's more willing to entertain all kinds of ways that government can improve the economy, from welfare to infrastructure spending to regulation, but it also recognizes that these won't always work. It embraces a philosophy of careful experimentation. Sometimes the new center-left is even in favor of deregulation -- for example, loosening zoning restrictions and reducing occupational licensing . It's not ideologically opposed to the free market.

The best evangelist of the New Center-Left Consensus might be President Barack Obama. In an amazingly well-informed editorial in the Economist, he recently laid out a comprehensive picture of the economy and policy. I have little doubt that Obama's understanding was heavily informed by his chief economic adviser, Jason Furman , who has become a titan of center-left policy advocacy. Obama mixes a healthy respect for capitalism with a desire to use government to temper the market's excesses.

But there's a second strain of progressive economic thinking that is gaining attention and strength. This alternative could be called the New Heterodox Explosion. It's basically a movement to purge mainstream economics from progressive policy-making and thought.

The New Heterodox Explosion rose in large part out of strongly left-leaning intellectual circles, particularly sociology, the humanities and other disciplines outside economics. It has also found a home in some economics departments in other countries (most notably the U.K.). Recently, it has started to permeate blogs and the media.

The new website Evonomics , for example, is heavily devoted to strongly worded critiques of the entire edifice of modern [neoliberal] economics and it's where the work of many of the most outspoken champions of the New Heterodox Explosion appears. These include evolutionary biologist David Sloan Wilson, activist and venture capitalist Nick Hanauer, speechwriter Eric Liu and Eric Beinhocker of the Institute for New Economic Thinking. In a spate of recent blog posts and editorials, these thinkers have advocated replacing mainstream economic theory with thinking based on evolution, and/or on complexity theory.

Though it's difficult to boil down these critiques to a few sentences, one basic theme of Wilson, Hanauer, et al.'s thinking is that modern economics is based on selfishness. Mainstream theories model human beings as atomistic individuals pursuing their own wants. But, say these Evonomics writers, people are social beings who care a lot about their fellow humans, and are also deeply embedded in larger social structures and organizations like communities, nations and cultures.

I'm sympathetic to this point of view. I'm not at all sure that economies can be completely understood by looking at individual decisions, any more than I'm certain the growth of a tree can be understood simply by looking at the motions of the particles in the leaves and roots. And I do wish that economists dedicated a lot more thought and attention to the phenomena they call " externalities " and " social preferences ."

But I'm also very wary of applying the Evonomics ideas to policy-making without a lot more work. First, the connection to evolution and complexity theory often seems less than solid. Nobody really knows if economies evolve the way organisms do. And efforts to connect complexity theory to economics, led by the Santa Fe Institute , have been going on for quite some time without any dramatic breakthroughs.

So while the New Center-Left Consensus is fully formed and ready for application in the real world, the New Heterodox Explosion is still in its infancy. Center-left ideas have tons of very careful academic empirical work behind them, while those wishing to tear up economics and start over are still working mostly with broad analogies. I hope that the New Heterodox Explosion -- which of course extends far beyond the few writers and ideas I've cited in this post -- becomes a rich source of new and innovative economic ideas. But it still has a long way to go to match the intellectual heft of the center-left.

This column does not necessarily reflect the opinion of the editorial board or Bloomberg LP and its owners.

Noah Smith is a Bloomberg View columnist. He was an assistant professor of finance at Stony Brook University, and he blogs at Noahpinion.

[Oct 16, 2016] The Cathedral -- The self-organizing ideological consensus represented by the universities, the media, and the civil service by Rod Dreher

Notable quotes:
"... The corridor between Manhattan and Washington is a well trodden highway for the personalities we have all gotten to know in the period since the massive deregulation of Wall Street: Robert Rubin, Lawrence Summers, Henry Paulson, Timothy Geithner and many others. ..."
"... General Petraeus' expertise in these areas is unclear. His ability to peddle influence, however, is a known and valued commodity. ..."
"... Petraeus also obtained a sinecure as a non-resident senior fellow at the Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs at Harvard. The Ivy League is, of course, the preferred bleaching tub and charm school of the American oligarchy. ..."
"... The Cathedral has no central administrator, but represents a consensus acting as a coherent group that condemns other ideologies as evil. ..."
"... "you believe that morality has been essentially solved, and all that's left is to work out the details." ..."
"... Cultural assimilation is partly a matter of what psychologist Irving L. Janis called "groupthink," the chameleon-like ability of people to adopt the views of their superiors and peers. This syndrome is endemic to Washington: The town is characterized by sudden fads, be it negotiating biennial budgeting, making grand bargains or invading countries. Then, after a while, all the town's cool kids drop those ideas as if they were radioactive. As in the military, everybody has to get on board with the mission, and questioning it is not a career-enhancing move. The universe of people who will critically examine the goings-on at the institutions they work for is always going to be a small one. As Upton Sinclair said, "It is difficult to get a man to understand something when his salary depends upon his not understanding it. ..."
"... A more elusive aspect of cultural assimilation is the sheer dead weight of the ordinariness of it all once you have planted yourself in your office chair for the 10,000th time. ..."
"... No wonder so few people are whistle-blowers, quite apart from the vicious retaliation whistle-blowing often provokes: Unless one is blessed with imagination and a fine sense of irony, growing immune to the curiousness of one's surroundings is easy. To paraphrase the inimitable Donald Rumsfeld, I didn't know all that I knew, at least until I had had a couple of years away from the government to reflect upon it. ..."
"... It's probably not a coincidence that the American media elite live, work, and socialize in New York and Washington, ..."
"... It's a kind of corporatism. ..."
"... They pretend to be merrily neutral servants of the state, giving the best advice possible on national security or financial matters. But they hold a very deep ideology of the Washington consensus at home, which is deregulation, outsourcing, de-industrialization and financialization. ..."
"... And they believe in American exceptionalism abroad, which is boots on the ground everywhere, it's our right to meddle everywhere in the world. And the result of that is perpetual war. ..."
Feb 28, 2014 | The American Conservative

From: The Deep State By Rod Dreher

The corridor between Manhattan and Washington is a well trodden highway for the personalities we have all gotten to know in the period since the massive deregulation of Wall Street: Robert Rubin, Lawrence Summers, Henry Paulson, Timothy Geithner and many others.

Not all the traffic involves persons connected with the purely financial operations of the government: In 2013, General David Petraeus joined KKR (formerly Kohlberg Kravis Roberts) of 9 West 57th Street, New York, a private equity firm with $62.3 billion in assets. KKR specializes in management buyouts and leveraged finance. General Petraeus' expertise in these areas is unclear. His ability to peddle influence, however, is a known and valued commodity. Unlike Cincinnatus, the military commanders of the Deep State do not take up the plow once they lay down the sword. Petraeus also obtained a sinecure as a non-resident senior fellow at the Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs at Harvard. The Ivy League is, of course, the preferred bleaching tub and charm school of the American oligarchy.

Lofgren goes on to say that Silicon Valley is a node of the Deep State too, and that despite the protestations of its chieftains against NSA spying, it's a vital part of the Deep State's apparatus. More:

The Deep State is the big story of our time. It is the red thread that runs through the war on terrorism, the financialization and deindustrialization of the American economy, the rise of a plutocratic social structure and political dysfunction. Washington is the headquarters of the Deep State, and its time in the sun as a rival to Rome, Constantinople or London may be term-limited by its overweening sense of self-importance and its habit, as Winwood Reade said of Rome, to "live upon its principal till ruin stared it in the face."

Read the whole thing.

Steve Sailer says that the Shallow State is a complement to the Deep State. The Shallow State is, I think, another name for what the Neoreactionaries call "The Cathedral," defined thus:

The Cathedral - The self-organizing consensus of Progressives and Progressive ideology represented by the universities, the media, and the civil service. A term coined by blogger Mencius Moldbug. The Cathedral has no central administrator, but represents a consensus acting as a coherent group that condemns other ideologies as evil. Community writers have enumerated the platform of Progressivism as women's suffrage, prohibition, abolition, federal income tax, democratic election of senators, labor laws, desegregation, popularization of drugs, destruction of traditional sexual norms, ethnic studies courses in colleges, decolonization, and gay marriage. A defining feature of Progressivism is that "you believe that morality has been essentially solved, and all that's left is to work out the details." Reactionaries see Republicans as Progressives, just lagging 10-20 years behind Democrats in their adoption of Progressive norms.

You don't have to agree with the Neoreactionaries on what they condemn - women's suffrage? desegregation? labor laws? really?? - to acknowledge that they're onto something about the sacred consensus that all Right-Thinking People share. I would love to see a study comparing the press coverage from 9/11 leading up to the Iraq War with press coverage of the gay marriage issue from about 2006 till today. Specifically, I'd be curious to know about how thoroughly the media covered the cases against the policies that the Deep State and the Shallow State decided should prevail. I'm not suggesting a conspiracy here, not at all. I'm only thinking back to how it seemed so obvious to me in 2002 that we should go to war with Iraq, so perfectly clear that the only people who opposed it were fools or villains. The same consensus has emerged around same-sex marriage. I know how overwhelmingly the news media have believed this for some time, such that many American journalists simply cannot conceive that anyone against same-sex marriage is anything other than a fool or a villain. Again, this isn't a conspiracy; it's in the nature of the thing. Lofgren:

Cultural assimilation is partly a matter of what psychologist Irving L. Janis called "groupthink," the chameleon-like ability of people to adopt the views of their superiors and peers. This syndrome is endemic to Washington: The town is characterized by sudden fads, be it negotiating biennial budgeting, making grand bargains or invading countries. Then, after a while, all the town's cool kids drop those ideas as if they were radioactive. As in the military, everybody has to get on board with the mission, and questioning it is not a career-enhancing move. The universe of people who will critically examine the goings-on at the institutions they work for is always going to be a small one. As Upton Sinclair said, "It is difficult to get a man to understand something when his salary depends upon his not understanding it."

A more elusive aspect of cultural assimilation is the sheer dead weight of the ordinariness of it all once you have planted yourself in your office chair for the 10,000th time. Government life is typically not some vignette from an Allen Drury novel about intrigue under the Capitol dome. Sitting and staring at the clock on the off-white office wall when it's 11:00 in the evening and you are vowing never, ever to eat another piece of takeout pizza in your life is not an experience that summons the higher literary instincts of a would-be memoirist.

After a while, a functionary of the state begins to hear things that, in another context, would be quite remarkable, or at least noteworthy, and yet that simply bounce off one's consciousness like pebbles off steel plate: "You mean the number of terrorist groups we are fighting is classified?" No wonder so few people are whistle-blowers, quite apart from the vicious retaliation whistle-blowing often provokes: Unless one is blessed with imagination and a fine sense of irony, growing immune to the curiousness of one's surroundings is easy. To paraphrase the inimitable Donald Rumsfeld, I didn't know all that I knew, at least until I had had a couple of years away from the government to reflect upon it.

When all you know is the people who surround you in your professional class bubble and your social circles, you can think the whole world agrees with you, or should. It's probably not a coincidence that the American media elite live, work, and socialize in New York and Washington, the two cities that were attacked on 9/11, and whose elites - political, military, financial - were so genuinely traumatized by the events.

Anyway, that's just a small part of it, about how the elite media manufacture consent. Here's a final quote, one from the Moyers interview with Lofgren:

BILL MOYERS: If, as you write, the ideology of the Deep State is not democrat or republican, not left or right, what is it?

MIKE LOFGREN: It's an ideology. I just don't think we've named it. It's a kind of corporatism. Now, the actors in this drama tend to steer clear of social issues. They pretend to be merrily neutral servants of the state, giving the best advice possible on national security or financial matters. But they hold a very deep ideology of the Washington consensus at home, which is deregulation, outsourcing, de-industrialization and financialization.

And they believe in American exceptionalism abroad, which is boots on the ground everywhere, it's our right to meddle everywhere in the world. And the result of that is perpetual war.

This can't last. We'd better hope it can't last. And we'd better hope it unwinds peacefully.

I, for one, remain glad that so many of us Americans are armed. When the Deep State collapses - and it will one day - it's not going to be a happy time.

Questions to the room: Is a Gorbachev for the Deep State conceivable? That is, could you foresee a political leader emerging who could unwind the ideology and apparatus of the Deep State, and not only survive, but succeed? Or is it impossible for the Deep State to allow such a figure to thrive? Or is the Deep State, like the Soviet system Gorbachev failed to reform, too entrenched and too far gone to reform itself? If so, what then?

[Oct 08, 2016] Krugman is an abhorrent neoliberal hack and Hillary stooge

Notable quotes:
"... Krugman is such a deplorable hack. I know we are supposed to accept bribe-taking politicians and the economy run by looting robber barons. But can't we even have a goddamn fourth estate? ..."
"... The way Krugman murders journalism ethics by outright campaigning for one of the most corrupt politicians in American history is outrageous. Barfing up her disgusting campaign memes verbatim as if he's coordinating his columns with her war room. ..."
"... If you're a scientist you would know that economics does not remotely resemble a science. One familiar with the history of math and science will notice that their development (based on discovered facts) forms a tree-like structure. One discovery branches out to more discoveries. The growth is therefore exponential. ..."
Oct 08, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com
JohnH -> pgl... , Friday, October 07, 2016 at 06:44 PM
Sure...Krugman will occasionally pay lip service to green energy.

The problem is that 'liberal' economists tend to keep separate silos for green energy and infrastructure.

Question is, why do they refuse to connect the dots between climate change mitigation, green energy, fiscal stimulus, and lots of jobs? And why do they prioritize more road and bridges, which will only make climate change worse?

Sure sounds like the usual hypocrisy to me...

nikbez -> JohnH... , Saturday, October 08, 2016 at 03:45 PM
Krugman is an abhorrent neoliberal hack (as well as Hillary stooge).

Who actually understand very little about climate change clearly being non-specialist without any training of physics and geophysics. He is a second rate neoclassical economist with penchant for mathiness (and a very talented writer).

The key question here is Clinton warmongering and the threat of nuclear war with Russia. Washington neocon chichenhawks became recently realty crazy. Obama looks completely important and does not control anything.

I think this is more immediate threat then climate change.

Oil depletion (which already started and will be in full force in a couple of decades) might take care about climate change as period of "cheap oil" (aka "oil age") probably will last less then 100 years and as such is just a blip in Earth history.

End of cheap oil also might lead to natural shrinking of human population -- another factor in the global climate change and a threat to natural ecosystems.

supersaurus : , Friday, October 07, 2016 at 09:56 AM
@Sandwichman: it isn't illegal to be an idiot in this country (USA), hence "almost".
Sandwichman -> supersaurus... , Friday, October 07, 2016 at 10:00 AM
It is, however, often illegal to not be an idiot.
Ron Waller -> pgl... , Friday, October 07, 2016 at 12:29 PM
Hillary is the fracking Queen. Claiming she's a champion of the environment is as ridiculous portraying Donald Trump a feminist.

Obomba is another pretender on the environment. The Paris Agreement commits to absolutely nothing but more talk at a future time. China signed on and is still keeping its commitment to do absolutely nothing to reduce emissions until 2030. (By the time the West has exported the lion share of its emissions to the country in a pointless GHG emissions shell game; emission per capita have skyrocketed since 2002! a 25% increase!)

Krugman is such a deplorable hack. I know we are supposed to accept bribe-taking politicians and the economy run by looting robber barons. But can't we even have a goddamn fourth estate?

The way Krugman murders journalism ethics by outright campaigning for one of the most corrupt politicians in American history is outrageous. Barfing up her disgusting campaign memes verbatim as if he's coordinating his columns with her war room.

So to all the pretend liberals out there who offer the people nothing more than more corruption, lies, war-profiteering and public trust liquidation: you deserve Trump. And I pray that you get him. (After him, a New Deal; and the 'me generation,' the Void.)

pgl -> DrDick... , Friday, October 07, 2016 at 12:44 PM
I think he consumed too much of the byproduct from fracking. Dirty dangerous business.
Ron Waller -> pgl... , Friday, October 07, 2016 at 01:24 PM
You two must be economists. Never anything intelligent to say.
DrDick -> Ron Waller ... , Friday, October 07, 2016 at 01:39 PM
Actually, I am a cultural anthropologist. I must say that there are no signs of intelligent life on you planet.
Ron Waller -> DrDick... , Friday, October 07, 2016 at 02:40 PM
If you're a scientist you would know that economics does not remotely resemble a science. One familiar with the history of math and science will notice that their development (based on discovered facts) forms a tree-like structure. One discovery branches out to more discoveries. The growth is therefore exponential.

Economic history does not follow this pattern.

With science there are paradigm shifts that occur with groundbreaking discoveries like the theories of relativity and quantum mechanics. The Friedmanian paradigm shift was founded on jettisoning all the enormously successful work Keynes accomplished and digging up failed 19th century ideology, repeating disastrous history.

Even psychology follows the pattern. Although it began with a lot of unsubstantiated Aristotelian philosophizing, it was a starting point from which a significant body of definite knowledge and medical treatments developed. A real social science. (Not perfect. It was recently discovered that about 50% of published psychological experiments were not reproducible.)

As an anthropologist you should know about cliques and group-think. Have an inkling of how corruption could gradually develop and spread among upper-echelon cliques to the point where the government, the economy, the courts and the news media become captured by the upper class. Understand how cowards would rather look the other way than take a stand and deal with it: "see no evil, hear no evil, speak no evil."

DrDick -> Ron Waller ... , Friday, October 07, 2016 at 04:28 PM
As an anthropologist, I can assert with confidence that you are babbling about things you do not really understand at all. I have issues with a lot of economics, but you are completely incoherent.
Ron Waller -> DrDick... , Friday, October 07, 2016 at 05:21 PM
Completely incoherent? Then it should be easy enough for you to tear apart what I wrote. It was certainly easy enough for me to tear into Krugman's crass political pandering. But all you got is lame generalizations. Stock insults that could be said about anything.

What issues do you have with "a lot of economics?" I bet you can't come up with anything. Come on. Out with it! Say something intelligent about anything, if you are at all capable, Mr. Dick. I have yet to read anything from you that indicates you have any knowledge about anything.

DrDick -> Ron Waller ... , Saturday, October 08, 2016 at 06:36 AM
It is Dr. Dick, since I have a Ph.D. If you ever read the comments on this blog, you would know full well what those issues are, since I have raised them here many times. For a start the assumption of "rational actors" (only partially true), the assumption of economic maximization (people maximize many different things which affect their economic choices), and the assumption of "rational markets" (this ignores pervasive information assymetry and active deceit).
nikbez -> DrDick... , Saturday, October 08, 2016 at 03:48 PM
"I must say that there are no signs of intelligent life on you planet."

That's good :-) Thank you --

[Oct 07, 2016] Noahpinion The new heavyweight macro critics

Notable quotes:
"... I got tired of lambasting macroeconomics a while ago, and the "macro wars" mostly died down in the blogosphere around when the recovery from the Great Recession kicked in. But recently, there have been a number of respected macroeconomists posting big, comprehensive criticisms of the way academic macro gets done. Some of these criticisms are more forceful than anything we bloggers blogged about back in the day! ..."
"... First, there's Paul Romer's latest, " The Trouble With Macroeconomics ". The title is an analogy to Lee Smolin's book " The Trouble With Physics ". Romer basically says that macro (meaning business-cycle theory) has become like the critics' harshest depictions of string theory - a community of believers, dogmatically following the ideas of revered elders and ignoring the data. The elders he singles out are Bob Lucas, Ed Prescott, and Tom Sargent. ..."
"... In response to the observation that the shocks [in DSGE models] are imaginary, a standard defense invokes Milton Friedman's (1953) methodological assertion from unnamed authority that "the more significant the theory, the more unrealistic the assumptions (p.14)." More recently, "all models are false" seems to have become the universal hand-wave for dismissing any fact that does not conform to the model that is the current favorite. ..."
"... We [macroeconomists] tend to view research as being the process of posing a question and delivering a pretty precise answer to that question...The research agenda that I believe we need is very different. It's hugely messy work. We need...to build a more evidence-based modeling of financial institutions. We need...to learn more about how people actually form expectations. We need [to use] firm-based information about residual demand functions to learn more about product market structure. At the same time, we need to be a lot more flexible in our thinking about models and theory, so that they can be firmly grounded in this improved empirical understanding. ..."
"... This is a somewhat misleading way of putting it, but it allows me to illustrate some important points about 'unrealistic' assumptions. In real world modelling in Physics 'unrealistic' assumptions are ubiquitous. What matters is not literal realism of assumptions but robustness.of conclusions. ..."
"... Simplifying assumptions are context specific, ie ad hoc, and never axiomatic.The ad hoc nature of simplifying assumptions is a feature, not a bug as the above example illustrates. ..."
"... Robustness is critical. As we move from our simplifying assumptions towards greater realism/precision, the conclusion should not change in any material way, and we use the simplifications because the gain in accuracy of the conclusions is not worth the added complexity and consequent loss of tractability in the model. ..."
"... This is indeed excellent. The three criteria for evaluating assumptions/simplifications, the precise definition of ad hoc, and the crystal-clear example of point mass for orbits vs rotation. ..."
"... So, we are witnessing a battle between a declining DSGE scam and ascending "Realistic assumptions" scam. ..."
"... Both approaches are worthless, but I guess it will give an excuse to macroeconomists why they are useless: we just used the wrong paradigm, now we are switching to the new one. Just many more years of research is needed and we will be ready. Science!, as they say. ..."
"... Science, IEHO, has three touchstones. Coherence - your model and its assumptions should not contradict each other or lead to contradictory conclusions. Consilience - a good theory has a broad reach for explaining reality. Consensus - a theory which is coherent and consilient should lead to a consensus among practicioners. It is only within a strong consensus that people can talk to each other and extend the field. ..."
"... It appears that macro misses out on a number of these. ..."
"... "Romer basically says that macro (meaning business-cycle theory)" ..."
"... In either case, I think this is another big problem with macro, its obsession with business cycles as opposed to long-term thriving and prosperity. eg, Gerald Friedman got tied in knots by this; he was trying to use "stimulus" thinking and arguments to talk about about multi-decadal possibilities. ..."
"... I'm fond of observing that in addition to "cargo cult science", macroeconomics has often been likened to a religion. What religions do when the mainstream becomes intolerable for one reason or another is schism. Then after a number of years what used to be the mainstream dies out and the former schismatics become the mainstream. ..."
"... Psychology went through this kind of crisis some years ago when the scientists split off from the clinicians, and created the Association for Psychological Science to contrast with the clinically-oriented American Psychological Association (the APA is the one that publishes the unscientific but influential Diagnostic and Statistical Manual). ..."
"... In order to be scientific, the standard method is to actually try predicting. Prediction is messy and provably fails to converge to any possible theory, but there are other authentic sciences that have this same theoretical limitation, like meteorology. This doesn't prevent meteorologists from constructing theories which make predictions that demonstrably get better and better year after year. ..."
"... For twenty years Romer has been implying (and recently saying) that economists who don't accept endogenous growth theory have abandoned the canons of science and are either blind or indifferent to the truth. Over the same twenty years he seems to have produced very little theoretical work, while his targets have remained working economists. (Why, after all, should anyone continue to do theory, since Romer has discovered the truth?) ..."
Oct 02, 2016 | noahpinionblog.blogspot.com
I got tired of lambasting macroeconomics a while ago, and the "macro wars" mostly died down in the blogosphere around when the recovery from the Great Recession kicked in. But recently, there have been a number of respected macroeconomists posting big, comprehensive criticisms of the way academic macro gets done. Some of these criticisms are more forceful than anything we bloggers blogged about back in the day! Anyway, I thought I'd link to a couple here.

First, there's Paul Romer's latest, " The Trouble With Macroeconomics ". The title is an analogy to Lee Smolin's book " The Trouble With Physics ". Romer basically says that macro (meaning business-cycle theory) has become like the critics' harshest depictions of string theory - a community of believers, dogmatically following the ideas of revered elders and ignoring the data. The elders he singles out are Bob Lucas, Ed Prescott, and Tom Sargent.

Romer says that it's obvious that monetary policy affects the real economy, because of the Volcker recessions in the early 80s, but that macro theorists have largely ignored this fact and continued to make models in which monetary policy is ineffectual. He says that modern DSGE models are no better than old pre-Lucas Critique simultaneous-equation models, because they still take lots of assumptions to identify the models, only now the assumptions are hidden instead of explicit. Romer points to distributional assumptions, calibration, and tight Bayesian priors as ways of hiding assumptions in modern DSGE models. He cites an interesting 2009 paper by Canova and Sala that tries to take DSGE model estimation seriously and finds (unsurprisingly) that identification is pretty difficult.

As a solution, Romer suggests chucking formal modeling entirely and going with more general, vague but flexible ideas about policy and the macroeconomy, supported by simple natural experiments and economic history.

Romer's harshest zinger (and we all love harsh zingers) is this:

In response to the observation that the shocks [in DSGE models] are imaginary, a standard defense invokes Milton Friedman's (1953) methodological assertion from unnamed authority that "the more significant the theory, the more unrealistic the assumptions (p.14)." More recently, "all models are false" seems to have become the universal hand-wave for dismissing any fact that does not conform to the model that is the current favorite.
The noncommittal relationship with the truth revealed by these methodological evasions...goes so far beyond post-modern irony that it deserves its own label. I suggest "post-real."
Ouch. He also calls various typical DSGE model elements names like "phlogiston", "aether", and "caloric". Fun stuff . (Though I do think he's too harsh on string theory, which often is just a kind of math that physicists do to keep themselves busy, and has no danger of hurting anyone, unlike macro theory.)

Meanwhile, a few weeks earlier, Narayana Kocherlakota wrote a post called " On the Puzzling Prevalence of Puzzles ". The basic point was that since macro data is fairly sparse, macroeconomists should have lots of competing models that all do an equally good job of matching the data. But instead, macroeconomists pick a single model they like, and if data fails to fit the model they call it a "puzzle". He writes:

To an outsider or newcomer, macroeconomics would seem like a field that is haunted by its lack of data...In the absence of that data, it would seem like we would be hard put to distinguish among a host of theories...[I]t would seem like macroeconomists should be plagued by underidentification...
But, in fact, expert macroeconomists know that the field is actually plagued by failures to fit the data – that is, by overidentification.
Why is the novice so wrong? The answer is the role of a priori restrictions in macroeconomic theory...
The mistake that the novice made is to think that the macroeconomist would rely on data alone to build up his/her theory or model. The expert knows how to build up theory from a priori restrictions that are accepted by a large number of scholars...[I]t's a little disturbing how little empirical work underlies some of those agreed-upon theory-driven restrictions – see p. 711 of Lucas (JMCB, 1980) for a highly influential example of what I mean.
In fact, Kocherlakota and Romer are complaining about much the same thing: the overuse of unrealistic assumptions. Basically, they say that macroeconomists, as a group, have gotten into the habit of assuming stuff that just isn't true. In fact, this is what the Canova and Sala paper says too, in a much more technical and polite way:
Observational equivalence, partial and weak identification problems are widespread and typically produced by an ill-behaved mapping between the structural parameters and the coefficients of the solution.
That just means that the model elements aren't actually real things.
(This critique resonates with me. From day 1, the thing that always annoyed me about macro was how people made excuses for assumptions that were either unverifiable or just flatly contradictory to micro data. The usual excuse was the " pool player analogy " - the idea that the pieces of a model don't have to match micro data as long as the resulting model matches macro data. I'm not sure that's how Milton Friedman wanted his metaphor to be used, but that seems to be the way it does get used. And when the models didn't match macro data either, the excuse was "all models are wrong," which really just seems to be a way of saying "the modeler gets to choose which macro facts are used to validate his theory". It seemed that to a large extent, macro modelers were just allowed to do whatever they wanted, as long as their papers won some kind of behind-the-scenes popularity contest. But I digress.)
So what seems to unite the new heavyweight macro critics is an emphasis on realism . Basically, these people are challenging the idea, very common in econ theory, that models shouldn't worry about being realistic. (Paul Pfleiderer is another economist who has recently made a similar complaint , though not in the context of macro.) They're not saying that economists need 100% perfect realism - that's the kind of thing you only get in physics, if anywhere. As Paul Krugman and Dani Rodrik have emphasized, even the people advocating for more realism acknowledge that there's some ideal middle ground. But if Romer, Kocherlakota, etc. are to be believed, macroeconomists aren't currently close to that optimal interior solution.


Updates

Olivier Blanchard is a bet less forceful, but he's definitely also one of the new heavyweight critics . Among his problems with DSGE models, at least as they're currently done, are 1. "unappealing" assumptions that are "at odds with what we know about consumers and firms", and 2. "unconvincing" estimation methods, including calibration and tight Bayesian priors. Sounds pretty similar to Romer.

Meanwhile, Kocherlakota responds to Romer . He agrees with Romer's criticism of unrealistic macro assumptions, but he dismisses the idea that Lucas, Prescott, and Sargent are personally responsible for the problems. Instead, he says it's about the incentives in the research community. He writes:

We [macroeconomists] tend to view research as being the process of posing a question and delivering a pretty precise answer to that question...The research agenda that I believe we need is very different. It's hugely messy work. We need...to build a more evidence-based modeling of financial institutions. We need...to learn more about how people actually form expectations. We need [to use] firm-based information about residual demand functions to learn more about product market structure. At the same time, we need to be a lot more flexible in our thinking about models and theory, so that they can be firmly grounded in this improved empirical understanding.
Kocherlakota says that this isn't a "sociological" issue, but I think most people would call it that. Since journals and top researchers get to decide what constitutes "good" research, it seems to me that to get the changes in focus Kocherlakota wants, a sociological change is exactly what would be required.

Kocherlakota now has another post describing how he thinks macro ought to be done . Basically, he thinks researchers - as a whole, not just on their own! - should start with toy models to facilitate thinking, then gather data based on what the toy models say is important, then build formal "serious" models from the ground up to match that data. He contrasts this with the current approach of tweaking existing models.

My question is: Who is going to enforce this change? If a few established researchers start doing things the way Kocherlakota wants, they'll certainly still get published (because they're famous old people), but will the young folks follow? How likely is it that established researchers en masse are going to switch to doing things this way, and demanding that young researchers do the same, and using their leverage as reviewers, editors, and PhD advisers to make that happen? This doesn't seem like the kind of change that can be brought about by a few young smart rebels forcing everyone else to recognize the value of their approach - the existing approach, which Kocherlakota dislikes, already succeeds in getting publication and prestige, so the rebels would simply coexist alongside the old approach, rather than overthrowing it. How could this cultural change be put into effect?

Also: Romer now has a follow-up to his original post, defending his original post against the critics. This part stood out to me as particularly persuasive:

The whine I hear regularly from the post-real crowd is that "it is really, really hard to do research on macro so you shouldn't criticize any of our models unless you can produce one that is better."
This is just post-real Calvinball used as a shield from criticism. Imagine someone saying to a mathematician who finds an error in a theorem that is false, "you can't criticize the proof until you come up with valid proof." Or try this one on and see how it feels: "You can't criticize the claim that vaccines cause autism unless you can come up with a better explanation for autism."
Sounds right to me. The old like that "it takes a theory to kill a theory" just seems wrong to me. Sometimes all it takes is evidence.

Herman 7:21 PM

I've already commented at lenght on Romer at Mark Thoma's. So I'll just use something you wrote on physics to make a tangential comment on unrealistic assumptions.

"They're not saying that economists need 100% perfect realism - that's the kind of thing you only get in physics, if anywhere"

This is a somewhat misleading way of putting it, but it allows me to illustrate some important points about 'unrealistic' assumptions. In real world modelling in Physics 'unrealistic' assumptions are ubiquitous. What matters is not literal realism of assumptions but robustness.of conclusions.

Consider a point-mass. There is no such thing. Yet it is a perfectly legitimate simplifying assumption about a planet if you are interested in studying its orbit around its sun. It is not a legitimate assumption if you are interested in studying a planet's rotation about its axis

The most important points underlying such simplifying assumptions are:

1. Simplifying assumptions are context specific, ie ad hoc, and never axiomatic.The ad hoc nature of simplifying assumptions is a feature, not a bug as the above example illustrates.

2. Robustness is critical. As we move from our simplifying assumptions towards greater realism/precision, the conclusion should not change in any material way, and we use the simplifications because the gain in accuracy of the conclusions is not worth the added complexity and consequent loss of tractability in the model.

3. Out of sample performance of the model.

* Richard Feynman:

"...in order to understand physical laws you must understand that they are all some kind of approximation.

The trick is the idealizations. To an excellent approximation of perhaps one part in 10^10, the number of atoms in the chair does not change in a minute, and if we are not too precise we may idealize the chair as a definite thing; in the same way we shall learn about the characteristics of force, in an ideal fashion, if we are not too precise. One may be dissatisfied with the approximate view of nature that physics tries to obtain (the attempt is always to increase the accuracy of the approximation), and may prefer a mathematical definition; but mathematical definitions can never work in the real world. A mathematical definition will be good for mathematics, in which all the logic can be followed out completely, but the physical world is complex, as we have indicated in a number of examples, such as those of the ocean waves and a glass of wine. When we try to isolate pieces of it, to talk about one mass, the wine and the glass, how can we know which is which, when one dissolves in the other? The forces on a single thing already involve approximation, and if we have a system of discourse about the real world, then that system, at least for the present day, must involve approximations of some kind.

This system is quite unlike the case of mathematics, in which everything can be defined, and then we do not know what we are talking about. In fact, the glory of mathematics is that we do not have to say what we are talking about. The glory is that the laws, the arguments, and the logic are independent of what "it" is.

[ Feynman Lectures Vol.I Ch.12 ]

JW Mason 9:39 AM

These are good observations. The way "ad hoc" has become a decisive argument against a model, at least in macro, is a symptom of the problem.

Herman 4:10 PM

Indeed. That was part of the reason for redundantly using the phrase :) . The other reason was that the usage is strictly accurate. ad hoc = for this particular purpose (Shorter OED)

It is difficult to see how simplifying assumptions underlying real world models can be anything but ad hoc (context-specific)

For a mathematician to object to ad hoc statements would be understandable, but for someone concerned with real world modelling to do so is mind-boggling.

It is worth pointing out that the economists who do so object have never in their life built a model that works, for any definition of 'works' acceptable anywhere outside economics.

Steve Roth 10:23 AM

This is indeed excellent. The three criteria for evaluating assumptions/simplifications, the precise definition of ad hoc, and the crystal-clear example of point mass for orbits vs rotation.

I'd like to bring in my pet bailiwick, accounting. Our (national) accounting systems are rife with assumptions and simplifications - they are economic models. (Or in Feynman's excellent term, "idealizations.") And those assumptions are effectively invisible to almost everyone. If I had a nickel for every time I've heard "it's an accounting identity" as if that was somehow synonymous with "truth"...

Just one example, relating to a rather important economic measure - income:

http://unstats.un.org/unsd/nationalaccount/rissue.asp?rID=3

The national-accounting sages know that the appropriateness of this basic conceptual construct is a very open question. But that fact is invisible to almost everyone. National accounts could be depicted quite differently (yes, with everything still balancing).

Economists' thinking is completely owned by the conceptual constructs, the idealizations, embodied in our national-accounting structures. And they frequently display zero understanding of the constructs that they are (we are) using to think with.

reason 4:05 AM

Herman,

I've been critical of you in the past, but that is a really good comment, 100% on the ball. But I will add that the simplifying assumption you used to illustrate your point, may not be true, but it is nearly true (without the scales being considered). And many simplifying assumptions used in economics are not nearly true.

Herman 4:42 PM

Informally we might - and sometimes do - say that the assumption (point-mass) is 'nearly true', but it is not quite correct. It is an idealization that satisfies criterion (2): robustness, and the resulting model satisfies criterion (3); out-of-sample performance.

Of course this is very different from the sort of assumptions common in economics which are often patently false - and this is the critical point - making them more realistic materially changes the conclusions ie the assumptions in the models fail to satisfy the robustness criterion. And, at least in DSGE/RBC macro to talk of in-sample fit or out-of-sample performance of the resulting model would imply a libelous misuse of the terms.

Herman 4:53 PM

... cont

Actually, as Romer notes, the situation in economics is often even worse.with assumptions being not merely false ( with non-robust conclusions) but entirely meaningless in terms of real world observables. Assumptions of the sort that are deservedly derisively dismissed as not even wrong in every scientific or engineering discipline.

Anonymous 6:26 AM

It's not just an argument about having models with realistic assumptions. It is also an argument about the extent to which mathematics and models can usefully provide the answers we need to know. Basically we are going back to Keynes's (1937) arguments about the limitations of "pretty and polite techniques". Edgeworth was also very much aware of the limitations of mathematics in economics. And so have many others, for a long time.

I have been critical of Romer in the past. His growth theory for me does not answer the critical questions that I think are the most important into understanding why certain countries get on to a growth curve and others do not. But I now really have to admire his honesty.

I wish him all the best at the World Bank.

NK.

Anonymous 6:47 AM

It is not true that we do not have a lot of macro data. The National Accounts contain scores of (largely stock-flow consistent) data. The point is: one of the big failures of DSGE economists is their failureto establish a measurement system which produces data consistent with the DSGE models. Keynes, who even established his own government statistical office, the present day ONS, and, in a more indirect sense, Smith, Marshall as well and Veblen did establish systems of measurement to measure data consistent with their models and ideas. Read Mitra Kahn http://openaccess.city.ac.uk/1276/ or my efforts

https://www.researchgate.net/publication/304988655_Models_and_measurement_in_economics_2_A_short_overview_of_conceptual_differences_between_neoclassical_macro_models_and_the_national_accounts

DSGE economists never bothered to do this. Weird (well, not that weird - taking account of real life data would have meant taking unemployment and the government serious... Or the fact that the National Accounts identities only hold for nominal variables, not for deflated real variables). Anyway - as there is no system of DSGE consistent measurement of the macro-economy it can't be called a valid science.There are however systems consistent with the ideas of Keynes and Veblen...

Merijn Knibbe

Krzys 3:35 PM

So, we are witnessing a battle between a declining DSGE scam and ascending "Realistic assumptions" scam.

Both approaches are worthless, but I guess it will give an excuse to macroeconomists why they are useless: we just used the wrong paradigm, now we are switching to the new one. Just many more years of research is needed and we will be ready. Science!, as they say.

I'm curious how many economists are simply too blind to understand that this will lead nowhere and how many are simply cynical beyond belief.

I just don't understand the mentality. Wouldn't you like to do something productive? Like produce actual knowledge? Can you guys be satisfied with infinite curve fitting?

EliRabett 7:53 PM

Science, IEHO, has three touchstones. Coherence - your model and its assumptions should not contradict each other or lead to contradictory conclusions. Consilience - a good theory has a broad reach for explaining reality. Consensus - a theory which is coherent and consilient should lead to a consensus among practicioners. It is only within a strong consensus that people can talk to each other and extend the field.

It appears that macro misses out on a number of these.

Steve Roth 10:26 AM

"Romer basically says that macro (meaning business-cycle theory)"

Are you equating macro with business-cycle theory, or are you saying that Romer does?

In either case, I think this is another big problem with macro, its obsession with business cycles as opposed to long-term thriving and prosperity. eg, Gerald Friedman got tied in knots by this; he was trying to use "stimulus" thinking and arguments to talk about about multi-decadal possibilities.

Todd Kreider 12:57 PM

" (Though I do think he's too harsh on string theory, which often is just a kind of math that physicists do to keep themselves busy, and has no danger of hurting anyone, unlike macro theory.)"

I find it hard to believe Noah understands string theory well enough to justify such a strong opinion of it only existing to keep theorists employed. As much as I like "The Trouble With Physics" those reading should keep in mind that Lee Smolin acknowledges that maybe there is something to string theory.

And again, the focus of string theory in theoretical physics is harmful to the expansion of knowledge and economic growth if too many brains not only barked up the wrong tree - nothing wrong with that - but *continued* to bark up the wrong tree for years, ignoring other paths of understanding physics, which is Smolin's main point.

G3 McK 10:24 PM

I'm fond of observing that in addition to "cargo cult science", macroeconomics has often been likened to a religion. What religions do when the mainstream becomes intolerable for one reason or another is schism. Then after a number of years what used to be the mainstream dies out and the former schismatics become the mainstream.

Psychology went through this kind of crisis some years ago when the scientists split off from the clinicians, and created the Association for Psychological Science to contrast with the clinically-oriented American Psychological Association (the APA is the one that publishes the unscientific but influential Diagnostic and Statistical Manual).

All that heterodox economists need to do is gain some self-confidence and stop calling themselves derogatory names. That won't make them scientific, but it'll be a step in the right direction.

In order to be scientific, the standard method is to actually try predicting. Prediction is messy and provably fails to converge to any possible theory, but there are other authentic sciences that have this same theoretical limitation, like meteorology. This doesn't prevent meteorologists from constructing theories which make predictions that demonstrably get better and better year after year.

Why don't all these macro critics stop publishing in "unscientific" mainstream journals and setup their own J.Econ.Sci. that has rigorous scientific standards? Many of them have tenure or non-academic jobs (e.g. Roemer) and don't need to kowtow to committees who care only about established impact factors. It's been done elsewhere. It wasn't so long ago that one of the most prestigious biology journals Cell, was just an upstart new face on the block. All it takes is a strong editor and a pool of like-minded peer reviewers.

Tom Barson 9:33 AM

I think Paul Romer's self-serving ad hominem attacks should be identified as just that. One would hardly blame the older generation of Nobel laureates of conspiring to deny economic pre-eminence to Romer - look at how he behaves! - but I think they probably have better things to do.

I admit I haven't completely digested Romer's latest thunderbolt - I'm basing my comments more on Romer's "mathiness" series of a year ago. In that case, I went back and read the "mathy" papers that Romer was attacking. Mathy they were, but the Lucas and Moll paper at least was very clear about why it didn't see increasing returns-to-scale in growth models convincing: the intellectual property-driven economic sector just isn't, in their view, big enough. (BTW, that's almost exactly the same argument made by William Nordhaus against the AI "singularity" folks: it could happen, but none of today's macroeconomic data suggest that it is happening.)

To come back to the current discussion, I have no particular sympathy with the Lucas-Prescott-Sargent rational expectations / microfoundations / real business cycle approach - but the needed discussion of the defects of RBC has been underway for some time. And note that Romer's opening distillation of RBC makes its problems all about a supposed "exogenous" component, for which the subtext is that RBC's authors don't accept Romer's "endogenous" growth theory.

For twenty years Romer has been implying (and recently saying) that economists who don't accept endogenous growth theory have abandoned the canons of science and are either blind or indifferent to the truth. Over the same twenty years he seems to have produced very little theoretical work, while his targets have remained working economists. (Why, after all, should anyone continue to do theory, since Romer has discovered the truth?)

I wish Romer well at the World Bank. There is no doubt that his ideas around urbanization, for example, will bring an important and updated perspective to a development bank. But the very move suggest to me that the World Bank has not failed to note Romer's ability to propagandize an economic agenda - and that it values his political skills as much as his reputation as an economic theorist.

Anonymous 7:11 PM

It's easy to poke holes in existing methodology, but it's much more difficult to come up with viable alternatives and solutions. Do those who knock DSGE models really think we should go back to 1970's macro and reuse old-school Keynesian models? The empirical evidence against Keynesian multipliers is overwhelming (See Ramey for an overview). Methodologically, Keynesian models make just as many implausible, ad hoc assumptions as DSGE models, if not more. Their forecast accuracy is no better; private forecasters are mostly selling stories and scenarios, not forecasts that in any way will prove ex post to be accurate.

Tom Barson 8:44 AM

I think you are repeating - and it is a good reminder - the classic Mark Blaug argument that economists should not abandon the "best available" theory (even if its deficiencies are manifest) if there is no better replacement. I have no problem with that.

However, I think the discussion right now is about those manifest defects. And there are stirrings about what comes next. Noah has blogged several times on the new "empirical turn". And the Keynesians, who have never gone away, may yet stand up a rehabilitated theory. For a usable business cycle theory, there are really three tests to satisfy:
1) Normal forecasting capability (as you mention);
2) Convincing comparative statics on the effects of monetary or fiscal intervention. (RBC omitted this almost by definition.)
3) Some ability to detect pressures that are building toward a major shock. (I call this 'the Cassandra feature', since the predictions are unlikely to be believed or heeded.) Whether any model could really offer this is open to question, but it's a real question. The Fed always talks about "risks to the economy", but is the perception of those risks coming from the model? How did Warren Buffet know that the pile of financial derivatives would collapse, but bankers and regulators and economists not know it? One answer, at least for economists, is that rational expectations theory forces prediction of any kind of discontinuity completely out of the model. That part of Paul Romer's complaint seems to me to be valid.

[Oct 07, 2016] Heterodox macro - a reply to some replies

Notable quotes:
"... There is indeed a wing of heterodox economics that is anti-mathematical. Known as "Critical Realism" and centred on the work of Tony Lawson at Cambridge UK, it attributes the failings of economics to the use of mathematics itself... ..."
"... Steve also offers some useful criticism of Milton Friedman's ideas about how to evaluate a model's empirical success ( I agree ). ..."
"... The problem with 'heterodox economics' is that it is self-definition in terms of the other. It says 'we are not them' - but says nothing about what we are. This is because it includes everything outside of the mainstream, from reasonably well-defined and coherent schools of thought such as Post Keynesians, Marxists and Austrians, to much more nebulous and ill-defined discontents of all hues. To put it bluntly, a broad definition of 'people who disagree with mainstream economics' is going to include a lot of cranks. People will place the boundary between serious non-mainstream economists and cranks differently, depending on their perspective. ..."
"... Aside from rejecting standard neoclassical economics, the Marxists and the Austrians don't have a great deal in common. ..."
"... Noah seems to define heterodox economics as 'non-mathematical' economics. This is inaccurate. There is much formal modelling outside of the mainstream. ..."
"... Noah's post unfortunately seems to have elicited some rather defensive responses from the heterodox community, along the lines of " But we DO like mathematics! " or even, " Actually our mathematics is better than yours ". But this is to buy into Noah's core proposition. The heterodox economics community should - and, to be fair, in most cases does - reject it outright. Economics is not, and cannot be , exclusively mathematical...There is no need for the heterodox economic community to be defensive about vagueness. ..."
Aug 20, 2016 | noahpinionblog.blogspot.com

The other day I wrote a Bloomberg View post arguing that heterodox macroeconomics is not in any better shape than mainstream macroeconomics. As you might expect, this drew some lively responses.

One or two of the responses seemed to be arguing against the title of my post, rather than the contents. That's understandable, since titles are important. In this case, though, it probably detracted from the debate a great deal. The Bloomberg title people are good, and they usually get things right, but once in a while the title they choose doesn't quite capture the point I'm trying to make. This was one of those cases. The title they gave my post was "Economics Without Math Is Trendy, But It Doesn't Add Up." But actually, this wasn't what I was arguing. My point about non-mathy models wasn't that these are bad, useless, or inferior. It was that they're different from mathy models, and so comparing non-mathy models with mathy ones is an apples-to-oranges comparison. Both types of models have their uses, but you can't really compare one to the other. I make that pretty clear in the text of my post , but most of the people who responded tended to focus more on the title. Oh well. These things happen.

Anyway, on to some of the responses. The numbering here is arbitrary, corresponding to the order in which the tabs were open on my browser. (Note: The ordering has changed; see #4.)

Response 1: Steve Keen

First, we have a response by Steve Keen . Steve, unlike others, did get the point I was making about mathy vs. non-mathy models (Thanks, Steve!), and had some good commentary on the subject:

There is indeed a wing of heterodox economics that is anti-mathematical. Known as "Critical Realism" and centred on the work of Tony Lawson at Cambridge UK, it attributes the failings of economics to the use of mathematics itself...
What Noah might not know is that many heterodox economists are critical of this approach as well. In response to a paper by Lawson that effectively defined "Neoclassical" economics as any economics that made use of mathematics (which would define me as a Neoclassical!), Jamie Morgan edited a book of replies to Lawson entitled What is Neoclassical Economics? (including a chapter by me). While the authors agreed with Lawson's primary point that economics has suffered from favouring apparent mathematical elegance above realism, several of us asserted that mathematical analysis is needed in economics, if only for the reason that Noah gave in his article[.]
Steve also offers some useful criticism of Milton Friedman's ideas about how to evaluate a model's empirical success ( I agree ).

Steve also makes the useful point that linearization critically hampers many mainstream models ( I agree ).

Steve points out that non-mathy models can make qualitative forecasts. That's true. However, my point was that these are often a lot less actionable than quantitative forecasts. A non-mathy model might tell you that private-sector debt is dangerous, but it might not tell you how much of it is dangerous, or how dangerous. For that, you'd need some kind of mathy model. Steve definitely seems to get this point too, though, so I'm not disagreeing.

Steve then discusses overfitting of data, and points out that many mainstream models do this too. That's certainly true, although I think DSGE models tend to be a lot more parsimonious than SFC models or stuff like FRB/US. Actually, overfitting is one of the big criticisms of the most popular DSGE models in use at central banks.

Steve then addresses the idea that heterodox models are similar to mainstream ones. I never said they were, although I said there are some similarities between the FRB/US model and Wynne Godley-type SFC models. In fact, there are some similarities, though there are also differences. But in general, most heterodox models are very different from most mainstream models.

Steve also discusses my (admittedly too brief) mention of agent-based models, and has some good comments:

Largely speaking, this is true - if you want to use these models for macroeconomic forecasting. But they are useful for illustrating an issue that the mainstream avoids: "emergent properties". A population, even of very similar entities, can generate results that can't be extrapolated from the properties of any one entity taken in isolation...Neoclassical economists unintentionally proved this about isolated consumers as well, in what is known as the Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu theorem. But they have sidestepped its results ever since...Multi-agent modelling may not lead to a new policy-oriented theory of macroeconomics. But it acquaints those who do it with the phenomenon of emergent properties - that an aggregate does not function as a scaled-up version of the entities that comprise it. That's a lesson that Neoclassical economists still haven't absorbed.
I think this is right. Agent-based models have so far served as a demonstration of the fragility of representative agent models. In the future, they might be much more than that.

So anyway, I'd say I pretty much agree with Steve's response. Good stuff. (Though this person on Reddit had some problems with it.)


Response 2: Ari Andricopolous

Ari has a response as well . His response comes in the form of a list of things that he thinks macro models should not include. The list is:

  1. Microfoundations
  2. Neoliberal_rationality/
  3. Loanable funds
  4. Interest rate effects
  5. The financial sector

It's pretty clear that the last item on this list is misplaced, since Ari thinks one should include the financial sector in models.

Whether macro models should be microfounded is a big open question, but I'd like to note that by saying they shouldn't be, Ari is saying that agent-based models are bad. Agent-based models are as microfounded as they come.

As for rationality, I kind of disagree...humans observe and learn and adapt (OK, some more than others, I'll grant). Even though perfect rationality is probably pretty unrealistic, to insist that models totally ignore human observation, learning, and adaptation seems very dangerous for the realism of any model.

As for the loanable funds thing...yeah, OK, sure.


Response 3: Jo Michell

Jo Michell's response might have been the first to go up, but it's later on this list because...the numbering is arbitrary!

Jo, which I believe is short for "Jörmungandr", has a helpful diagram of the "schools" of macroeconomic thought. He also pushes back on the notion that "heterodox" is a useful classification at all:

The problem with 'heterodox economics' is that it is self-definition in terms of the other. It says 'we are not them' - but says nothing about what we are. This is because it includes everything outside of the mainstream, from reasonably well-defined and coherent schools of thought such as Post Keynesians, Marxists and Austrians, to much more nebulous and ill-defined discontents of all hues. To put it bluntly, a broad definition of 'people who disagree with mainstream economics' is going to include a lot of cranks. People will place the boundary between serious non-mainstream economists and cranks differently, depending on their perspective.
Another problem is that these schools of thought have fundamental differences. Aside from rejecting standard neoclassical economics, the Marxists and the Austrians don't have a great deal in common.
This is a good and useful point. My Bloomberg post really did bite off more than it could chew. My point was that there wasn't something better and more successful out there that by rights ought to already have displaced the (unsuccessful) mainstream approach. But in making that point, I touched on a number of different types of alternatives that aren't really closely connected. And I left out others (for example, Steve Keen's own work, and the Austrians).

Jo, unfortunately, appears to have gotten tripped up by the title:

Noah seems to define heterodox economics as 'non-mathematical' economics. This is inaccurate. There is much formal modelling outside of the mainstream.
Well, no, I don't define it that way, otherwise I wouldn't have discussed SFC models and agent-based models in my post.

Jo goes on to make some good points about mainstream models, and some of the problems they encounter.

Response 4: Frances Coppola

Frances Coppola, whom I cited in my Bloomberg post, also has a response . I responded to this post earlier, but Frances changed it, so I moved my response down to #4.

Frances still seems to misunderstand my post somewhat, and to have been tripped up by the title:

Noah's core proposition is that economics has no validity unless it is expressed in mathematical terms. He says that economics without mathematics doesn't add up.
Actually, I didn't make such a claim. Nor do I believe it. What I wrote was:
Broad idea-sketching is certainly a valuable activity. If theorists get lost in the specifics of their models, they can blind themselves to truly new hypotheses and mechanisms that would let them make big, radical changes. I do think this has happened to some degree in mainstream macro...But that doesn't mean that broad idea-sketching is a replacement for formal models. It's not an apples-to-apples comparison.
My point is that although non-mathematical econ is often valuable, it's not comparable to mathematical econ. Both have their place. But to say that a non-quantitative theory was successful at predicting the Great Recession, while a quantitative theory failed, is to hold the two theories to very different standards, since "predict" means different things for quantitative theories than it does for non-quantitative theories.

Frances goes on to discuss some of the limitations of purely quantitative models. She's broadly right. She then criticizes some heterodox theorists who, in her opinion, focus too much on math:

Noah's post unfortunately seems to have elicited some rather defensive responses from the heterodox community, along the lines of " But we DO like mathematics! " or even, " Actually our mathematics is better than yours ". But this is to buy into Noah's core proposition. The heterodox economics community should - and, to be fair, in most cases does - reject it outright. Economics is not, and cannot be , exclusively mathematical...There is no need for the heterodox economic community to be defensive about vagueness.
Again, Frances demonstrates a deep misunderstanding of my thesis. I never said that econ theory should be exclusively mathematical, nor do I believe it. This confusion is partly the result of the title, and partly the result of me just not explaining my thesis well enough.

Anyway, those are the responses I've seen. Thanks to everyone who took the time to respond!

[Oct 04, 2016] Trumponomics

Notable quotes:
"... Trump isn't attempting to appeal to neocons or neoliberals. (New Classical or New Keynesian.) That's Hillary's job. So losing this guy (neocon Bush economist) means nothing. ..."
"... Accusations of corruption against Hillary are ridiculous! Have you ever listened to Hillary's voice? Her speeches are like music to the ears! The only reason why corporations across various industrial complexes - financial, healthcare, private prison, military, Big Oil, etc. - pay Hillary $250k a speech is because they can afford to. The rest of society - the moochers - can only dream of being wealthy enough to enjoy a Hillary speech! ..."
"... I'm so tired of people hating on the rich and disparaging the Clintons' 'democratic innovation' techniques. They are clearly nothing more than envious ingrates and ignoramuses! ..."
"... All of the neoclassical tax cutting over the past 35 years has only provided a net benefit to the upper class. Only 30% of the US economy is related to international trade. So very little of the debt created with tax cuts has trickled down into trade deficits. ..."
"... But trade-liberalization/outsourcing policies, on the other hand, explain how a trade deficit has an accompanying budget deficit (according to the Twin Deficits hypothesis.) If a country is spending more on imports than it is earning in exports it will have to borrow the money to pay for them. ..."
"... Trump's absurd tax cuts would only benefit the top 20%. They would not increase demand for imports or increase the trade deficit. All of this money would be in the form of whopping budget deficits and growing government debt. It would be a spectacular failure. A better one than what Hillary would bring: because the Republicans would be on the hook for it. (If Hillary wins, the Democrats are on the hook for a 12 year Great Recession by 2020. That kicks the New Deal can down the road to 2024.) ..."
"... Sanders supporters dislike Republicans more than Hillary supporters do according to polls. They're not going to go for trickle-down economics. Sanders's message was that the problem with the economy and political system are people like Trump. That's why he proposed a significant financial transaction tax. Sanders supporters agree with Sanders, Dean Baker and Jared Bernstein that corporate trade deals could be made more fair. ..."
"... "Corporate" trade deals aren't the issue. It is capital markets. Republicans wants a total abolition of regulations on capital markets. Not only will Trumps deficits need more foreign finance, he will gut the economy to bring that foreign finance in or gut the economy if it doesn't come in if he trade saber rattles. The only other option is much such large government spending cuts, that creates a recession as well creating capital flight. ..."
"... Mankiw reveals like Krugman he's never been to East Asia, nor is he the least bit curious about why the US developed in the first place. If he had studied economic development or East Asia he would know that blistering high interest rates (+50%) were common in the East Asian countries during their periods of stunning growth. Rising interest rates from the reduced flow of capital would also be associated with - for the first time in 40 years -- positive incentives to invest in US tradable goods production. ..."
"... Watch Charles Ferguson's Inside Job for information on how morally and financially compromised US economists are. ..."
"... And Mankiw does this specifically in the context of offering support to idiotic Republican policies, to pander to the Republican mandarins who hire him every 4 years as economic adviser to their Presidential candidate (and to sell more textbooks at Red-state schools). ..."
"... Why does Mankiw think he deserves to sell his own ass like a two-bit prison whore, while Navarro and Ross can't? ..."
Sep 29, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com

Ron Waller -> DrDick...

Trump isn't attempting to appeal to neocons or neoliberals. (New Classical or New Keynesian.) That's Hillary's job. So losing this guy (neocon Bush economist) means nothing.

This argument against Trump's economic plan would appear to be nonsensical. Interest rates are not marked to international markets. They are set by the central bank to manage demand and inflation. (According to 'orthodox' economics, protectionism would negatively affect GDP and put a downward pressure on demand, inflation and interest rates. So this argument is doubly senseless.)

I can't imagine that many economists understand international trade or they wouldn't be in favor of the highly mercantlist global economy that free-trade globalization has produced.

The 35 years of trade deficits the US has run with undeveloped mercantilist countries is a triple whammy: 1) jobs, production and investment flow out of the country reducing GDP, real incomes and demand; 2) the trade deficit has an accompanying budget deficit (according to the Twin Deficits hypothesis); this creates rising government debt; spending cuts further depress demand; 3) for every dollar that flows out of the country from imported goods, a dollar must flow back into the country in the form of foreign investment (i.e. debt owed to foreign countries.)

This process is certainly no Carnot engine. Simply a linear process of wealth being transferred from one source to another (much of it in debt.) A process that is quickly running out of steam.

My impression is that only a return to the progressive Keynesian New Deal era (that began with FDR and ended with Reagan) can prevent the global economy from collapsing into fascist revolutions and world war. (Repeating the history of the 1930s; Trump would make a better Herbert Hoover than Hillary, that's for sure.)

Ron Waller -> sanjait... , -1
Accusations of corruption against Hillary are ridiculous! Have you ever listened to Hillary's voice? Her speeches are like music to the ears! The only reason why corporations across various industrial complexes - financial, healthcare, private prison, military, Big Oil, etc. - pay Hillary $250k a speech is because they can afford to. The rest of society - the moochers - can only dream of being wealthy enough to enjoy a Hillary speech!

I'm so tired of people hating on the rich and disparaging the Clintons' 'democratic innovation' techniques. They are clearly nothing more than envious ingrates and ignoramuses!

Ron Waller -> spencer... , -1
This is putting the cart before the horse.

All of the neoclassical tax cutting over the past 35 years has only provided a net benefit to the upper class. Only 30% of the US economy is related to international trade. So very little of the debt created with tax cuts has trickled down into trade deficits.

But trade-liberalization/outsourcing policies, on the other hand, explain how a trade deficit has an accompanying budget deficit (according to the Twin Deficits hypothesis.) If a country is spending more on imports than it is earning in exports it will have to borrow the money to pay for them.

Clearly any form of non-regulated stimulus (tax cuts or income redistribution) that primes anemic demand by putting more money in the hands of the bottom 80% will produce a bigger trade deficit. The only way to eliminate a trade deficit with a mercantilist country is with tariffs.

If Trump's plan is to raise GDP by eliminating the trade deficit with some form of regulatory measures, then clearly this could not raise the trade deficit.

Trump's absurd tax cuts would only benefit the top 20%. They would not increase demand for imports or increase the trade deficit. All of this money would be in the form of whopping budget deficits and growing government debt. It would be a spectacular failure. A better one than what Hillary would bring: because the Republicans would be on the hook for it. (If Hillary wins, the Democrats are on the hook for a 12 year Great Recession by 2020. That kicks the New Deal can down the road to 2024.)

Peter K. -> pgl... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 01:27 PM
Sanders supporters dislike Republicans more than Hillary supporters do according to polls. They're not going to go for trickle-down economics. Sanders's message was that the problem with the economy and political system are people like Trump. That's why he proposed a significant financial transaction tax. Sanders supporters agree with Sanders, Dean Baker and Jared Bernstein that corporate trade deals could be made more fair.
Ben Groves -> Peter K.... , -1
"Corporate" trade deals aren't the issue. It is capital markets. Republicans wants a total abolition of regulations on capital markets. Not only will Trumps deficits need more foreign finance, he will gut the economy to bring that foreign finance in or gut the economy if it doesn't come in if he trade saber rattles. The only other option is much such large government spending cuts, that creates a recession as well creating capital flight.

Sanders doesn't support deregulated capital markets, he can swagger about 'trade'.

Saigo Takamori : , -1
Mankiw reveals like Krugman he's never been to East Asia, nor is he the least bit curious about why the US developed in the first place. If he had studied economic development or East Asia he would know that blistering high interest rates (+50%) were common in the East Asian countries during their periods of stunning growth. Rising interest rates from the reduced flow of capital would also be associated with - for the first time in 40 years -- positive incentives to invest in US tradable goods production.

US economists are paid to confuse people and be confused. Watch Charles Ferguson's Inside Job for information on how morally and financially compromised US economists are.

No wonder the US is an economic basket case on the cusp of becoming a third world country. Thanks economists! You guys have the best advice! Free trade and comparative advantage are real winners! Just ask Haiti, the second most open economy in the Americas after the US.

vic twente : , -1
This is rich coming from Mankiw.

I've watched Mankiw, on video, on several occasions, make patently false claims about economic policy based on first-year macro that's completely and utterly disproven at even a third-year level.

And Mankiw does this specifically in the context of offering support to idiotic Republican policies, to pander to the Republican mandarins who hire him every 4 years as economic adviser to their Presidential candidate (and to sell more textbooks at Red-state schools).

Why does Mankiw think he deserves to sell his own ass like a two-bit prison whore, while Navarro and Ross can't?

[Oct 01, 2016] The conventional [neoliberal] view serves to protect us from the painful job of thinking

Oct 01, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com

RC AKA Darryl, Ron : September 30, 2016 at 07:16 AM

RE: Stop pretending that an economy can be controlled

[Wow, this is interesting. I wonder what reason, Sandwichman, and cm think of this?]

http://oecdinsights.org/2016/09/29/stop-pretending-that-an-economy-can-be-controlled/

Angel Gurría, OECD Secretary-General

The crisis exposed some serious flaws in our economic thinking. It has highlighted the need to look at economic policy with more critical, fresh approaches. It has also revealed the limitations of existing tools for structural analysis in factoring in key linkages, feedbacks and trade-offs – for example between growth, inequality and the environment.

We should seize the opportunity to develop a new understanding of the economy as a highly complex system that, like any complex system, is constantly reconfiguring itself in response to multiple inputs and influences, often with unforeseen or undesirable consequences. This has many implications. It suggests policymakers should be constantly vigilant and more humble about their policy prescriptions, act more like navigators than mechanics, and be open to systemic risks, spillovers, strengths, weaknesses, and human sensitivities. This demands a change in our mind-sets, and in our textbooks. As John Kenneth Galbraith once said, "the conventional view serves to protect us from the painful job of thinking."

This is why at the OECD we launched an initiative called New Approaches to Economic Challenges (NAEC). With this initiative we want to understand better how the economy works, in all its complexity, and design policies that reflect this understanding. Our aim is to consider and address the unintended consequences of policies, while developing new approaches that foster more sustainable and inclusive growth.

Complexity is a common feature of a growing number of policy issues in an increasingly globalised world employing sophisticated technologies and running against resource constraints.

The report of the OECD Global Science Forum (2009) on Applications of Complexity Science for Public Policy reminds us of the distinction between complicated and complex systems. Traditional science (and technology) excels at the complicated, but is still at an early stage in its understanding of complex phenomena like the climate.

For example, the complicated car can be well understood using normal engineering analyses. An ensemble of cars travelling down a highway, by contrast, is a complex system. Drivers interact and mutually adjust their behaviours based on diverse factors such as perceptions, expectations, habits, even emotions. To understand traffic, and to build better highways, set speed limits, install automatic radar systems, etc., it is helpful to have tools that can accommodate non-linear and collective patterns of behaviour, and varieties of driver types or rules that might be imposed. The tools of complexity science are needed in this case. And we need better rules of the road in a number of areas.

This is not an academic debate. The importance of complexity is not limited to the realm of academia. It has some powerful advocates in the world of policy. Andy Haldane at the Bank of England has thought of the global financial system as a complex system and focused on applying the lessons from other network disciplines – such as ecology, epidemiology, and engineering – to the financial sphere. More generally, it is clear that the language of complexity theory – tipping points, feedback, discontinuities, fat tails – has entered the financial and regulatory lexicon. Haldane has shown the value of adopting a complexity lens, providing insights on structural vulnerabilities that built up in the financial system. This has led to policy suggestions for improving the robustness of the financial system.

Closer to home, Bill White, Chairman of our Economic and Development Review Committee (EDRC) has been an ardent advocate of thinking about the economy as a complex system. He has spoken in numerous OECD meetings – in part as an explanation and in part as a warning – that systems build up as a result of cumulative processes, can have highly unpredictable dynamics and can demonstrate significant non-linearity. As a result Bill has urged policymakers to accept more uncertainty and be more prudent. He also urged economists to learn some exceedingly simple but important lessons from those that have studied or work with complex systems such as biologists, botanists, anthropologists, traffic controllers, and military strategists.

Perhaps the most important insight of complexity is that policymakers should stop pretending that an economy can be controlled. Systems are prone to surprising, large-scale, seemingly uncontrollable, behaviours. Rather, a greater emphasis should be placed on building resilience, strengthening policy buffers and promoting adaptability by fostering a culture of policy experimentation.

At the OECD, we are starting to embrace complexity. For several years we have been mapping the trade "genome" with our Trade in Value Added (TiVA) database to explain the commercial interconnections between countries.

We have examined the possibilities for coupling economic and other systems models, for example environmental (climate) and societal (inequalities). Our work on the Costs of Inaction and Resource Constraints: Implications for Long-term Growth (CIRCLE) is a key example of linking bio-physical models and economic models to gauge the impact of environmental degradation and climate change on the economy.

We are also looking at governing complex systems in areas as diverse as education and international trade policy. And we are looking at the potential for tapping big data – an indispensable element of complexity modelling approaches. But there remains much to do to fully enrich our work with the perspectives of complexity.

The OECD is delighted to work with strong partners – the Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET) Oxford, and the European Commission to help policy-makers advance the use of complex systems thinking to address some of the most difficult challenges.

An important question remains. How can the insights and methods of complexity science be applied to assist policymakers as they tackle difficult problems in areas such as environmental protection, financial regulation, sustainability or urban development?

At the Workshop on Complexity and Policy on 29-30 September at the OECD, we will help find the answer – stimulate new thinking, new policy approaches and ultimately better policies for better lives.


[Sometimes when it seems like you are just howling at the moon there really is a new day coming.]

Reply Friday, September 30, 2016 at 07:16 AM reason -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , Friday, September 30, 2016 at 07:39 AM
I think it is both correct, and entirely wrong-headed.

Firstly, we have not believed that the economy can be controlled (we were just trying to steer it) - the guiding principle was that it didn't need to be controlled which is something completely different. It also falls into the trap of talking about "the economy" as though the economy was an organism that had its own purposes, rather than as a set of institutions that ultimately exist to serve human beings (a job which it achieves with quite varying degrees of success). I won't say this approach is necessarily bound to fail, I just doubt that it will be alone sufficient.

RC AKA Darryl, Ron said in reply to reason ... , Friday, September 30, 2016 at 08:01 AM
The OECD is one of those institutions. Yep, they have plenty of their own assumptions. Complexity has been mentioned here before.

Exactly what they mean is indeterminable from the general principles mentioned, but examples are worthwhile. You might read them to mean be cautious about leaps of faith such as financial deregulation because bad stuff CAN happen.

RC AKA Darryl, Ron said in reply to RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , Friday, September 30, 2016 at 08:58 AM
"...Perhaps the most important insight of complexity is that policymakers should stop pretending that an economy can be controlled. Systems are prone to surprising, large-scale, seemingly uncontrollable, behaviours. Rather, a greater emphasis should be placed on building resilience, strengthening policy buffers and promoting adaptability by fostering a culture of policy experimentation..."

[In context I took this more to mean that economic models are probabilistic at best rather than deterministic rather than that it said policy makers in the OECD were performing central planning of the economy, which everyone knows is not true.]

anne -> reason ... , -1
Firstly, we have not believed that the economy can be controlled (we were just trying to steer it) - the guiding principle was that it didn't need to be controlled which is something completely different. It also falls into the trap of talking about "the economy" as though the economy was an organism that had its own purposes, rather than as a set of institutions that ultimately exist to serve human beings (a job which it achieves with quite varying degrees of success)....

[ Nice. ]

RGC : , Friday, September 30, 2016 at 08:09 AM
Re: Stop pretending that an economy can be controlled - OECD Insights

"The crisis exposed some serious flaws in our economic thinking. It has highlighted the need to look at economic policy with more critical, fresh approaches. It has also revealed the limitations of existing tools for structural analysis in factoring in key linkages, feedbacks and trade-offs – for example between growth, inequality and the environment.

We should seize the opportunity to develop a new understanding of the economy as a highly complex system that, like any complex system, is constantly reconfiguring itself in response to multiple inputs and influences, often with unforeseen or undesirable consequences. This has many implications. It suggests policymakers should be constantly vigilant and more humble about their policy prescriptions, act more like navigators than mechanics, and be open to systemic risks, spillovers, strengths, weaknesses, and human sensitivities. This demands a change in our mind-sets, and in our textbooks. As John Kenneth Galbraith once said, "the conventional view serves to protect us from the painful job of thinking."
..................................
Complex systems such as chemical processes are managed by feedback control systems that specify a desired output and then measure deviation from that control point (the error signal) to adjust the inputs and thus return to the desired setpoint.

I have promoted the use of control theory concepts in economics before. From a previous post:

Auto-control:

Did you ever think about how you keep the temperature in your house at a comfortable level even though the weather is unpredictable and can change a lot?
Well, maybe the level of the economy could be controlled on similar principles. Maybe economists could borrow from the control theory that is employed in air conditioning thermostats.
For example, if we wanted to maintain full employment we could adjust inputs in a similar manner to the way heat and cooling is adjusted in your house. Just as heat is added when the temperature gets too low, government jobs could be added when private employment falls short. When the temperature starts to get too high ( full employment is achieved), heat could be sucked out ( no more jobs would be added and/or higher taxes could be imposed) to cool things off.
This is an appealing analogy because, like the weather, the economy is inherently unpredictable and, like the air conditioning in your house, you could keep things comfortable without the need of forecasting the unknowable.
So maybe economists should forsake their DSGE models and instead study control theory.
...................
In my view such approaches are not promoted because they require central control by the state and our elite establishment quashes such threats to their dominance. That is why Keynes' conclusions were subverted:

"The context is as follows: in an interview with the leftist British journalist Kingsley Martin (1897–1969) in the New Statesman of January 1939, Keynes – commenting on the need for a new interventionist economic system and at the same time the need to avoid the authoritarianism of the Fascist and communist states – said this:

"The question is whether we are prepared to move out of the nineteenth-century laissez faire state into an era of liberal socialism, by which I mean a system where we can act as an organized community for common purposes and to promote social and economic justice, whilst respecting and protecting the individual-his freedom of choice, his faith, his mind and its expression, his enterprise and his property." (Moggridge 1982: 500 = Keynes and Martin 1939: 123).
............
Many people now accept that we have traveled the wrong path since the 1950's. I would submit that economists would do well to go back to the ideas of Keynes, Kalecki, Lerner and perfect those concepts within a framework of automatic stabilization. This would be greatly facilitated if some prominent economists would have the guts to say again what Keynes was saying in the 30's.


anne -> RGC... , Friday, September 30, 2016 at 08:23 AM
What would a recommended reading of or about Abba Lerner be? Though Lerner is frequently mentioned, I still have no idea where to begin reading. Would this do?

http://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/wp272.pdf

July, 1999

Functional Finance and Full Employment: Lessons from Lerner for Today?
By Mathew Forstater

pgl -> anne... , Friday, September 30, 2016 at 08:41 AM
Lerner wrote a lot. But his comment reminded me of the Functional Finance piece so I think you got the right one.
pgl -> anne... , Friday, September 30, 2016 at 08:44 AM
Lerner's Symmetry Theorem was noted the other day:

http://www2.econ.iastate.edu/classes/econ355/choi/lerner.htm

Of course this related to Navarro's nonsense on VAT and trade so I doubt this was the paper relevant here.

anne -> pgl... , Friday, September 30, 2016 at 08:52 AM
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Lerner_symmetry_theorem

The Lerner symmetry theorem is a result used in international trade theory, which states that, based on an assumption of a zero balance of trade (that is, the value of exported goods equals the value of imported goods for a given country), an ad valorem import tariff (a percentage of value or an amount per unit) will have the same effects as an export tax. The theorem is based on the observation that the effect on relative prices is the same regardless of which policy (ad valorem tariffs or export taxes) is applied.

The theorem was developed by economist Abba P. Lerner in 1936.

anne -> RGC... , -1
http://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/wp272.pdf

July, 1999

Functional Finance and Full Employment: Lessons from Lerner for Today?
By Mathew Forstater

The Asian Crisis, with the fallout in Latin America and the transition economies; the Russian default; continuing troubles in Japan; weaknesses in the structure of the new European EMU; volatility on Wall Street; deflationary pressures in the global economy: recent economic developments invite a reconsideration of some of our most deeply held beliefs concerning economic theory and public policy. Even within the hallowed halls of mainstream economics, voices of dissent can be heard. Paul Krugman, Joseph Stiglitz, and Jeffrey Sachs are among those whose recent proclamations indicate that we have entered a period in which orthodox views are being openly questioned, creating an atmosphere characterized by a crisis of confidence.

Such periods of impending crisis and open expressions of self-doubt, questioning our most deeply held beliefs about the way the world works, creates a climate in which the ideas of the great unorthodox thinkers of the past may be revisited. The work of those who in the past dedicated their lives to formulating solutions to the challenges of modern capitalist economies may contain lessons applicable to the contemporary situation. It is in this spirit that this paper revisits the early works of Abba Lerner, outlining fifteen such lessons regarding macroeconomic theory and policy, as fresh in the context of the current scene as they were some five decades ago when they were first formulated.

Lesson #1: Full employment, price stability, and a decent standard of living for all are fundamental macroeconomic goals, and it is the responsibility of the state to promote their attainment.

Lesson #2: Policies should be judged on their ability to achieve the goals for which they are designed and not on any notion of whether they are "sound" or otherwise comply with the dogmas of traditional economics.

Lesson #3: "Money Is a Creature of the State"

Lesson #4: Taxing is not a funding operation.

Lesson #5: Government Borrowing is not a funding operation.

Lesson #6: The primary purpose of taxation is to influence the behavior of the public.

Lesson #7: The primary purpose of government bond sales is to regulate the overnight interest rate.

Lesson #8: Bond sales logically follow from, rather than precede, government spending....

RGC -> anne... , Friday, September 30, 2016 at 08:53 AM
This has some history:

MMP Blog #31: FUNCTIONAL FINANCE: Monetary and Fiscal Policy for Sovereign Currencies
Posted on January 8, 2012

By L. Randall Wray

http://neweconomicperspectives.org/2012/01/mmp-blog-31-functional-finance-monetary.html

anne -> RGC... , Friday, September 30, 2016 at 09:13 AM
http://neweconomicperspectives.org/2012/01/mmp-blog-31-functional-finance-monetary.html

January 8, 2012

Functional Finance: Monetary and Fiscal Policy for Sovereign Currencies
By L. Randall Wray

Today we will lay out Abba Lerner's approach to policy. In the 1940s he came up with what he called the functional finance approach to policy.

Lerner's Functional Finance Approach. Lerner posed two principles:

First Principle: if domestic income is too low, government needs to spend more. Unemployment is sufficient evidence of this condition, so if there is unemployment it means government spending is too low.

Second Principle: if the domestic interest rate is too high, it means government needs to provide more "money", mostly in the form of bank reserves.

The idea is pretty simple. A government that issues its own currency has the fiscal and monetary policy space to spend enough to get the economy to full employment and to set its interest rate target where it wants. (We will address exchange rate regimes later; a fixed exchange rate system requires a modification to this claim.) For a sovereign nation, "affordability" is not an issue-it spends by crediting bank accounts with its own IOUs, something it can never run out of.If there is unemployed labor, government can always afford to hire it-and by definition, unemployed labor is willing to work for money.

Lerner realized that this does not mean government should spend as if the "sky is the limit"-runaway spending would be inflationary (and, as discussed many times, it does not presume that government spending won't affect the exchange rate). When Lerner first formulated the functional finance approach (in the early 1940s), inflation was not a major concern-the US had recently lived through deflation in the Great Depression. However, over time, inflation became a serious concern, and Lerner proposed a form of wage and price controls to constrain inflation that he believed would result as the economy nears full employment. Whether or not that would be an effective and desired way of attenuating inflation pressures is not our concern here. The point is that Lerner was only arguing that government should use its spending power with a view to moving the economy toward fullemployment-while recognizing that it might have to adopt measures to fight inflation.

Lerner rejected the notion of "sound finance"-that is the belief that government ought to run its finances as if it were like a household or a firm. He could see no reason for the government to try to balance its budget annually, over the course of a business cycle, or ever. For Lerner, "sound" finance (budget balancing) was not "functional"-it did not help to achieve the public purpose (including, for example, full employment). If the budget were occasionally balanced, so be it; but if it never balanced, that would be fine too. He also rejected any attempt to keep a budget deficit below any specific ratio to GDP, as well as any arbitrary debt to GDP ratio. The "correct" deficit would be the one that achieves full employment.

Similarly the "correct" debt ratio would be the one consistent with achieving the desired interest rate target. This follows from his second principle: if government issues too much debt, it has by the same token issued too few bank reserves and cash. The solution is for the treasury and central bank to stop selling bonds,and, indeed, for the central bank to engage in open market purchases (buying treasuries by crediting the selling banks with reserves). That will allow the overnight rate to fall as banks obtain more reserves and the public gets more cash.

Essentially, the second principle just says that government ought to let the banks,households, and firms achieve the portfolio balance between "money" (reserves and cash) and bonds desired. It follows that government bond sales are not really a "borrowing" operation required to let the government deficit spend. Rather, bond sales are really part of monetary policy, designed to help the central bank to hit its interest rate target. All of that is consistent with the modern money view advanced previously....

anne -> RGC... , -1
Properly edited link:

https://pro.creditwritedowns.com/2012/01/monetary-and-fiscal-policy-for-sovereign-currencies.html

January 9, 2012

Functional Finance: Monetary and Fiscal Policy for Sovereign Currencies
By L. Randall Wray

[Sep 29, 2016] A recession initiated by a financial crisis cause consumers to reduce their own borrowing, so erroneous analogies between governments and households resonate

Sep 29, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com

pgl : , A recession initiated by a financial crisis cause consumers to reduce their own borrowing, so erroneous analogies between governments and households resonate

Simon Wren Lewis (Mainly Macro) highlights his new paper on why some supported austerity even if it was a disaster. Krugman's latest adds more.
Dan Kervick -> pgl... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 05:21 AM
It seems to me this line from Wren-Lewis is the biggie as far as the Great Recession/Longer Depression is concerned:

"A recession initiated by a financial crisis is also likely to see consumers reducing their own borrowing, and so (erroneous) analogies between governments and households resonate."

In 2008/9 the public was (rightly) convinced that the collapse was due to deflation of a financial bubble blown up by many years of excessive private borrowing and debt-fueled over-consumption: too much credit card debt; too much borrowing against (inflated) home values; two much speculative gambling with, and ponzi profiting from, cutesy and overvalued financial instruments. That correct, instinctive evaluation of the situation was backed up by numbers showing that the total private debt to GDP ratio had reached a level unseen since 1928, and by the sudden discovery of the many analyses of many experienced, sober, but neglected financial observers who had been predicting some kind of collapse for years.

Since the public was thus primed to believe that, going forward, the private economy had to reduce its overall debt load, it was very easy to convince them that governments, being just another part of the overall economy, had to do the same thing.

But what Wren-Lewis doesn't seem to mention is that the public had already been primed by decades of Norquistian, Petersonian and Rubinite deficit-hectors, debt-despairers and entitlement-exterminators to believe that our deficits were a very bad thing, that government was too big, and that we were headed for a "fiscal train wreck" because of our undisciplined budgets and government spending. They were thus easily convinced that the financial crisis also had something to to with the problems alleged by this bipartisan team of budget Casandras all finally coming a-cropper.

We had endless cadres of Republican politicians promoting hysteria over the public debt and also decrying the very size of government, whether deficit-financed or not.

We had Bill Clinton running around bragging about his "reinvention" (shrinking) of government and his dot-com boom-assisted surprise surplus.

We had Joe Biden telling everyone that the financial collapse was caused by "putting two wars on a credit card".

We had the Concord Coalition and the Peterson Institute gearing up their zombies for the Fix the Debt onslaught that eventually saddled us with an economic discourse driven by a stupid budget-reduction commission in the middle a deep recession!

Hatred of governments and their spending habits had already given us years of gradually building stagnation due to declining public investment and a consequent secular shift from capital formation to consumption. But the voters saw only that all of the Serious People in both parties were strongly in favor of this "disciplined" decimation of government. So why in the world wouldn't they end up supporting its continuation?

ken melvin -> Dan Kervick... , -1
Very good.

[Sep 29, 2016] Economists Keep Getting It Wrong Because the Media Coverup Their Mistakes

Notable quotes:
"... Most workers suffer serious consequences when they mess up on their jobs. Custodians get fired if the toilet is not clean. Dishwashers lose their job when they break too many dishes, but not all workers are held accountable for the quality of their work. ..."
"... At the top of the list of people who need not be competent to keep their job are economists. Unlike workers in most occupations, when large groups of economists mess up they can count on the media covering up their mistakes and insisting it was just impossible to understand what was going on. ..."
Sep 29, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com

anne : September 29, 2016 at 05:18 AM , September 29, 2016 at 05:18 AM

http://cepr.net/blogs/beat-the-press/economists-keep-getting-it-wrong-because-the-media-coverup-their-mistakes

September 29, 2016

Economists Keep Getting It Wrong Because the Media Coverup Their Mistakes

Most workers suffer serious consequences when they mess up on their jobs. Custodians get fired if the toilet is not clean. Dishwashers lose their job when they break too many dishes, but not all workers are held accountable for the quality of their work.

At the top of the list of people who need not be competent to keep their job are economists. Unlike workers in most occupations, when large groups of economists mess up they can count on the media covering up their mistakes and insisting it was just impossible to understand what was going on.

This is first and foremost the story of the housing bubble. While it was easy * to recognize that the United States and many other countries were seeing massive bubbles that were driving their economies, which meant that their collapse would lead to major recessions, the vast majority of economists insisted there was nothing to worry about.

The bubbles did burst, leading to a financial crisis, double-digit unemployment in many countries, and costing the world tens of trillions of dollars of lost output. The media excused this extraordinary failure by insisting that no one saw the bubble and that it was impossible to prevent this sort of economic and human disaster. Almost no economists suffered any consequences to their career as a result of this failure. The "experts" who determined policy in the years after the crash were the same people who completely missed seeing the crash coming.

We are now seeing the same story with trade. The New York Times has a major magazine article ** on the impact of trade on the living standards of workers in the United States and other wealthy countries. The subhead tells readers:

"Trade is under attack in much of the world, because economists failed to anticipate the accompanying joblessness, and governments failed to help."

Of course many economists did not anticipate the negative impact of trade, but of course many of us did. The negative impact was entirely predictable and predicted. (Here are a few from Center for Economic and Policy Research, *** **** ***** there are many more books and papers from my friends at the Economic Policy Institute.) The argument is straightforward: trade policy has been designed to put manufacturing workers in direct competition with low paid workers in the developing world. This costs jobs and puts downward pressure on the wages of these workers. It also puts downward pressure on the wages of less-educated workers more generally, as displaced manufacturing workers seek jobs in retail and other sectors. Stagnating wages and increasing inequality are the predicted result of this pattern of trade, not a surprising outcome.

If economists were like custodians and dishwashers, the failure to recognize this obvious outcome of trade policy would have put them out on the street. Instead, we get major news outlets like the New York Times, telling us this is all a remarkable surprise. No one could have seen that trade would have bad outcomes for large segments of the workforce. Rather than lose their jobs, economists can still draw comfortable six figure salaries as they tell reporters how it was impossible for them to understand the economy.

Economic theory tells us that if economists don't face consequences for completely messing up on the job then they have no incentive to get things right. If the custodian never pays any price for not cleaning the toilet, then they won't clean the toilet. In the same way, if the media and the country always grant a "who could have known" amnesty to large chunks of the economics profession when it gets things completely wrong, then there is no reason to expect that economists will ever get things right. All they have to do is say the same things as other elite economists say, and if it turns out to be wrong, the NYT will just run major news articles explaining that no one could have known better.

There is one other important point that needs emphasis here. There was nothing inherent to trade that required growing inequality, it was the structure of trade policy that gave us this result. There are millions of very bright ambitious people in the developing world who would be very happy to study to meet U.S. standards and work as doctors, dentists, lawyers and other professionals in the United States. We could have designed trade agreements to facilitate this process.

The result would be massive economic gains in the form of lower cost health care, dental care, legal services and other professionals services. In the case of physicians alone, if the increased supply brought the pay of our doctors down to the levels of Western Europe and Canada, we would save close to $100 billion a year. This comes to roughly $700 a year in savings for every family in the United States. And, this would lead to a reduction in inequality.

Our elite economists have chosen not to discuss this sort of trade opening. (They also rarely discuss reducing rather than increasing protectionist barriers like patents and copyrights.) These issues are discussed in more depth in my forthcoming book, "Rigged: How Globalization and the Rules of the Modern Economy Were Structured to Make the Rich Richer" (coming to a website near year in October). But the key point here is that economists should know better, and if they were doing their job, they did.

* http://cepr.net/documents/publications/housing_2002_08.pdf

** http://www.nytimes.com/2016/09/29/business/economy/more-wealth-more-jobs-but-not-for-everyone-what-fuels-the-backlash-on-trade.html

*** http://cepr.net/documents/publications/trade_2008_01.pdf

**** http://cepr.net/documents/publications/faf_2006_11.pdf

***** http://cepr.net/documents/publications/trade_2001_10_03.pdf

-- Dean Baker

Paine -> anne... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 06:47 AM
Dean is a dream

I'll leave it at that --

Peter K. -> Paine... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 06:56 AM
the job class happy warrior
Peter K. -> anne... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 06:56 AM
"The argument is straightforward: trade policy has been designed to put manufacturing workers in direct competition with low paid workers in the developing world. This costs jobs and puts downward pressure on the wages of these workers. It also puts downward pressure on the wages of less-educated workers more generally, as displaced manufacturing workers seek jobs in retail and other sectors. Stagnating wages and increasing inequality are the predicted result of this pattern of trade, not a surprising outcome."

This is surprising to PGL and Krugman who argue the Fed will just adjust to keep full employment or at least that's what the models tell them.

pgl -> Peter K.... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 07:07 AM
Dean is talking about protectionism for drug companies, doctors etc. and free trade for the rest of us. On this score he is exactly right and I have said so many times. This is a very different issue from the macroeconomic ones. I would accuse you of once again misrepresenting what I have said. But to be fair - you are too stupid to get these distinctions so maybe you are not lying. I do wish I had a smarter internet stalker.
Tom aka Rusty -> anne... , -1
Baker get the diagnosis correct.

Baker's standard solutions do very little for blue collar workers. Having a cheaper doctor and lawyer don't help much for the unemployed and underemployed.

[Sep 29, 2016] A General Theory Of Austerity

Sep 29, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com

anne : September 29, 2016 at 04:45 AM , September 29, 2016 at 04:45 AM

http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2016/09/29/a-general-theory-of-austerity/

September 29, 2016

A General Theory Of Austerity?
By Paul Krugman

Simon Wren-Lewis has an excellent new paper * trying to explain the widespread resort to austerity in the face of a liquidity trap, which is exactly the moment when such policies do the most harm. His bottom line is that

"austerity was the result of right-wing opportunism, exploiting instinctive popular concern about rising government debt in order to reduce the size of the state."

I think this is right; but I would emphasize more than he does the extent to which both the general public and Very Serious People always assume that reducing deficits is the responsible thing to do. We have some polling from the 1930s, showing a strong balanced-budget bias even then:

[Chart]

I think Simon would say that this is consistent with his view that large deficits grease the rails for deficit phobia, since Franklin Roosevelt's administration did run up deficits and debt that were unprecedented for peacetime. But has there ever been a time when the public favored bigger deficits?

Meanwhile, as someone who was in the trenches during the US austerity fights, I was struck by how readily mainstream figures who weren't especially right-wing in general got sucked into the notion that debt reduction was THE central issue. Ezra Klein documented this phenomenon ** with respect to Bowles-Simpson: ***

"For reasons I've never quite understood, the rules of reportorial neutrality don't apply when it comes to the deficit. On this one issue, reporters are permitted to openly cheer a particular set of highly controversial policy solutions. At Tuesday's Playbook breakfast, for instance, Mike Allen, as a straightforward and fair a reporter as you'll find, asked Simpson and Bowles whether they believed Obama would do 'the right thing' on entitlements - with 'the right thing' clearly meaning 'cut entitlements.' "

Meanwhile, as Brad Setser points out, the International Monetary Fund - whose research department has done heroic work puncturing austerity theories and supporting a broadly Keynesian view of macroeconomics - is, in practice, pushing for fiscal contraction **** almost everywhere.

Again, this doesn't exactly contradict Simon's argument, but maybe suggests that there is a bit more to it.

* http://www.bsg.ox.ac.uk/sites/www.bsg.ox.ac.uk/files/documents/BSG-WP-2016-014.pdf

** https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2013/02/20/the-problem-with-alan-simpson/

*** https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/National_Commission_on_Fiscal_Responsibility_and_Reform

*** http://blogs.cfr.org/setser/2016/08/22/imf-cannot-quit-fiscal-consolidation-in-asian-surplus-countries/

anne -> anne... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 04:50 AM
http://www.bsg.ox.ac.uk/sites/www.bsg.ox.ac.uk/files/documents/BSG-WP-2016-014.pdf

May, 2016

A General Theory of Austerity
By Simon Wren-Lewis

Abstract

Austerity is defined as a fiscal contraction that causes a significant increase in aggregate unemployment. For the global economy, or an economy with a flexible exchange rate, or a monetary union as a whole, an increase in unemployment following a fiscal consolidation can and should be avoided because monetary policy can normally offset the demand impact of the consolidation. The tragedy of global austerity after 2010 was that fiscal consolidation was not delayed until monetary policy was able to do this.

An individual member of a currency union that requires a greater fiscal contraction than the union as a whole cannot use its own monetary policy to offset the impact of fiscal consolidation. Even in this case, however, a sharp and deep fiscal contraction is unlikely to be optimal. Providing this economy is in a union where the central bank acts as a sovereign lender of last resort, a more gradual fiscal adjustment is likely to minimise the unemployment cost.

As the theory behind these propositions is simple and widely accepted, the interesting question is why global austerity happened. Was austerity an unfortunate accident, or is there a more general political economy explanation for why it occurred? Answering this question is vital to avoid the next global recession being followed by yet more austerity.

jonny bakho -> anne... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 05:43 AM
The answer is that politicians and pundits have a flawed understanding of inflation and its relationship to hyperinflation.
Some economists promoted a seriously flawed interpretation of the 1970s stagflation that solidified myths about inflation.

As Max Planck said, "Science advances one funeral at a time." We need the current generation of economists and their failed models to be replaced by a new generation that does not suffer from the same mythology.

Peter K. -> anne... , -1
If one just read Krugman or Kevin Drum you wouldn't understand how Bill Clinton declared "the era of Big Government is over" or how after he was first elected he listened to his top two economic advisers Robert Rubin and Alan Greenspan and dropped his middle class spending campaign promise in favor of deficit reduction.

Greenspan promised Clinton lower rates in exchange for reducing government. Clinton ended "welfare as we knew it."

But Greenspan didn't regulate this increase in private investment. It led to the tech-stock bubble and a shadow banking system which was susceptible to a banking panic.

According to Hillary, Bush's tax cuts caused the housing bubble and Great Recession. It's a little more complicated. But this cuts against Krugman and Drum's narrative that the Clinton years were nothing but awesome.

Summers told Brooksley Born that derivatives shouldn't be regulated b/c the market is magic.

Obama reinforced the narrative that government should tighten its belt during hard times like households do. This is exactly wrong.

Maybe it's understandable for politicians to pander for short-term political expediency but it's hurts the long-term ideological conflict.

There's the right and there's the left and Obama and Clinton tried to straddle the two ideologies which just waters down the left's appeal and pull.

That's why the millennials and more progressive workers aren't as excited for Hillary's candidacy. That's why Sanders energized them.

Now I agree with Sanders that a Trump Presidency would be a disaster, but this doesn't preclude me from correcting Krugman's outlook as some center-leftists would insist in their binary thinking.

pgl : , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 01:41 AM
Simon Wren Lewis (Mainly Macro) highlights his new paper on why some supported austerity even if it was a disaster. Krugman's latest adds more. mainly macro Why was austerity once so popular
Dan Kervick -> pgl... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 05:21 AM
It seems to me this line from Wren-Lewis is the biggie as far as the Great Recession/Longer Depression is concerned:

"A recession initiated by a financial crisis is also likely to see consumers reducing their own borrowing, and so (erroneous) analogies between governments and households resonate."

In 2008/9 the public was (rightly) convinced that the collapse was due to deflation of a financial bubble blown up by many years of excessive private borrowing and debt-fueled over-consumption: too much credit card debt; too much borrowing against (inflated) home values; two much speculative gambling with, and ponzi profiting from, cutesy and overvalued financial instruments. That correct, instinctive evaluation of the situation was backed up by numbers showing that the total private debt to GDP ratio had reached a level unseen since 1928, and by the sudden discovery of the many analyses of many experienced, sober, but neglected financial observers who had been predicting some kind of collapse for years.

Since the public was thus primed to believe that, going forward, the private economy had to reduce its overall debt load, it was very easy to convince them that governments, being just another part of the overall economy, had to do the same thing.

But what Wren-Lewis doesn't seem to mention is that the public had already been primed by decades of Norquistian, Petersonian and Rubinite deficit-hectors, debt-despairers and entitlement-exterminators to believe that our deficits were a very bad thing, that government was too big, and that we were headed for a "fiscal train wreck" because of our undisciplined budgets and government spending. They were thus easily convinced that the financial crisis also had something to to with the problems alleged by this bipartisan team of budget Casandras all finally coming a-cropper.

We had endless cadres of Republican politicians promoting hysteria over the public debt and also decrying the very size of government, whether deficit-financed or not.

We had Bill Clinton running around bragging about his "reinvention" (shrinking) of government and his dot-com boom-assisted surprise surplus.

We had Joe Biden telling everyone that the financial collapse was caused by "putting two wars on a credit card".

We had the Concord Coalition and the Peterson Institute gearing up their zombies for the Fix the Debt onslaught that eventually saddled us with an economic discourse driven by a stupid budget-reduction commission in the middle a deep recession!

Hatred of governments and their spending habits had already given us years of gradually building stagnation due to declining public investment and a consequent secular shift from capital formation to consumption. But the voters saw only that all of the Serious People in both parties were strongly in favor of this "disciplined" decimation of government. So why in the world wouldn't they end up supporting its continuation?

ken melvin -> Dan Kervick... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 06:28 AM
Very good.
Benedict@Large -> Dan Kervick... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 06:38 AM
+1

Exactly. This all having started with the 70s arrival of monetarism, essentially a gold standard with no gold. While no one really paid attention to gold standard (depressionary) budgeting until Clinton I, the rhetoric was being put into place such that, even today, the Democrats still hail Clinton's "balanced budget" disaster as if it were God's gift, when in reality it was the kickoff to consumers cannibalizing the home equity just to keep pace, and the ultimate reason the 2008 crash was so severe on household spending. Hillary Clinton; be forewarned.

Hobroken -> Dan Kervick... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 08:03 AM
Hatred of governments and their spending habits
"

If governmental fat cats and billionaire lobbyists would spend more time at fixing the obvious, they would have less time for looting the public treasure. Do you see how they could have prevented the HD, Hoboken disaster?

They could have removed the overpowered transformers that oversupplied coulombs to the Catenary wire that supplied current to the Pantograph of the Hoboken train that just now crashed into the station full of passengers. All the transformers at the end of the line should be scaled down to prevent this sort of disaster, plus all the transformers near a curves in the roadbed should be scaled back to prevent excess power from speeding train up enough to jump the track. No!

You can't always depend on the engineer's judgment to prevent these disasters. Can't always depend on high-tech-safety devices to prevent! Hell! High-tech can be hacked by the North Koreans. You need to change the deep infrastructure of power available.

Get back to work,

Governmental
goof-off-s --

jonny bakho -> pgl... , Thursday, September 29, 2016 at 05:24 AM
Most people have a flawed understanding of inflation.
Sustainable inflation means BOTH wages and prices go up.
Most people think of inflation only in terms of price increases so we get: Prices go up, wages stay the same: BAD.

A minimum level of inflation is necessary to allow relative prices and wages to reset smoothly.
Prices and wages are sticky downward.
It is unsustainable for a business to deflate prices below fixed costs.
A price can be reset downward by inflation (if inflation is high enough) erosion and thus is less likely to be below fixed costs.
Businesses don't cut wages of employees, they layoff employees.
Businesses don't only cut prices, they cut production.
Workers with leverage and fixed payments cannot afford to work for less.
Inflation allows relative wages to deflate without causing issues with fixed payments.
Everyone agrees that deflation is bad because it is associated with lower output and higher unemployment.
Inflation and deflation are a continuum. Inflation that is too low is only marginally better than deflation.
Inflation must be high enough to absorb relative price resets demanded by the majority of economic shocks or the process of resetting wages and prices will be extended and be a continued drag on an economy.
The evidence clearly suggests that US inflation in the 21st Century has been much too low. A higher inflation target is clearly necessary.

People misunderstand hyperinflation.
Hyperinflation is associated with an increased money supply.
The increased money supply is an effect of hyperinflation not its cause.
Under hyperinflation, an economy needs increasingly larger amounts of currency for transactions, so governments print more money to meet demand.

Hyperinflation is caused by loss of confidence in a currency.
Under hyperinflation, the risk of complete loss of buying power of a currency factors into the price that vendors are willing to accept for goods and services.
Example: In the 1865 US, Confederate currency hyper inflated, not because too much was printed, but because the Confederate government was facing elimination and the currency no longer being honored. 90 percent of the currency could have been eliminated and prices still would have hyperinflated.

Major Myths:
Printing money does not cause hyperinflation, loss of confidence does.
A higher rate of inflation does not make hyperinflation more likely.
A lower rate of inflation is NOT always better for an economy than a higher rate.
Politicians and pundits need to unlearn these inflation myths.

DrDick -> pgl... , -1
Krugman makes some good points, adding to Wren Lewis's excellent observations. I would point out, however, that neither of them acknowledges that most of our media are economic and policy illiterates and incapable of understanding the issues, while the general public has been sold on the idiocy that national budgets are just like household budgets (mostly by that same illiterate media).

[Sep 26, 2016] The Outlaws of Political Economy

Sep 26, 2016 | econospeak.blogspot.com

EconoSpeak

Perusing Palgrave's Dictionary of Political Economy from 1894 alerted me to the odd interaction of a pair of distinctions. The first distinction was between the study of "what is" and "what ought to be." The second distinction was between "economic science" (or "economics") and "political economy." Economic science presumably distinguished itself from political economy by its strict focus on describing "what is" rather than on prescribing "what ought to be."

Palgrave's
explains the latter distinction to have been at least partly motivated by the confusion that arose over just what kind of laws -- legal or natural -- so-called "laws of political economy" were. Even after the attempt at rebranding, however:

"...even well-educated persons still occasionally speak of "laws of political economy" as being "violated" by the practice of statesmen, trades-unions and other individuals and bodies.
You can't "break" scientific laws. They are simply generalized descriptions of fact. A flying airplane doesn't break the law of gravity. It conforms to a more comprehensive complex of physical laws. The law of gravity isn't the only law.

Palgrave's Dictionary further noted that the "great complexity and variety of circumstance which surround every economic problem are such as to render the enunciation of general laws, on a large scale, barely possible and if possible barely useful."

So the whole "positive" economics rigamarole wasn't just about methodological rigor. It was a purification ritual to rid the political economist of the stigma of dogma. Economists who invoke the violation of so-called laws aren't only forfeiting any legitimate claim to economic science. They are contaminating their profession with atavistic hokum.

Speaking of atavistic hokum, I have been trying to track down ANY accessible published record of a trade unionist or advocate of the reduction of the hours of labor EVER overtly expressing the belief that there is a fixed amount of work to be done or a certain quantity of labor to be performed or whatever synonymous equivalent. There is none.

There is a reasonable explanation for this absence of evidence. The alleged false belief is expressed in abstract language that was not vernacular to the people accused of harbouring it. It's the wrong answer to a question workers never asked themselves.

False belief requires two conditions to be fulfilled: 1. the idea is false and 2. it is believed by someone to be true. The matrix below shows the possible states of belief and falsehood. An idea does not have to be true to be "not false" and it doesn't have to be believed to be false to be "not believed to be true." The fallacy claim asserts a simplistic (and false!) polarization in which the beliefs of the "unenlightened" are "the opposite" of economic orthodoxy.

In an 1861 letter to the Times of London "A Master Builder" alleged that George Potter, secretary of the carpenters' union, and his associates had "absurdly argued that there was only a certain amount of work to be done" during a 1859 strike and lock-out of the London building trades. There is a detailed report on the 1859 strike in an 1860 report on Trades' Societies and Strikes published by the National Association for the Promotion of Social Science. The 23-page account presents several items of correspondence from Potter outlining the union's position with not a hint of a lump in the load. The "certain amount of work to be done" was what Mr. Master Builder thought he heard when he mentally translated Potter's argument into his own capitalistic patois .

There was something else interesting in the 685-page document -- an overarching controversy about whether or not labor was a commodity just like any other and therefore whether or not unions violated the laws of political economy by trying to regulate wages and hours of work. The employers who maintained this were pretty dogmatic about it. "Rates of wages cannot be settled by mediation, but must be left to the free operation of supply and demand." It's the law!

This was not simply political economy It was vulgar political economy of the most self-serving and disingenuous kind. One has no difficulty whatsoever finding multiple evocations by employers of the so-called laws of political economy but the elusive lump remains "one of the most tenaciously held and generally least articulated of trade union beliefs."

Least articulated? Least articulated is an understatement. Try NEVER articulated. There is no there there. The alleged false belief is a pure projection by the laws-of-political-economy crowd onto the unbeliever. The eighth annual report of the New York Bureau of Labor Statistics for the year 1890 contains the responses of over 600 labor union locals to the question of whether and why they support an eight-hour day. Not one claims there is only a certain quantity of work to be done.

Below is an example of what an overt statement of the theory of the lump of labor looks like. It is not from a trade union manifesto or a pamphlet of the eight-hour day movement. It is from a propaganda tract put out by Nassau Senior's crew of Whig-Benthamites in defense of their New Poor Laws, which abolished outdoor relief and established the workhouse test:

The fact is, there is a certain quantity of work to be done, and the question is who ought to do it -- those who live by their labour, and their labour only, or those who have thrown themselves on public charity.
Can anyone find such an unequivocal articulation of the false belief by a trade unionist? Of course not. It's not the way that workers talk about their work. Work is not an abstract, disembodied quantity to those who do it. It is part of a lived experience. "A certain quantity of work to be done" is political economy speak, plain and simple. It's ceteris paribus and "all else being equal."

Paradoxically, for old school vulgarians there both is and is not a certain quantity of work to be done. There is a certain quantity of work to be done when it comes to disparaging the idea that workers might increase wages their through collective action:

There is a certain quantity of work to be done, and a certain number of hands to do it; if there be much work and comparatively few hands, wages will rise; if little work and an excess of hands, wages will fall. It is self-evident that combinations and strikes cannot alter this law. They can neither increase capital, nor diminish population; and, therefore, it is utterly impossible, in the very nature of things, that they ever can procure a permanent rise of wages.
But there isn't a certain amount of work when it comes to explaining why such foolish action isn't even necessary:
There is, say they, a certain quantity of labour to be performed. This used to be performed by hands, without machines, or with very little help from them... The principle itself is false. There is not a precise limited quantity of labour, beyond which there is no demand. Trade is not hemmed in by great walls, beyond which it cannot go. By bringing our goods cheaper and better to market, we open new markets, we get new customers, we encrease the quantity of labour necessary to supply these, and thus we are encouraged to push on, in hope of still new advantages. A cheap market will always be full of customers.
Five years ago I compiled a database of over 500 instances of the claim in books and journal articles between 1890 and 2010 ( Excel file ). That's 500 claims without a single overt statement of the false belief from an alleged believer. Six claimants (about one percent) named culprits whose argument "arguably depends upon..." "makes an error equivalent to..." "indicates a belief..." "seems hopelessly involved in..." "is an example of the strange conclusions to which one may be carried by clinging clinging firmly to..." and "are driven by implicit assumptions." Each of those turns out to be a false alarm -- an uncharitable, speculative inference. Five hundred boys crying "wolf" and not a single wolf to be seen?

This is an astonishing performance. This compulsion to repeat is not "careless" or "dogmatic." It's neurotic.

The patient cannot remember the whole of what is repressed in him, and what he cannot remember may be precisely the essential part of it.. He is obliged to repeat the repressed material as a contemporary experience instead of remembering it as something in the past.
The atavistic return of the repressed "laws of political economy" conforms faithfully to a description toward the end of chapter 3 of Beyond the Pleasure Principle where Freud talks about the experiences of "people with whom every human relationship ends in the same way" and gives as a "singularly affecting" final example the events in a romantic epic, in which the hero, Tancred, repeatedly slays his beloved, Clorinda, each time she reappears in a different guise. In this example, as Gavriel Reisner notes,
Freud reverses the compulsion to repeat, showing how we will sometimes injure others in order to avoid injuring ourselves. Freud concludes that we often project the internal, masochistic drive as the external, sadistic drive, victimizing others to redirect an intent toward self-victimization.
The utilitarian political economists styled themselves advocates for "the greatest good for the greatest number" and viewed opponents as apologists for narrow special interests. The supposed laws they discovered, which operated through isolated exchanges between individuals in the market, vindicated a system of natural liberty and consequently freedom entailed obedience to those laws. Collective action and collective bargaining violated the laws of individual exchange, resulting in sub-optimal outcomes. Such perversity could only be motivated by false beliefs. The false beliefs of the adversary were presumably the opposite of the true beliefs of the faithful: trade unions operated through tyranny and their bizzaro-world political economy assumed that less output meant more income.

Reality discredited that polemic of political economy and calmer heads sought to rebrand the enterprise as economics. The ersatz laws were scaled back to tendencies, which operated within the admittedly abstract ceteris paribus pound of the economist's static model. Real life and the evolution of economic relations operated outside the ceteris paribus pound but maybe the static model could shed light on dynamic economic activity.

It was no longer fashionable to denounce "The Evils of Collective Bargaining in Trades' Unions" (Thomas Cree, 1898) because it was increasingly understood that the so-called laws of supply and demand operated quite differently with regard to the peculiar commodity of labor power (Richard Ely, 1886):

While those who sell other commodities are able to influence the price by a suitable regulation of production, so as to bring about a satisfactory relation between supply and demand, the purchaser of labor has it in his own power to determine the price of this commodity and the other conditions of sale.
But even as old-guard political economy was being gradually displaced by rebranded economics in the universities, employers' associations and business journalism emerged to propound and propagate the old-time religion. The break with quasi-scientific, quasi-legalistic, quasi-religious pseudo-laws was ambivalent, the reconciliation surreptitious. Employers' associations told the college teachers what to teach. Textbooks served up a smorgasbord of the obsolescent and the innovative.

In this twilight of science and superstition, the fallacy claim offered uncertain economists a distinctive advantage. It enabled them to continue to denounce violations of the laws of political economy without actually having to specify which laws were being violated. That left them exempt from any obligation to justify the validity of defunct laws. The burden of proof deftly shifted and the providence of economic science affirmed, albeit by default.

Economic science thus gets to have its "what is" humility... and eat its "what ought to be" hubris too! Evidence be damned.



That there was one particular offense singled out for condemnation by the self-appointed economic police is suggested by the example given in Palgrave's Dictionary for the common confusion between the legislative and scientific senses of law: "Thus it is often said that to regulate the hours of labour, or to introduce differential import duties, is to break economic law." The anachronism of such a view should require no explanation. The hours of labor are regulated.

Any proposal to repeal the Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938 on the grounds that it "breaks economic law" would no doubt be laughed at by Paul Krugman, David Autor, Jonathan Portes or Alan Manning. But, inadvertently, that is precisely the historical grammar of their lump-of-labor fallacy taunt. Although there is no logical imperative that links the law-breaking claim to the fallacy claim, they have been inseparably paired in usage from their inception. To invoke the latter is either to imply the former or it is a non sequitur.

At long last, economists, have you no scientific self-respect ? On this labor day, 2016, would you still insist that regulating of the hours of work breaks the laws of economics? Posted by Sandwichman at

[Sep 26, 2016] Equilibrium and Information Literacy

Sep 23, 2016 | econospeak.blogspot.com
"Everybody except Joan Robinson agrees about capital theory." -- Robert Solow (as paraphrased by Robinson)
An essential text in my researches on mercantilism, usury and bills of exchange is Raymond de Roover's Gresham on Foreign Exchange, which just happens to be stored in part of SFU's library that is under construction and thus inaccessible. The immediate unavailability of that book, however, led to a fortuitous discovery.

I browsed in the call number section of the library's general collection where de Roover's book would have been and Robert Leeson's Ideology and the International Economy caught my eye. I flipped through the book and noticed on page 19 the delicious quote from Joan Robinson that, "the free-trade doctrine is just a more subtle form of mercantilism."

The quote is from a 1966 lecture, "The New Mercantilism" that is included in a collection of essays, Contributions to Modern Economics, which also contains "Capital Theory Up-to-Date," a 1970 review of C. E. Ferguson's The Neoclassical Theory of Production and Distribution, in which Robinson reprises her parody of neo-Walrasian, neo-neoclassical capital " leets. " Leets is steel spelled backward and makes its debut in "Equilibrium Growth Models," Robinson's 1961 review of James Meade's Neo-Classical Theory of Economic Growth.

This allegedly ectoplasmic representation of capital is, in a nutshell, the crux of the "Cambridge capital controversy," which Robinson launched with her 1952 challenge, "I leave it to those who draw production functions to say what marginal productivity and the elasticity of substitution mean when labour and capital are the factors of production." Looking back, in 1978, on her 1952 essays and the "long struggle to escape... habitual modes of thought and expression," Robinson stressed that "it was precisely from the concept of equilibrium that Keynes was struggling to escape..." Contrarily, though:

"...textbook teaching in the department of so-called macro theory was an attempt to push Keynes into short-term equilibrium. ... The grand neoclassical synthesis (now known as bastard Keynesianism) was a more ambitious attempt to reduce the General Theory to a system of equilibrium."
In responding to Robinson's leets critique, Robert Solow began by acknowledging "much truth" to the objection that "the usual production functions, allowing for more or less substitutability between capital and labor, attribute to 'capital' a degree of malleability which contradicts common observation." He then distinguished between the "econometrically-minded person" who would view the overly malleable capital as a "specification error" and others -- presumably including Robinson -- who judge it to be "a doctrinal error; and its consequence is a kind of Fall from Grace." Seven years later, Robinson had this to say about "doctrinal disputes":
Many economists, nowadays, who are interested in practical questions are impatient of doctrinal disputes. What does it matter, they are inclined to say, let him have his leets, what harm does it do? But the harm that the neo-neoclassicals have done is, precisely, to block off economic theory from any discussion of practical questions.
If one is concerned about actual unemployment in an actual economy, Robinson later explained, one "has to discuss it in terms of processes taking place in actual history. The concept of equilibrium is incompatible with history. It is a metaphor based on movements in space applied to processes taking place in time." In other words, it is not just some kind of ethereal affectation to object to the concept of equilibrium -- it is an argument with irrevocable real-world consequences.

The failure of what Robinson dismissed as "bastard Keynesianism" also had real-world doctrinal consequences. "In the era of stagflation, this notion [that equilibrium growth can be achieved through fiscal and monetary 'fine tuning'] has been discredited and the quantity theory of money is blossoming afresh amongst its ruins." This 'blossoming,' incidentally, was not something Robinson welcomed.

Well, my interlibrary loan of de Roover's Gresham on Foreign Exchange has arrived, so I'm off up the hill to pick it up. To be continued...

[Sep 16, 2016] We Need to Move on from Existing Theories of the Economy

Notable quotes:
"... [Dave Elder-Vass accepted my invitation to write a response to my discussion of his recent book, ..."
"... Profit and Gift in the Digital Economy ..."
"... ). Elder-Vass is Reader in sociology at Loughborough University and author as well of ..."
"... The Causal Power of Social Structures: Emergence, Structure and Agency ..."
"... The Reality of Social Construction ..."
"... , discussed ..."
"... . Dave has emerged as a leading voice in the philosophy of social science, especially in the context of continuing developments in the theory of critical realism. Thanks, Dave!] ..."
"... Profit and Gift in the Digital Economy ..."
"... Financial Times ..."
"... the argument for Pareto optimality of real market systems is patently false, but it continues to be trotted out constantly. ..."
Sep 16, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com
by Dave Elder-Vass at Understanding Society: September 15, 2016
Guest post by Dave Elder-Vass : [Dave Elder-Vass accepted my invitation to write a response to my discussion of his recent book, Profit and Gift in the Digital Economy ( link ). Elder-Vass is Reader in sociology at Loughborough University and author as well of The Causal Power of Social Structures: Emergence, Structure and Agency and The Reality of Social Construction , discussed here and here . Dave has emerged as a leading voice in the philosophy of social science, especially in the context of continuing developments in the theory of critical realism. Thanks, Dave!]

We need to move on from existing theories of the economy

Let me begin by thanking Dan Little for his very perceptive review of my book Profit and Gift in the Digital Economy . As he rightly says, it's more ambitious than the title might suggest, proposing that we should see our economy not simply as a capitalist market system but as a collection of "many distinct but interconnected practices". Neither the traditional economist's focus on firms in markets nor the Marxist political economist's focus on exploitation of wage labour by capital is a viable way of understanding the real economy, and the book takes some steps towards an alternative view.

Both of those perspectives have come to narrow our view of the economy in multiple dimensions. Our very concept of the economy has been derived from the tradition that began as political economy with Ricardo and Smith then divided into the Marxist and neoclassical traditions (of course there are also others, but they are less influential). Although these conflict radically in some respects they also share some problematic assumptions, and in particular the assumption that the contemporary economy is essentially a capitalist market economy, characterised by the production of commodities for sale by businesses employing labour and capital. As Gibson-Graham argued brilliantly in their book The End Of Capitalism (As We Knew It): A Feminist Critique of Political Economy , ideas seep into the ways in which we frame the world, and when the dominant ideas and the main challengers agree on a particular framing of the world it is particularly difficult for us to think outside of the resulting box. In this case, the consequence is that even critics find it difficult to avoid thinking of the economy in market-saturated terms.

The most striking problem that results from this (and one that Gibson-Graham also identified) is that we come to think that only this form of economy is really viable in our present circumstances. Alternatives are pie in the sky, utopian fantasies, which could never work, and so we must be content with some version of capitalism – until we become so disillusioned that we call for its complete overthrow, and assume that some vague label for a better system can be made real and worthwhile by whoever leads the charge on the Bastille. But we need not go down either of these paths once we recognise that the dominant discourses are wrong about the economy we already have.

To see that, we need to start defining the economy in functional terms: economic practices are those that produce and transfer things that people need, whether or not they are bought and sold. As soon as we do that, it becomes apparent that we are surrounded by non-market economic practices already. The book highlights digital gifts – all those web pages that we load without payment, Wikipedia's free encyclopaedia pages, and open source software, for example. But in some respects these pale into insignificance next to the household and family economy, in which we constantly produce things for each other and transfer them without payment. Charities, volunteering and in many jurisdictions the donation of blood and organs are other examples.

If we are already surrounded by such practices, and if they are proliferating in the most dynamic new areas of our economy, the idea that they are unworkably utopian becomes rather ridiculous. We can then start to ask questions about what forms of organising are more desirable ethically. Here the dominant traditions are equally warped. Each has a standard argument that is trotted out at every opportunity to answer ethical questions, but in reality both standard arguments operate as means of suppressing ethical discussions about economic questions. And both are derived from an extraordinarily narrow theory of how the economy works.

For the mainstream tradition, there is one central mechanism in the economy: price equilibration in the markets, a process in which prices rise and fall to bring demand and supply into balance. If we add on an enormous list of tenuous assumptions (which economists generally admit are unjustified, and then continue to use anyway), this leads to the theory of Pareto optimality of market outcomes: the argument that if we used some other system for allocating economic benefits some people would necessarily be worse off. This in turn becomes the central justification for leaving allocation to the market (and eliminating 'interference' with the market).

There are many reasons why this argument is flawed. Let me mention just one. If even one market is not perfectly competitive, but instead is dominated by a monopolist or partial monopolist, then even by the standards of economists a market system does not deliver Pareto optimality, and an alternative system might be more efficient. And in practice capitalists constantly strive to create monopolies, and frequently succeed! Even the Financial Times recognises this: in today's issue (Sep 15 2016) Philip Stevens argues, "Once in a while capitalism has to be rescued from the depredations of, well, capitalists. Unconstrained, enterprise curdles into monopoly, innovation into rent-seeking. Today's swashbuckling "disrupters" set up tomorrow's cosy cartels. Capitalism works when someone enforces competition; and successful capitalists do not much like competition".

So the argument for Pareto optimality of real market systems is patently false, but it continues to be trotted out constantly. It is presented as if it provides an ethical justification for the market economy, but its real function is to suppress discussion of economic ethics: if the market is inherently good for everyone then, it seems, we don't need to worry about the ethics of who gets what any more.

The Marxist tradition likewise sees one central mechanism in the economy: the extraction of surplus from wage labour by capitalists. Their analysis of this mechanism depends on the labour theory of value, which is no more tenable that mainstream theories of Pareto optimality (for reasons I discuss in the book). Marxists consistently argue as if any such extraction is ethically reprehensible. Marx himself never provides an ethical justification for such a view. On the contrary, he claims that this is a scientific argument and disowns any ethical intent. Yet it functions in just the same way as the argument for Pareto optimality: instead of encouraging ethical debate about who should get what in the economy, Marxists reduce economic ethics to the single question of the need to prevent exploitation (narrowly conceived) of productive workers.

We need to sweep away both of these apologetics, and recognise that questions of who gets what are ethical issues that are fundamental to justice, legitimacy, and political progress in contemporary societies. And that they are questions that don't have easy 'one argument fits all' answers. To make progress on them we will have to make arguments about what people need and deserve that recognise the complexity of their social situations. But it doesn't take a great deal of ethical sophistication to recognise that the 1% have too much when many in the lower deciles are seriously impoverished, and that the forms of impoverishment extend well beyond underpaying for productive labour.

I'm afraid that I have written much more than I intended to, and still said very little about the steps I've taken in the book towards a more open and plausible way of theorising how the economy works. I hope that I've at least added some more depth to the reasons Dan picked out for attempting that task.

Peter K. : , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 01:37 PM
"This in turn becomes the central justification for leaving allocation to the market (and eliminating 'interference' with the market)."

Krugman is a neoliberal, although a softer, kinder neoliberal much better than Mankiw, Cowen or the Republicans.

"pgl -> Peter K....

Please find me a Krugman discussion where he says nothing can be done about income inequality. This is so straw man that the winds have blown this stupid lie away.

Reply Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 12:59 PM"

http://www.nytimes.com/2016/08/15/opinion/wisdom-courage-and-the-economy.html

Wisdom, Courage and the Economy
by Paul Krugman
AUG. 15, 2016

It's fantasy football time in political punditry, as commentators try to dismiss Hillary Clinton's dominance in the polls - yes, Clinton Derangement Syndrome is alive and well - by insisting that she would be losing badly if only the G.O.P. had nominated someone else. We will, of course, never know. But one thing we do know is that none of Donald Trump's actual rivals for the nomination bore any resemblance to their imaginary candidate, a sensible, moderate conservative with good ideas.

Let's not forget, for example, what Marco Rubio was doing in the memorized sentence he famously couldn't stop repeating: namely, insinuating that President Obama is deliberately undermining America. It wasn't all that different from Donald Trump's claim that Mr. Obama founded ISIS. And let's also not forget that Jeb Bush, the ultimate establishment candidate, began his campaign with the ludicrous assertion that his policies would double the American economy's growth rate.

Which brings me to my main subject: Mrs. Clinton's economic vision, which she summarized last week. It's very much a center-left vision: incremental but fairly large increases in high-income tax rates, further tightening of financial regulation, further strengthening of the social safety net.

It's also a vision notable for its lack of outlandish assumptions. Unlike just about everyone on the Republican side, she isn't justifying her proposals with claims that they would cause a radical quickening of the U.S. economy. As the nonpartisan Tax Policy Center put it, she's "a politician who would pay for what she promises."

So here's my question: Is the modesty of the Clinton economic agenda too much of a good thing? Should accelerating U.S. economic growth be a bigger priority?

For while the U.S. has done reasonably well at recovering from the 2007-2009 financial crisis, longer-term economic growth is looking very disappointing. Some of this is just demography, as baby boomers retire and growth in the working-age population slows down. But there has also been a somewhat mysterious decline in labor force participation among prime-age adults and a sharp drop in productivity growth.

The result, according to the Congressional Budget Office, is that the growth rate of potential G.D.P. - what the economy could produce at full employment - has declined from around 3.5 percent per year in the late 1990s to around 1.5 percent now. And some people I respect believe that trying to get that rate back up should be a big goal of policy.

But as I was trying to think this through, I realized that I had Reinhold Niebuhr's famous Serenity Prayer running through my head: "Grant me the serenity to accept the things I cannot change, courage to change the things I can, and wisdom to know the difference." I know, it's somewhat sacrilegious applied to economic policy, but still.

After all, what do we actually know how to do when it comes to economic policy? We do, in fact, know how to provide essential health care to everyone; most advanced countries do it. We know how to provide basic security in retirement. We know quite a lot about how to raise the incomes of low-paid workers.

I'd also argue that we know how to fight financial crises and recessions, although political gridlock and deficit obsession has gotten in the way of using that knowledge.

On the other hand, what do we know about accelerating long-run growth? According to the budget office, potential growth was pretty stable from 1970 to 2000, with nothing either Ronald Reagan or Bill Clinton did making much obvious difference. The subsequent slide began under George W. Bush and continued under Mr. Obama. This history suggests no easy way to change the trend.

Now, I'm not saying that we shouldn't try. I'd argue, in particular, for substantially more infrastructure spending than Mrs. Clinton is currently proposing, and more borrowing to pay for it. This might significantly boost growth. But it would be unwise to count on it.

Meanwhile, I don't think enough people appreciate the courage involved in focusing on things we actually know how to do, as opposed to happy talk about wondrous growth.

When conservatives promise fantastic growth if we give them another chance at Bushonomics, one main reason is that they don't want to admit how much they would have to cut popular programs to pay for their tax cuts. When centrists urge us to look away from questions of distribution and fairness and focus on growth instead, all too often they're basically running away from the real issues that divide us politically.

So it's actually quite brave to say: "Here are the things I want to do, and here is how I'll pay for them. Sorry, some of you will have to pay higher taxes." Wouldn't it be great if that kind of policy honesty became the norm?

Peter K. -> Peter K.... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 01:39 PM
"For while the U.S. has done reasonably well at recovering from the 2007-2009 financial crisis,"

Reasonably well?

"Now, I'm not saying that we shouldn't try. I'd argue, in particular, for substantially more infrastructure spending than Mrs. Clinton is currently proposing, and more borrowing to pay for it. "

Then why was he for Hillary over Bernie Sanders who did campaign on substantially more infrastructure spending?

Instead Krugman argues that we need to lower our hopes and expectations.

"According to the budget office, potential growth was pretty stable from 1970 to 2000, with nothing either Ronald Reagan or Bill Clinton did making much obvious difference. "

So the market price mechanism rules and we government can't do much?

Neoliberal.

Peter K. -> Peter K.... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 01:41 PM
No queue PGL to tell us that Krugman was saying something that he obviously wasn't.

What is Hillary going to try to do about inequality and distributional issues?

Family leave? Raise taxes on the rich?

Anything else besides minor tweaks and tax incentives?

A public option for health care?

Peter K. -> Peter K.... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 01:44 PM
"So here's my question: Is the modesty of the Clinton economic agenda too much of a good thing? Should accelerating U.S. economic growth be a bigger priority?"

Her agenda is unambitious. It is "center-left" as Krugman puts it which is partly why her poll numbers are in the dumps.

" It's very much a center-left vision: incremental but fairly large increases in high-income tax rates, further tightening of financial regulation, further strengthening of the social safety net."

Point me to a blog post where Krugman spells out exactly where he explains how Clinton proposes to do things.

He doesn't.

Far East Famine017 said in reply to Peter K.... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 01:46 PM

Raise taxes on the rich?

Anything else besides minor tweaks and tax
"

President Trump has proposed a $25000 standard deduction for each of us, but $50,000 for married couples who prove that they have consummated. Hey! IRS Agents like to watch.

Peter K. -> Far East Famine017... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 01:54 PM
How does one prove consummation? Video? Pelvic exams? Bedsheets?
Far East Famine017 said in reply to Peter K.... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 06:24 PM

Tell them what you are about to tell them!

Tell them!

Tell them what you have told them!

But first you have to get their attention. Sorry about the consummation voyeur rib, but getting folks to listen is one of the primary concerns here.

An attention

getting
device --

anne -> Far East Famine017... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 02:54 PM
Crazy gibberish encourages more of the same and is destructive. The name alone is destructive. The content is mean nonsense. Enough.
Far East Famine017 said in reply to anne... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 06:16 PM

a $25000 standard deduction
"

Can you see how this minimum federal standard-deduction is de-fang-ed by lower state-standard-deduction? Tell me something!

When state minimum wage is $5 / hour but federal minimum wage is $9 / hour, does employer hiring in same state have to pay $5 or $9? Do you see how that works?

State's rights are dissolved by the federal statute.

This dissolution of state's rights means that Congress could as easily pass a law to establish minimum standard-deduction for all state's income tax collection. Tell me something else!

Would such a minimum standard deduction on all state income tax collection cause any unemployment? Would it bankrupt any small businesses?

Of course not! By contrast, the federal minimum wage regulation does cause unemployment, does close down some employers of entry level workers, a danger to employment and poverty.

Economics is all about opportunity costs. The opportunity cost of federal minimum wage is the possibility of federal minimum standard deduction, a more harmless subsidy.

Get
it --

anne -> Far East Famine017... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 06:25 PM
State's rights are dissolved by the federal statute.

This dissolution of state's rights means that Congress could as easily pass a law to establish minimum standard-deduction for all state's income tax collection. Tell me something else!

Would such a minimum standard deduction on all state income tax collection cause any unemployment? Would it bankrupt any small businesses?

Of course not! By contrast, the federal minimum wage regulation does cause unemployment, does close down some employers of entry level workers, a danger to employment and poverty.

[ Ah, understood. A clever and important argument that I am thinking through. Like the rational for the federal Earned Income Tax Credit. ]

I am grateful. ]

anne -> Far East Famine017... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 06:27 PM
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Earned_income_tax_credit

The United States federal earned income tax credit or earned income credit (EITC) is a refundable tax credit for low- to moderate-income working individuals and couples, particularly those with children. The amount of EITC benefit depends on a recipient's income and number of children. For a person or couple to claim one or more persons as their qualifying child, requirements such as relationship, age, and shared residency must be met. In the 2013 tax year, working families, if they have children, with annual incomes below $37,870 to $51,567 (depending on the number of dependent children) may be eligible for the federal EITC. Childless workers who have incomes below about $14,340 ($19,680 for a married couple) can receive a very small EITC benefit.

Ben Groves -> Peter K.... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 02:26 PM
Growth is a fixed investment. The investments have been made. Especially older societies, consumption and leisure become more important the nature of purchases change.

I see Space Exploration as the only thing that will change that narrative. That would probably create another computer revolution, industrial revolution kind of change. People just aren't into it thought. People are happy with the dopamine economy and just want to get high.

Peter K. : , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 01:52 PM
Krugman:

"Second, less relevant to Sims but very relevant to other helicopter people, a deficit ultimately financed by inflation is just as much of a burden on households as one ultimately financed by ordinary taxes, because inflation is a kind of tax on money holders. From a Ricardian point of view, there's no difference.

So I'm trying to figure out exactly what Sims is saying. What, ahem, is his model?"

Inflation hits people with savings who don't have debt.

Inflation helps people with debt by eating away at the principle. Inflation signals tight job markets with growing incomes as well. That's why you have price pressures. That's why low inflation and loose job markets can be just as bad as deflation.

Who taxes hit depends on how the government has set up its tax system. Some people and corporations like Apple, Mitt Romney and presumably Trump pay little in taxes.

Krugman the neoliberal.

Ben Groves : , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 02:21 PM
Capitalism was invented by Sephardic Jews who immigrated to Iberia in the 15th and 16th century. They eventually invented market based economy.

By 1600's they had a swirling business sector located in Amsterdam and William the Orange spread it into England during the latter 17th century, creating the Bank of England in 1694 and became the worlds central bank via commodity money.

There is nothing to see here people. It is ponzi scheme and nothing more. Capitalism has only made it because of liberalism. You have to be open to market expansion and have the resources to make it work. It is why "konservatism" is a farce. One, the konservatives were the ones that pushed the decaying "feudal" aristocracy to merge with the merchant caste in the first place and create the bourgeois, despite the aristocracy being the birth place of most of the technology we have now. This morphed into what we call capitalism. Basically the Jews are the Parasites(Finance), "Whites"(the capitalists, which has a abnormal % of homosexuals) the Host and the non-whites the cattle(mass famines and genocide during the 19th and 20th century are what really powered the manpower behind anti-capitalism. Aka the British Empire led to 150 million deaths globally. All global fraternities and organizations like the Skull in Bones to the Council of Foreign relations are a conservative institutions. Yet, those cons won't admit it. As Butler said about his Pacific "campaigns" is is all about spreading capitalism. It is indeed a racket.

These same forces are what created "Protestantism" and "Mormanism", which were a global financed movement. First led by Catholic turncoat Martin Luther, who was financed by the Jews, then run by Jewish John Cohen(Calvin) who spread the judeo-christian revolution globally. This also led to the farce of "sovereignty" nonsense Mormons have tried to use in the last 40 years to push a plutocracy. Then the other bible thumpers caught on. Destroy the nation, bring on the market totalitarianism. Dumb sheep.

anne -> Ben Groves... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 02:41 PM
Do you understand that this writing is crazily, horridly, violently prejudiced, madly anti-Semitic? Do you understand just how clinically mad this is?

This writing reflects a need for professional help. Such help is available and should immediately be sought.

This prejudice reflects a dangerous illness. Do seek assistance.

Do not write like this ever again.

cm -> anne... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 10:48 PM
This is what we have long been used to from Mr. Groves. Ramblings in this style pretty much comment on their own merit and don't need to be graced with rebuttals, as that implies an acknowledgement that at some level a sort of identifiable argument was made.
BenIsNotYoda : , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 03:49 PM
Harvard Study pooh poohs the recovery:

https://www.scribd.com/document/324137454/Harvard-Study-on-US-Economy-Under-Obama#from_embed

Choice excerpts:

"America's economic performance peaked in the late 1990s, and erosion in crucial economic indicators such as the rate of economic growth, productivity growth, job growth, and investment began well before the Great Recession.

Workforce participation, the proportion of Americans in the productive workforce, peaked in 1997. With fewer working-age men and women in the workforce, per-capita income for the U.S. is reduced.

Median real household income has declined since 1999, with incomes stagnating across virtually all income levels. Despite a welcome jump in 2015, median household income remains below the peak attained in 1999, 17 years ago. Moreover, stagnating income and limited job prospects have disproportionately affected lower-income and lower-skilled Americans, leading inequality to rise."

and something I have been going hoarse saying:

"The U.S. lacks an economic strategy, especially at the federal level. The implicit strategy has been to trust the Federal Reserve to solve our problems through monetary policy."

the charts alone are worth the effort to check out this excellent study.

Paine : , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 06:09 PM
I really like this


" Neither the traditional economist's focus on firms in markets nor the Marxist political economist's focus on exploitation of wage labour by capital is a viable way of understanding the real economy, and the book takes some steps towards an alternative view. "


It is the quintessence of heterodox ambitions

Publius : , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 07:58 PM
Why did East Asia become Star Trek instead of the US? Why didn't the hopeful visions of mid-1960's America become reality for the Americans? Read Ha Joon Chang if you want to know why East Asia is on track to be as rich as the US/USSR portrayed in 2001 Space Odyssey. Western provincialism, or perhaps the corruption of economists by looting banks (as documented by Charles Ferguson) has led Western economists to offer really, really terrible advice to their own governments: free trade forever, don't worry about massive deindustrialization, there will be new jobs, there's no chance the US ends up like Mali.
kaleberg : , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 08:45 PM
One of the big problems of economics is how little of our society it explains. Exactly how many people of either sex actually sit down and decide to have children based on a return on investment calculation? How many people spend time with their friends and families based on some kind of maximization function? When you visit a dying friend or family member at the hospital is this the result of some gift exchange calculus? What about the time one spends listening to music, watching a baseball game or browsing Facebook?

It might help to start with anthropology and think about human societies and their organization. Start with something like the Lynds' Middletown books to get away from the implicit exoticism that the term anthropology invokes. Societies have certain basic functions: raising children, caring for those who cannot care for themselves, earning a living, spending free time, recognizing one's place in the universe, participating in civil society and so on. Economics only looks at a tiny piece of this, just part of the earning a living section. It's as if chemists never studied anything except hydrogen molecules.

Economics really does need some new thinking. Starting with Pareto optimality is simply the argument that we live in the best of all possible worlds. It is so transparently bogus that it is hard to believe that anyone ever took it seriously. Oil lamps were hard on torch makers and the automobile destroyed the buggy whip business. We need an economic system to regulate the production and allocation of goods and services, but we also need child custody laws and burial customs.

I'm a capitalist at heart, but I view capitalism as I view fire. There is nothing quite like fire for cooking food, lighting the dark, scaring wild animals, firing pottery and so on, but fire also needs to be carefully controlled, constantly monitored and subject to societal sanction.

cm -> kaleberg ... , Thursday, September 15, 2016 at 11:02 PM
Economics fashions itself (or is being fashioned) as a science, and as such has to restrict itself to measurable, identifiable, and (in principle) predictable phenomena.

What you are describing is more in the realm of philosophy, psychology, and moral judgement.

The problem starts when the economics profession and related occupations (business media, etc.) pretend to have identified "market mechanisms" as the unifying theory of society and world, including "explaining" social dynamics in terms of "objective/rational" market transactions and motivations.

But the desire for grand unified theories and "whole truths" is ever strong, lending credence and support to such efforts.

reason : , -1
Now is the time to push for my leisure theory of value. All goods and services traded in the economy are intermediate goods, and value is actually created during leisure time!

[Sep 12, 2016] The Strong Case Against Central Bank Independence Critically Examined

Notable quotes:
"... The deficit obsession that governments have shown since 2010 has helped produce a recovery that has been far too slow, even in the US. ..."
"... The Zero Lower Bound (ZLB) raises an acute problem for what I call the consensus assignment (leaving macroeconomic stabilisation to an independent, inflation targeting central bank), but add in austerity and you get major macroeconomic costs. ICBs appear to rule out the one policy (money financed fiscal expansion) that could combat both the ZLB and deficit obsession. ..."
Mar 8, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com
Simon Wren-Lewis has a follow-up to his recent post on central bank independence:
The 'strong case' critically examined : Perhaps it was too unconventional setting out an argument (against independent central banks, ICBs) that I did not agree with, even though I made it abundantly clear that was what I was doing. It was too much for one blogger, who reacted by deciding that I did agree with the argument, and sent a series of tweets that are best forgotten. But my reason for doing it was also clear enough from the final paragraph. The problem it addresses is real enough, and the problem appears to be linked to the creation of ICBs.

The deficit obsession that governments have shown since 2010 has helped produce a recovery that has been far too slow, even in the US. It would be nice if we could treat that obsession as some kind of aberration, never to be repeated, but unfortunately that looks way too optimistic.

The Zero Lower Bound (ZLB) raises an acute problem for what I call the consensus assignment (leaving macroeconomic stabilisation to an independent, inflation targeting central bank), but add in austerity and you get major macroeconomic costs. ICBs appear to rule out the one policy (money financed fiscal expansion) that could combat both the ZLB and deficit obsession.

I wanted to put that point as strongly as I could. Miles Kimball does something similar here , although without the fiscal policy perspective ...

Skipping ahead (and omitting quite a bit of the argument):

... The basic flaw with my strong argument against ICBs is that the ultimate problem (in terms of not ending recessions quickly) lies with governments. There would be no problem if governments could only wait until the recession was over (and interest rates were safely above the ZLB) before tackling their deficit, but the recession was not over in 2010. Given this failure by governments, it seems odd to then suggest that the solution to this problem is to give governments back some of the power they have lost. Or to put the same point another way, imagine the Republican Congress in charge of US monetary policy.

But if abolishing ICBs is not the answer to the very real problem I set out, does that mean we have to be satisfied with the workarounds? One possibility that a few economists like Miles Kimball have argued for is to effectively abolish paper money as we know it, so central banks can set negative interest rates. Another possibility is that the government (in its saner moments) gives ICBs the power to undertake helicopter money.

Both are complete solutions to the ZLB problem rather than workarounds. Both can be accused of endangering the value of money. But note also that both proposals gain strength from the existence of ICBs: governments are highly unlikely to ever have the courage to set negative rates, and ICBs stop the flight times of helicopters being linked to elections.

These are big (important and complex) issues. There should be no taboos that mean certain issues cannot be raised in polite company. I still think blog posts are the best medium we have to discuss these issues, hopefully free from distractions like partisan politics.

Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, March 8, 2016 at 12:24 AM in Economics , Fiscal Policy , Monetary Policy , Politics | Permalink Comments (28)

[Sep 12, 2016] Neoliberal pseudo theories vs tobin

Notable quotes:
"... We don't get to do many controlled experiments in economics, so history is mainly what we have to go on. ..."
"... What did orthodox salt-water macroeconomists believe about disinflation on the eve of the Paul Volcker contraction? As it happens, we have an excellent source document: James Tobin's "Stabilization Policy Ten Years After," * presented at Brookings in early 1980. ..."
"... Unemployment shot up faster than in Tobin's simulation, then came down faster, because the Fed didn't follow the simple rule he assumed. But the basic shape - a clockwise spiral, with inflation coming down thanks to a period of very high unemployment - was very much in line with what standard Keynesian macro said would happen. ..."
"... trade between any two regional economies is roughly proportional to the product of their GDPs and inversely related to distance. Neat. ..."
Sep 02, 2015 | economistsview.typepad.com

anne said...

http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2015/09/01/the-triumph-of-backward-looking-economics/

September 1, 2015

The Triumph of Backward-Looking Economics

By Paul Krugman

We don't get to do many controlled experiments in economics, so history is mainly what we have to go on. Unfortunately, many people who imagine that they know how the economy works go with what they think they heard about history, not with what actually happened. And I'm not just talking about the great unwashed; quite a few well-known economists seem not to have heard about FRED, or at least haven't picked up the habit of doing a quick scan of the actual data before making assertions about facts.

And there's one decade in particular where people are weirdly unaware of the realities: the 1980s. A lot of this has to do with Reaganolatry: the usual suspects have repeated so often that it was a time of extraordinary, incredible success that I often encounter liberals who believe that something special must have happened, that somehow the events were at odds with what the prevailing macroeconomic models of the time said would happen.

But nothing special happened, aside from the unexpected willingness of the Federal Reserve to impose incredibly high unemployment in order to bring inflation down.

What did orthodox salt-water macroeconomists believe about disinflation on the eve of the Paul Volcker contraction? As it happens, we have an excellent source document: James Tobin's "Stabilization Policy Ten Years After," * presented at Brookings in early 1980. Among other things, Tobin laid out a hypothetical disinflation scenario based on the kind of Keynesian model people like him were using at the time (which was also the model laid out in the Dornbusch-Fischer and Robert Gordon textbooks).

These models included an expectations-augmented Phillips curve, ** with no long-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment - but expectations were assumed to adjust gradually based on experience, rather than changing rapidly via forward-looking assessments of Fed policy.

This was, of course, the kind of model the Chicago School dismissed scathingly as worthy of nothing but ridicule, and which was more or less driven out of the academic literature, even as it continued to be the basis of a lot of policy analysis.

So here was Tobin's picture:

[Picture]

Here's what actually happened:

[Graph]

Unemployment shot up faster than in Tobin's simulation, then came down faster, because the Fed didn't follow the simple rule he assumed. But the basic shape - a clockwise spiral, with inflation coming down thanks to a period of very high unemployment - was very much in line with what standard Keynesian macro said would happen. On the other hand, there was no sign whatsoever of the kind of painless disinflation rational-expectations models suggested would happen if the Fed credibly announced its disinflation plans.

anne said...

http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2015/09/01/gravity/

September 1, 2015

Gravity
By Paul Krugman

Now that's fun: Adam Davidson tells us * about trade in the ancient Near East, as documented by archives found in Kanesh - and reports that the volume of trade between Kanesh and various trading partners seems to fit a gravity equation: trade between any two regional economies is roughly proportional to the product of their GDPs and inversely related to distance. Neat.

But what does the seemingly universal applicability of the gravity equation tell us? Davidson suggests that it's an indication that policy can't do much to shape trade. That's not where I would have gone, and it's not where those who have studied the issue closely ** have gone.

Here's my take: Think about two cities with the same per capita GDP - we can relax that assumption in a minute. They will trade if residents of city A find things being sold by residents of city B that they want, and vice versa.

So what's the probability that an A resident will find a B resident with something he or she wants? Applying what one of my old teachers used to call the principle of insignificant reason, a good first guess would be that this probability is proportional to the number of potential sellers - B's population.

And how many such desirous buyers will there be? Again applying insignificant reason, a good guess is that it's proportional to the number of potential buyers - A's population.

So other things equal we would expect exports from B to A to be proportional to the product of their populations.

What if GDP per capita isn't the same? You can think of this as increasing the "effective" population, both in terms of producers and in terms of consumers. So the attraction is now the product of the GDPs.

Is there anything surprising about the fact that this relationship works pretty well? A bit. Standard pre-1980 trade theory envisaged countries specializing in accord with their comparative advantage - England does cloth, Portugal wine. And these models suggest that how much countries trade should have a lot to do with whether they are similar or not. Cloth exporters shouldn't be selling much to each other, but should instead do their trading with wine exporters. In reality, however, there's basically no sign of any such effect: even seemingly similar countries trade about as much as a gravity equation says they should.

Calibrated models of trade have long dealt with this reality, somewhat awkwardly, with the so-called Armington assumption, *** which simply assumes that even the apparently same good from different countries is treated by consumers as a differentiated product - a banana isn't just a banana, it's an Ecuador banana or a Saint Lucia banana, which are imperfect substitutes. The new trade theory some of us introduced circa 1980 - or as some now call it, the "old new trade theory" - does a bit more, and possibly better, by introducing monopolistic competition and increasing returns to explain why even similar countries produce differentiated products.

And there's also a puzzle about both the effect of distance and the effect of borders, both of which seem larger than concrete costs can explain. Work continues.

Does any of this suggest the irrelevance of trade policy? Not really. Changes in trade policy do have obvious effects on how much countries trade. Look at what happened when Mexico opened up starting in the late 1980s, as compared with Canada, which was fairly open all along - and which, like Mexico, mainly trades with the US:

[Graph]

So what does gravity tell us? Simple Ricardian comparative advantage is clearly incomplete; the process of international trade is subtler, with invisible as well as visible costs. Not trivial, but not too unsettling. And gravity models are very useful as a benchmark for assessing other effects.

* http://www.nytimes.com/2015/08/30/magazine/the-vcs-of-bc.html

** https://www2.bc.edu/~anderson/GravitySlides.pdf

*** http://wits.worldbank.org/wits/wits/witshelp/Content/SMART/Demand%20side%20the%20Armington.htm

anne -> anne...

http://www.nytimes.com/2015/08/30/magazine/the-vcs-of-bc.html

August 29, 2015

The V.C.s of B.C.
By ADAM DAVIDSON

One morning, just before dawn, an old man named Assur-idi loaded up two black donkeys. Their burden was 147 pounds of tin, along with 30 textiles, known as kutanum, that were of such rare value that a single garment cost as much as a slave. Assur-idi had spent his life's savings on the items, because he knew that if he could convey them over the Taurus Mountains to Kanesh, 600 miles away, he could sell them for twice what he paid.

At the city gate, Assur-idi ran into a younger acquaintance, Sharrum-Adad, who said he was heading on the same journey. He offered to take the older man's donkeys with him and ship the profits back. The two struck a hurried agreement and wrote it up, though they forgot to record some details. Later, Sharrum-­Adad claimed he never knew how many textiles he had been given. Assur-idi spent the subsequent weeks sending increasingly panicked letters to his sons in Kanesh, demanding they track down Sharrum-Adad and claim his profits.

These letters survive as part of a stunning, nearly miraculous window into ancient economics. In general, we know few details about economic life before roughly 1000 A.D. But during one 30-year period - between 1890 and 1860 B.C. - for one community in the town of Kanesh, we know a great deal. Through a series of incredibly unlikely events, archaeologists have uncovered the comprehensive written archive of a few hundred traders who left their hometown Assur, in what is now Iraq, to set up importing businesses in Kanesh, which sat roughly at the center of present-day Turkey and functioned as the hub of a massive global trading system that stretched from Central Asia to Europe. Kanesh's traders sent letters back and forth with their business partners, carefully written on clay tablets and stored at home in special vaults. Tens of thousands of these records remain. One economist recently told me that he would love to have as much candid information about businesses today as we have about the dealings - and in particular, about the trading practices - of this 4,000-year-old community.

Trade is central to every key economic issue we face. Whether the subject is inequality, financial instability or the future of work, it all comes down to a discussion of trade: trade of manufactured goods with China, trade of bonds with Europe, trade over the Internet or enabled by mobile apps. For decades, economists have sought to understand how trade works. Can we shape trade to achieve different outcomes, like a resurgence of manufacturing or a lessening of inequality? Or does trade operate according to fairly fixed rules, making it resistant to conscious planning?

Economists, creating models of trade, have faced a challenge, because their data have derived exclusively from the modern world. Are their models universal or merely reflections of our time? It's a crucial question, because many in our country would like to change our trading system to protect American jobs and to improve working conditions here and abroad. The archives of Kanesh have proved to be the greatest single source of information about trade from an entirely premodern milieu.

In a beautifully detailed new book - ''Ancient Kanesh,'' written by a scholar of the archive, Mogens Trolle Larsen, to be published by Cambridge University Press later this year - we meet dozens of the traders of Kanesh and their relatives back home in Assur. Larsen has been able to construct family trees, detailing how siblings and cousins, parents and spouses, traded with one another and often worked against one another. We meet struggling businessmen, like Assur-idi, and brilliant entrepreneurs, like Shalim-Assur, who built a wealthy dynasty that lasted generations. In 2003, while covering the war in Iraq, I traveled to many ancient archaeological sites; the huge burial mounds, the carvings celebrating kings as relatives to the gods, all gave the impression of a despotic land in which a tiny handful of aristocrats and priests enjoyed dictatorial control. But the Kanesh documents show that at least some citizens had enormous power over their own livelihoods, achieving wealth and power through their own entrepreneurial endeavors.

The details of daily life are amazing, but another scholar, Gojko Barjamovic, of Harvard, realized that the archive also offered insight into something potentially more compelling. Many of the texts enumerate specific business details: the price of goods purchased and sold, the interest ate on debt, the costs of transporting goods and the various taxes in the many city-states that the donkey caravans passed on the long journey from Assur to Kanesh. Like most people who have studied Kanesh, Barjamovic is an Assyriologist, an expert in ancient languages and culture. Earlier this year, he joined some economists, as well as some other Assyriologists and archaeologists, on a team that analyzed Kanesh's financial statistics. The picture that emerged of economic life is staggeringly advanced. The traders of Kanesh used financial tools that were remarkably similar to checks, bonds and joint-stock companies. They had something like venture-capital firms that created diversified portfolios of risky trades. And they even had structured financial products: People would buy outstanding debt, sell it to others and use it as collateral to finance new businesses. The 30 years for which we have records appear to have been a time of remarkable financial innovation....

anne said...

http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2015/09/01/multipliers-what-we-should-have-known/

September 1, 2015

Multipliers: What We Should Have Known
By Paul Krugman

There's a very nice interview * with Olivier Blanchard, who is leaving the International Monetary Fund, in which among other things Olivier says the right thing about changing one's mind:

"With respect to outside, the issue I have been struck by is how to indicate a change of views without triggering headlines of 'mistakes,' 'Fund incompetence,' and so on. Here, I am thinking of fiscal multipliers. The underestimation of the drag on output from fiscal consolidation was not a 'mistake' in the way people think of mistakes, e.g. mixing up two cells in an excel sheet. It was based on a substantial amount of prior evidence, but evidence which turned out to be misleading in an environment where interest rates are close to zero and monetary policy cannot offset the negative effects of budget cuts. We got a lot of flak for admitting the underestimation, and I suspect we shall continue to get more flak in the future. But, at the same time, I believe that we, the Fund, substantially increased our credibility, and used better assumptions later on. It was painful, but it was useful."

Indeed. There are a lot of people out there whose idea of a substantive argument is "you used to say X, now you say Y" - never mind the reasons why you changed your view, and whether it was right to do so.It's important not to fall into the trap of being afraid to let new evidence or analysis speak.

One thing I would say, however, is that on this particular issue the Fund should have known better. Olivier says that the evidence "turned out to be misleading in an environment where interest rates are close to zero and monetary policy cannot offset the negative effects of budget cuts", but didn't we know that? I certainly did. **

And let me also beat one of my favorite drums: the prediction that multipliers would be much larger in a liquidity trap came out of IS-LMish macro (or, to be fair, New Keynesian models) and has been overwhelmingly confirmed by experience. So this was yet another victory for Keynesian analysis, the success story nobody will believe.

* http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/survey/so/2015/RES083115A.htm

** http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/11/10/depression-multipliers/

anne -> anne...

http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/11/10/depression-multipliers/

November 10, 2009

Depression Multipliers
By Paul Krugman

Barry Eichengreen and Kevin O'Rourke have lately been scoring a series of research coups, based on the combination of historical perspective and a global view. Most famously, they showed that on a global basis the first year of the current crisis was every bit as severe * as the first year of the Great Depression.

Now they and collaborators have a new piece on policy effects, ** especially fiscal multipliers.

The background here is that there are two problems with estimating multipliers relevant to our current situation. First, you need to look at what happens under liquidity-trap conditions - and except in Japan,these haven't prevailed anywhere since the 1930s. The second is that in the United States, fiscal policy was never forceful enough to provide a useful natural experiment. We didn't have a really big fiscal expansion until World War II; and WWII isn't a good experiment because the surge in defense spending was accompanied by government policies that suppressed private demand, such as rationing and restrictions on investment. (I really, really don't understand why this point has been so hard to get across.)

What E&R do here is use a broad international cross-section to overcome this problem. This works because a number of countries had major military buildups during the 1930s - fiscal expansions that can be regarded as exogenous to the economic situation, since they were

"driven above all by Hitler's rearmament programmes and other nations' efforts to match the Nazis in this sphere, and by one-off events like Italy's war in Abyssinia."

What do E&R find? Initial fiscal multipliers of 2 or more, although they shrink over time. Yes, fiscal expansion is expansionary.

* http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3421

** http://www.econ.berkeley.edu/~eichengr/great_dep_great_cred_11-09.pdf

So how does the decade of the 1980s end up being perceived as a defeat for Keynesians? To see it that way you have to systematically misrepresent both what happened to the economy and what people like Tobin were saying at the time. In reality, Tobinesque economics looks very good in the light of events.

* http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/Projects/BPEA/1980-1/1980a_bpea_tobin.PDF

** http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Phillips_curve

In economics, the Phillips curve is a historical inverse relationship between rates of unemployment and corresponding rates of inflation that result in an economy. Stated simply, decreased unemployment, (i.e. increased levels of employment) in an economy will correlate with higher rates of inflation.

[Aug 14, 2016] How the Fed Promoted Financial Dominance and Shadow Banking by Promoting Repo

Notable quotes:
"... By Daniela Gabor is associate professor in economics at the University of the West of England, Bristol. Originally published at the Institute for New Economic Thinking website ..."
"... For a detailed account see Gabor, D. (2016) The (impossible) repo trinity : the political economy of repo markets, Review of International Political Economy, doi 10.1080/09692290.2016.1207699 ..."
www.nakedcapitalism.com

... ... ...

By Daniela Gabor is associate professor in economics at the University of the West of England, Bristol. Originally published at the Institute for New Economic Thinking website

Since the 1980s, central banks have been increasingly freed from fiscal dominance , the obligation to monetize government debt. The new regime of monetary dominance celebrated the (price) stability benefits of insulating scientific monetary policy from poorly theorized, highly politicized fiscal policy. Yet the growing dominance of the 'monetary science, fiscal alchemy' view in both academia and policy circles played a critical role in the rapid rise of shadow banking. The untold story of shadow banking is the story of (failed) attempts to separate monetary from fiscal policy, and of the bordeland that connects them, mapped onto the repo market .

While the state withdrew from economic life, privatizing state-owned enterprises or state banks, and putting macroeconomic governance in the hands of independent central banks, its role in financial life grew bigger. Sovereign debt evolved into the cornerstone of modern financial systems, used as benchmark for pricing private assets, for hedging and as base asset for credit creation via shadow banking . The state's role as debt issuer, passive and systemic at once, has been reliant, beyond the arithmetic of budget deficits, on the intricate workings of the repo trinity.

The repo trinity captures a consensus in central bank circles emerging after the 1998 Russian crisis, the first systemic crisis of collateral-intensive finance, that financial stability requires liquid government bond markets and liberalized repo markets (fig. 1).

Figure 1 The repo trinity

gabbor-f1

The repo-government bond market nexus took shape in the 1980s. In the US, securities dealers preferred repos to secured lending against collateral because market convention treated repos as outright sales and repurchases of collateral that allowed dealers to re-use collateral for a wide range of activities (short-selling, hedging, selling to a third party). When bankruptcy courts decided that repos would be subjected to automatic stay rules, Paul Volcker, then the Federal Reserve chairperson, successfully lobbied Congress to exempt repos with US Treasuries (UST) and agency securities collateral. Then, Salomon Brothers short-squeezed the UST market in 1991 by becoming the only repo supplier of a two-year note. This allowed Salomon to fund securities through repo transactions at exceptionally low rates. The ensuing public enquiry into the Salomon scandal showed little appetite for regulating repos. Rather, the Fed and the Treasury introduced new practices to fix gaps in repo plumbing, celebrating repos as innovative, liquidity enhancing instruments that would support the state in the post fiscal-dominance era.

The UST blueprint diffused rapidly to Europe. Pressured to adjust to a world of independent central banks, market-based financing and global competition for liquidity, European states embarked on a project of creating modern government bond markets, with modernity understood to mean the structural features of the US government bond market: regular auctions, market-making based on primary dealers and a liberalised repo market.

Central banks were at first divided on the benefits of opening up repo markets. While Banque de France followed the US Fed in assuming a catalyst role for the repo-sovereign bond market nexus, Bundesbank and Bank of England worried that deregulated repo markets would unleash structural changes in finance that could undermine the conduct of monetary policy and financial stability. In the architecture of the US government bond market, the Bundesbank saw the conditions nurturing short-term , fragile finance. Seeking to keep banks captive on the uncollateralized segment of interbank markets, Bundesbank imposed reserve requirements on repo liabilities. In parallel, as government's fiscal agent, Bundesbank followed a conservative strategy, with irregular auctions, issuance concentrated at long maturities and repo rules that increased the costs of funding bunds via repos. German banks responded by moving (bund) repo activities to London and warned that France's open repo strategy would make it into the benchmark sovereign issuer for the Euroarea. For similar reasons, the Bank of England exercised strict control over the repo gilt market for 10 years after the 1986 Big Bang liberalisation of financial markets. Under intense pressure from the financial industry and Ministries of Finance, the two central banks liberalized repo markets by 1997.

As the fragilities of the new, collateral-intensive world became apparent in the 1998 Russian crisis, central banks working together in the Committee on the Global Financial System subscribed to the policy goals of the repo trinity. The CGFS argued that financial stability in market-based finance required global safe assets, issued in government bond markets, in turn 'lubricated' by free repo markets with carefully designed (but not regulated) risk management regimes.

In pursuing the objectives of the repo trinity, central banks helped consolidate the critical role that sovereign bonds play in modern financial markets. Throughout the 2000s, the shortage of US government bonds saw the trinity extended to include securitization markets, while the Euro project galvanized consensus for a European repo trinity, whereby central banks encouraged the European banks dominating the repo market to treat all Euro sovereign debt as high-quality collateral .

After Lehman, central banks and the Financial Stability Board recognized the impossible nature of the repo trinity, attributing cyclical leverage, fire sales and elusive liquidity in collateral markets, including government bond markets, to free repo markets. Central banks, with the Bank of England leading the way, now accept that financial stability means supporting liquidity in collateral markets in times of stress rather than supporting banking institutions as in the traditional lender of last resort (LOLR) model. Paradoxically, LOLR support, implemented through repo loans, can destabilize (shadow) banks where central banks' collateral framework follows collateral market valuations (figure 2).

Figure 2 The impossible repo trinity

gabbor-f2

The quiet revolution in crisis central banking that involves direct support for core markets may appear like, but does not entail a return to, fiscal dominance. Rather, it creates financial dominance , defined as asymmetric support for falling asset prices. While financial dominance should be addressed by direct regulatory interventions, the quest for biting repo rules has so far proved illusive. The precise impact of Basel III liquidity and leverage rules is yet to be determined, whereas the failed attempts to include repos in the European Financial Transactions Tax and the FSB's watered-down repo proposals suggest that (countercyclical) collateral rules are only possible once states design alternative models of organizing their sovereign debt markets. Paradoxically, new initiatives in Europe suggest that a return to the repo trinity is rather more likely: the Capital Market Union plans to create Simple, Transparent and Standardized ( STS ) securitisation again illustrate the catalyst role that central banks choose to play in market-driven solutions to safe asset shortages.

For a detailed account see Gabor, D. (2016) The (impossible) repo trinity : the political economy of repo markets, Review of International Political Economy, doi 10.1080/09692290.2016.1207699

ArkansasAngie , August 13, 2016 at 7:49 am

Intrinsically, that is authoritative … fascism,

Can't trust politicians or voters to make the right choices.

That's not a slippery slope … it's a dad gum cliff

Take decision making away from politicians and their constituents and place it in the hands of unelected yahoos.

That's a bridge to far …IMHO

Where have we seen these seeds? Why the European Union.

A troika coming to your town?

hemeantwell , August 13, 2016 at 7:59 am

Uhhh. The article is one of the rare "too short, wish it was longer" breed.

I'll hazard a remark: how can securitization be "transparent" if, as one of the articles yesterday discussed, central banks intervene to support banks so as to allow them to avoid having the market deliver a price verdict on asset value?

beene , August 13, 2016 at 8:57 am

Any time you let central banks like the Federal Bank of NY create money from debt; bankruptcy is on the horizon. This has only been proven true for around five thousand years.

For a recent example have a look at the difference in government debt in Canada now verses when it had a public banking system.

financial matters , August 13, 2016 at 8:37 am

I think this is an important point:

"Throughout the 2000s, the shortage of US government bonds saw the trinity extended to include securitization markets,"

This started treating asset based securities similar to US Treasuries

Also this:

"fire sales and elusive liquidity in collateral markets, including government bond markets,"

I don't think the European government bond market can be treated as sovereign government bonds as they don't have that guarantee of backing from a central bank.

----

Quite simply, US Treasuries can be put to much better use than supporting asset prices and other financial products.

The first target should be unemployment.

Jesper , August 13, 2016 at 12:53 pm

Repos hide risk and makes it possible to increase leverage. Why would anyone but financial institutions want that?
But since financial institutions rule all then I suppose that repos will continue and as a gesture of goodwill (dressed up as something else) they'll just become more and more complex – those (high) fees for the professionals enabling the practice has to be justified somehow…

sunny129 , August 13, 2016 at 5:21 pm

More complex invites, less transparency, more instability and volatility!

Until RESET or forced of gravity of reversion to the mean, over power the CBers, this charade will go on!

nothing but the truth , August 13, 2016 at 5:01 pm

the forced identity between credit and currency is the root of a lot problems.

it should not be the taxpayer funded mandate of the the govt to enforce this identity.

[Jul 20, 2016] Bill Black: Mankiws Mythical Ten Commandments of Theoclassical Economics

Notable quotes:
"... Democrats: Please Renounce Mankiw's Myths ..."
"... Mankiw is a propagandist. ..."
"... The values and ideology represented in the Economics textbook Bill Black analyzed didn't arise in a vacuum. The points Black lists reflect the ideology, values, ethics and interests of a narrow segment of our society who have accumulated enormous personal wealth through a variety of extra-legal and illegal mechanisms, and who use a small portion of that wealth to fund "Economics Chairs" in our public and private universities; economics "think tanks"; and speeches, books, consulting engagements, and board memberships for "prominent economists". ..."
"... Mankiw is a shill/useful idiot for his oligarchs patrons. #11 explains the idiocy of the previous 10. ..."
"... Did the banks which loaned billions to the gas frackers of North Dakota know that production would exceed demand and cause a crash? Perhaps the loan officer might have such concern, but would more likely be most concerned with his/her own bottom line – a meme Yves explores in Econned. ..."
"... Newly-printed money CAN cause inflation, but WHERE the price rises happen depends greatly on the pockets in which the money lands. ..."
"... stocks, real estate, luxury goods, premium educations, etc. ..."
"... This kind of ignorant cluelessness is pretty prevalent among the oligarchy and its supporters like Mankiw. Just like that guy in Davos who simply couldn't understand why there's so much social unrest in the world today. They live in a completely different world. ..."
"... My first exposure to Mankiw's principles was actually an early version of the talk by Yoram Bauman in this video. It hits several of the points Mr. Black makes and is also pretty funny. It definitely demonstrates how Mankiw attempts to cloak his biases in supposedly neutral terms. ..."
"... I doubt Mankiw will accept 100% estate tax on the justification that the cost of bequests is zero to the recipient. (and thus a 100% estate tax doesn't incur large costs on the recipient) ..."
"... My paper lists four principles claimed to be at the core of modern economics by Mankiw and then shows how all four principles are false: Amir-ud-Din, Rafi and Zaman, Asad, Failures of the 'Invisible Hand' (July 15, 2013). Forum for Social Economics, Vol. 45, Iss. 1, 2016. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2293940 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2293940 ..."
May 17, 2016 | nakedcapitalism.com

By Bill Black, the author of The Best Way to Rob a Bank is to Own One and an associate professor of economics and law at the University of Missouri-Kansas City. Jointly published with New Economic Perspectives

This is the second column in a series on the N. Gregory Mankiw's myths and dogmas that he spreads in his economic textbooks. The first column exposed the two (contradictory) meta-myths that begin his preface. This column de-mythologizes Mankiw's unprincipled " principles " of economics – the ten commandments of theoclassical economics' priestly caste. Some of these principles, correctly hedged, could be unobjectionable, but in each case Mankiw dogmatically insists on pushing them to such extremes that they become Mankiw myths.

To understand Mankiw's mythical 10 commandments, one must understand "Mankiw morality" – a morality that remains hidden in each of his textbooks. Few people understand how radically theoclassical economics has moved in the last thirty years. Milton Friedman famously argued that CEOs should operate exclusively in the interest of shareholders. Mankiw, however, is a strong supporter of the view that CEOs will not only defraud customers, but also shareholders and creditors by looting the firm. "[I]t would be irrational for savings and loans [CEOs] not to loot." "Mankiw morality" decrees that if you have an incentive as CEO to loot, and fail to do so, you are not moral – you are insane. Mankiw morality was born in Mankiw's response as discussant to George Akerlof and Paul Romer's famous 1993 article "Looting: The Economic Underworld of Bankruptcy for Profit."

Mankiw's textbooks preach the wonders of the indefensible a system he has helped design to allow elite CEOs to loot the shareholders with impunity – the antithesis of Friedman's stated goal. Mankiw morality helps create the "criminogenic environments" that produce the epidemics of "control fraud" that drive our recurrent, intensifying financial crises. It is essential to interpret Mankiw's ten myths in light of his unacknowledged immoral views about how CEOs will and should respond to incentives to rig the system against the firm's consumers, employees, creditors, and shareholders. His textbooks religiously avoid any disclosure of Mankiw morality or its implications for perverting his ten commandments into an unethical and criminogenic dogma that optimizes the design of a criminogenic environment.

Mankiw's myths

  1. People Face Tradeoffs. To get one thing, you have to give up something else. Making decisions requires trading off one goal against another.

    This can be true, but Mankiw pushes his principle to the point that it becomes a myth. Life is filled with positive synergies and externalities. If you study logic or white-collar criminology you will make yourself a far better economist. You may trade off hours of study, but not "goals." If your "goal" is to become a great economist you will not be "trading off one goal against another" if you become a multidisciplinary scholar – you will strongly advance your goal. If you study diverse research methods you will be a far better economist than if you study only econometrics.

  2. The Cost of Something is What You Give Up to Get It. Decision-makers have to consider both the obvious and implicit costs of their actions.

    "Opportunity costs" are an important and useful economic concept, but Mankiw's definition sneaks ideological baggage into both sentences that turns his principle into multiple myths. Mankiw implicitly assumes fraud and other forms of theft out of existence in the first sentence. "Cost" is often not measured in economics by "what you give up to get it." If your inherit a home that lacks fire insurance and immediately burns down there is a cost to you (and society) even though you gave up nothing to inherit the home. If the CEO loots "his" firm he gave up nothing to get the millions, but if he loses those millions he will consider it to have a "cost." Theoclassical economists have a primitive tribal taboo against even using the "f" word (fraud).

    Decision-makers frequently ignore the "costs of their actions." There is nothing in economic theory or experience that supports the claim that the "decision-makers" "have" to consider costs. It is rare that decision-makers must do – or not do – anything.

    It is likely that Mankiw means that optimization requires decision-makers to "consider" all "costs of their actions," but that too is a myth. Theoclassical optimization requires perfect, cost-free information, pure "rationality," and no externalities. None of these conditions exist. Car buyers have no means of knowing the costs of buying a particular car. If they bought a GM car the ignition mechanism defect could cause the driver to lose the ability to control the car – turning it into an unguided missile hurtling down (or off) a highway at 70 mph. The car buyer does not know of the defect, does not know who will be driving when the defect becomes manifest, does not know who the passengers will be, and does not know who and what else could be injured or damaged as a result of the defect. The theoclassical view is that the buyer who "considers" the costs of buying his defective car to others (negative externalities) and pays more money to buy a car that minimizes those negative externalities is not acting ethically, but irrationally.

    It is typically cheaper (for the producer, not society) to produce goods of inferior (but difficult to observe) quality. The inability of the consumer to "consider" even the true costs to the consumer and the consumer's loved ones of these hidden defects means that economists began warning 46 years ago that "market forces" could become criminogenic. George Akerlof's 1970 article on markets for "lemons" even coined the term "Gresham's" dynamic to describe the process. A Gresham's dynamic is a leading form of a criminogenic environment.

    [D]ishonest dealings tend to drive honest dealings out of the market. The cost of dishonesty, therefore, lies not only in the amount by which the purchaser is cheated; the cost also must include the loss incurred from driving legitimate business out of existence.

    Akerlof was made a Nobel laureate in economics in 2001 for this body of work. Economics is the only field in which someone would write a textbook ignoring a Nobel laureate whose work has proven unusually accurate on such a critical point. There is only one reason to exclude this reality from Mankiw's myths – Akerlof's work falsifies Mankiw's myths, so Akerlof's work disappears from Mankiw's principles, as does the entire concept of fraud.

  3. Rational People Think at the Margin . A rational decision-maker takes action if and only if the marginal benefit of the action exceeds the marginal cost.

    The mythical nature of this principle flows from the multiple errors I have described. Mankiw is being deliberately disingenuous. Theoclassical economics does not claim, for example, that a firm produces a product "only if the marginal benefit of the action exceeds the marginal cost." Theoclassical economists claim that a firm sells a product "only if the marginal benefit of the action to the seller exceeds the marginal cost to the seller." The seller ignores social costs and benefits.

    For the sake of brevity, I will summarize that Mankiw's third principle is a myth for five reasons known to every economist. First, it implicitly assumes out of existence positive and negative externalities, which means that supposedly rational, self-interested decision-makers he postulates, even if they had perfect, cost-free information, would not contract to maximize social welfare.

    Second, as Mankiw morality implicitly admits, the actual optimization principle under theoclassical economics would be determined by the marginal benefits and costs of an action to the decision-maker – the CEO – not the firm, and certainly not society. Theoclassical economists, however, refuse to admit that explicitly, so it disappears from Mankiw's 10 commandments.

    Third, the information provided by CEOs is often not simply incomplete and costly, but deliberately deceptive. Where information is merely incomplete, consumers may pay far more for a product than they will benefit from the purchase. Where the seller provides deceptive information about quality, the buyer and members of the public may be harmed or even killed. The CEO may also be looting "his" firm as well as the customers. Mankiw has implicitly assumed perfect, cost-free information and implicitly assumed that fraud does not exist.

    Fourth, conflating rationality with optimization of personal costs and benefits is wrong on multiple grounds. It defines ethical behavior as "irrational" where the consumer or CEO takes into account social costs and benefits and protects the interests of others in an altruistic manner. Everything we know from behavioral economics also makes clear that humans are not "rational" in the manner predicted by theoclassical economics. Mankiw has implicitly assumed out of existence thirty years of economic research on how people actually behave and make decisions.

    Fifth, firms with monopoly power, according to theoclassical economics, maximize their profits by deliberately reducing production to a point that the social cost of producing the marginal unit is less than the marginal benefit to the consumer. Mankiw has implicitly assumed away monopolies.

  4. People Respond to Incentives. Behavior changes when costs or benefits change.

    I have responded to this myth in a prior article . The implications of his fourth principle in conjunction with Mankiw morality are devastating for theoclassical economics. CEOs create the incentives and understand how "behavior changes" among their agents, employees, and subordinate officers in response to those incentives. Under theoclassical principles this will unambiguously lead "rational" CEOs to set incentives to rig the system in favor of the CEO. Because fraud and abuse creates a "sure thing" that is certain to enrich the CEO, Mankiw's fourth commandment predicts that control frauds led by CEOs will be ubiquitous. Fortunately, many CEOs are ethical and remain ethical unless they are subjected to a severe Gresham's dynamic. As a result, Mankiw's commandments over-predict the incidence of fraud and abuse by CEOs. Similarly, experiments demonstrate that humans frequently act in altruistic manners despite financial incentives to act unfairly.

  5. Trade Can Make Everyone Better Off .
    Trade allows each person to specialize in the activities he or she does best. By trading with others, people can buy a greater variety of goods or services.

    See my article on faux "trade deals" that exposes this myth.

  6. Markets Are Usually a Good Way to Organize Economic Activity .
    Households and firms that interact in market economies act as if they are guided by an "invisible hand" that leads the market to allocate resources efficiently. The opposite of this is economic activity that is organized by a central planner within the government.

    Again, the key interaction under theoclassical theory is between CEO and consumers, employees, creditors, shareholders, and the general public. "Markets" are vague constructs and they work best when ethical and legal provisions reduce fraud to minor levels. When these ethical and legal institutions are not extremely effective against fraud, the incentives created by the market can be so perverse that they create a criminogenic environment that produces epidemic levels of fraud. Mankiw's myth is to describe only one possible incentive and treat it as the sole possibility other than what he falsely describes as "the opposite" – a government planner. The opposite incentive to the so-called "invisible hand" is the Gresham's dynamic. Mankiw mythically presents the government as the threat to an effective economy rather than an institution that is essential to producing and enforcing the rule of law that prevents a Gresham's dynamic.

  7. Governments Can Sometimes Improve Market Outcomes .
    When a market fails to allocate resources efficiently, the government can change the outcome through public policy. Examples are regulations against monopolies and pollution.

    The myth here is that government only has a desirable role where there is a "market fail[ure]." Mankiw treats "markets" as the norm and implicitly assumes that the government normally has nothing to do with making markets succeed. Even conservative classical economists admitted that the rule of law was essential to an effective economy and required an effective government. Well-functioning governments always improve "market outcomes." Indeed, they are typically essential to making possible well-functioning "markets."

    Mankiw also fails to explain that "markets" will be fictional and massively distort resource allocation (that is what a hyper-inflated bubble does) when there is an epidemic of control fraud. As I have explained, Mankiw's own principles predict (indeed, over-predict) that deregulated "markets" will frequently prove so criminogenic that they will produce epidemics of control fraud.

  8. A Country's Standard of Living Depends on Its Ability to Produce Goods and Services. Countries whose workers produce a large quantity of goods and services per unit of time enjoy a high standard of living. Similarly, as a nation's productivity grows, so does its average income.

    First, the CEOs of sectors such as finance that are immensely unproductive – so unproductive that they cause enormous losses rather than growth, and receive exceptional income because they loot. Income is often based not on productivity, but on the CEOs' wealth and economic and political power that allows them to rig the economy. A nation's standard of living also depends on its employment levels, which can be crushed by economic policies such as austerity.

    The issue is not what happens to "average income," but what happens to median income, wealth, the income and wealth of the lowest quartile or particular minorities, and to income and wealth inequality. A nation can have high average productivity, yet have poor performance for decades in these other critical measures.

    Consider what has happened to the folks who tried to do everything right to boost their productivity according to the theoclassical economic "experts'" advice. This is what has happened to Latino and black households where a head of the household has at least a college degree. The source is economists at the extremely conservative St. Louis Fed .

    Hispanic and black families headed by someone with a four-year college degree, on the other hand, typically fared significantly worse than Hispanic and black families without college degrees. This was true both during the recent turbulent period (2007-2013) as well as during a two-decade span ending in 2013 (the most recent data available).

    White and Asian college-headed families generally fared much better than their less-educated counterparts. The typical Hispanic and black college-headed family, on the other hand, lost much more wealth than its less-educated counterpart. Median wealth declined by about 72 percent among Hispanic college-grad families versus a decline of only 41 percent among Hispanic families without a college degree. Among blacks, the declines were 60 percent versus 37 percent.

    One of the reasons that college-educated Latino and black families lost so much wealth compared to their white and Asian-American counterparts is that they were more likely to get their degrees from the for-profit colleges that theoclassical economists touted – colleges that frequently provided a very expensive and very poor education, often involving defrauding the students. Another reason that college-educated Latino and black families lost so much wealth compared to their white and Asian-American counterparts is that they were far more likely to be the victims of predatory home lending – an activity for which theoclassical economists served as the primary apologists.

    Mankiw also ignores critical factors that determine "a country's standard of living." Yes, China reports higher growth, but it is also operating in an unsustainable fashion that has destroyed much of its environment and threatens to be a major contributor to the global suicide strategy of causing severe climate change.

  9. Prices Rise When the Government Prints Too Much Money . When a government creates large quantities of the nation's money, the value of the money falls. As a result, prices increase, requiring more of the same money to buy goods and services.

    No, and Mankiw knew this was a myth when he wrote it. First, "prices rise" for many reasons. Pharmaceutical prices rise because hedge fund managers take over pharma firms or encourage others to do so in order to increase prices on existing drugs by hundreds, sometimes thousands of percent. Prices rise because accounting control fraud recipes hyper-inflated the largest bubble in history in U.S. real estate. Prices rise because of cartels. Prices rise because oil cartels cause oil shocks. Prices rise due to real bottlenecks, e.g., shortages of a skill or material.

    Inflation has not risen, indeed general price levels have often fallen (deflation) despite record creation of money by central banks and private banks. Theoclassical economists have regularly predicted hyper-inflation. As Paul Krugman emphasizes, virtually none of them even admits their serial prediction failures.

  10. Society Faces a Short-Run Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment . Reducing inflation often causes a temporary rise in unemployment. This tradeoff is crucial for understanding the short-run effects of changes in taxes, government spending and monetary policy.

    Mankiw ends his ten myths with a series of myths. Foolish, counterproductive austerity often causes inflation to fall to harmfully low – even negative (deflation) – levels that can lead to prolonged recessions that cause severe damage to people and economies. Stimulus provides a win-win that improves economic growth and reduces human suffering without causing harmful inflation.

    A nation is able to operate at extremely high levels of employment without producing harmful inflation. Mankiw is a partisan Republican. When Republican presidents in the modern era are faced with recessions they junk their theoclassical dogmas and adopt stimulus programs, though they generally do so largely through the economically inefficient and less effective means of slashing tax rates for the wealthy.

Democrats: Please Renounce Mankiw's Myths

Unlike the Republicans, who always rise above their theoclassical principles when their president is in office and faces a recession, the "New Democrats" are the ones who seem to have drunk the theoclassical Kool-Aid and strive endlessly to create the self-inflicted wound of austerity when they are in power. New Democrats also love to bash Republican presidents for running deficits even when those deficits produced no harmful inflation and helped produce recovery. It is sensible and honest to point out that tax cuts for the wealthy are a far less effective form of stimulus and to present and support superior alternatives such as job guarantee and infrastructure programs. It would be superb if Democrats were to point out that by far the most effective, prompt means of cutting taxes to stimulate the economy in response to a recession is to cease collecting the Social Security taxes for several years. It is not fine to praise Bill Clinton for taking the harmful step of running a budget surplus or to bash Republicans because they – correctly – increased fiscal stimulus (and therefore the short-term deficit) in response to a recession.

Democrats also need to stop spreading the myth that Bill Clinton was an economic marvel. He was the luckiest president in history in terms of timing. His economic "success" was the product of two of the largest bubbles in history (the dot.com and real estate bubbles). The real estate bubble is the only thing that prevented his dot.com bubble from causing an economic collapse during his term. The real estate bubble was so enormous that it made it easy for the fraudulent CEOs to "roll" (refinance) the fraudulent loans they made, which helped cause the bubble to hyper-inflate. The saying in the trade is "a rolling loan gathers no loss." This meant that the bubble was Bill Clinton and George Bush's bubble, but it collapsed on George Bush's watch so Clinton gets the credit for the high employment produced by the twin bubbles and Bush gets the blame for the massive unemployment that a massive bubble will create when it collapses (if it is not replaced by an even larger bubble).

Selected Skeptical Comments
ke , May 17, 2016 at 1:10pm

The pots are calling the kettles black; standard politics, redundancy easily replaced by automation.

You do know that Bernie isn't going after Hillary because he has his skeletons, especially in the medical university complex, don't you. Ever live in Vermont. You did notice that Hillary just threatened him, to the core of his argument.

Jef , May 17, 2016 at 11:2am

Ke – Very insightful!

This… "Energy is information, most of which humans ignore."…and this… "Public Education policies are disgusting to anyone who really wants to learn…" are the important elements although I would add that humans don't ignore so much as don't know/are not taught, and I would say Public education has been purposefully corroded to the point of disgusting.

Left in Wisconsin , May 17, 2016 at 11:5am

Democrats: Please Renounce Mankiw's Myths

Good one.

Jim Haygood , May 17, 2016 at 12:14pm

"Prices rise" for many reasons.

Pharmaceutical prices rise because hedge fund managers take over pharma firms or encourage others to do so in order to increase prices on existing drugs by hundreds, sometimes thousands of percent. Prices rise because accounting control fraud recipes hyper-inflated the largest bubble in history in U.S. real estate. Prices rise because of cartels. Prices rise because oil cartels cause oil shocks. Prices rise due to real bottlenecks, e.g., shortages of a skill or material.

- Bill Black

----–

All of these examples treat relative price rises in the affected sector, not the general inflation which saw the U.S. CPI increase by a factor of ten (10) since 1950. Hedge funds and cartels couldn't do that, no matter how successful they were in increasing their share of the pie.

The same logic is used by union busters to claim that "greedy labor unions" cause inflation - an equally false notion. Labor can increase its share of national income at the expense of corporate profit, but it cannot cause a general inflation.

This unprecedented secular inflation did, however, coincide with government bonds surpassing gold as the Federal Reserve's largest holding in 1945, and with the dollar's gold link being severed in 1971.

Bill Black evidently hews to the scholarly tradition of the eminent Argentine economist and former central banker Mercedes Marcó del Pont:

"It is totally false to say that the printing more money generates inflation; price increases are generated by other phenomena like supply and external sector's behaviour," said Marcó del Pont.

http://tinyurl.com/jk5d64w

This from a country that lopped thirteen (13) zeros off its currency in the past century.

*takes another bong hit and blows a fat smoke ring*

ChrisPacific , May 17, 2016 at 6:35pm

I would argue that the real estate bubble caused genuine inflation because it was a credit bubble, but I agree on your other points. Intuitively I think of inflation as a rise in prices without a corresponding rise in (average) affordability. It's why a Big Mac today can cost multiple times what it did 30 years ago without being any less affordable for the average customer.

Mankiw's definition isn't precisely wrong but it's oversimplified. He doesn't address the role of banks in money creation, he doesn't define money (what about credit?) he doesn't discuss the factors that might cause government to print more or less money, and he doesn't say how much is too much. Without more rigor than he provides, it's only useful as a plausibility argument after the fact.

Regarding Black's comment:

Inflation has not risen, indeed general price levels have often fallen (deflation) despite record creation of money by central banks and private banks.

I would say this was because they were doing it during the deflation of a credit bubble on a large enough scale that money creation by the government was a drop in the bucket by comparison, and that was what caused deflation. Which again points to the importance of defining terms and operating constraints (why couldn't the government print money on a massive scale to compensate? What are the drawbacks and limitations on that approach?)

Economists do love to make doomsday hyperinflation predictions that never seem to pan out. As far as I can tell, that's because they think that the economy is inherently unstable and will lapse naturally into massive inflation (see: wage-price spiral) or some other disastrous state without the wise guiding hand of a central banker to prevent it. There seems to be very little evidence of this actually happening in reality, and the few genuine examples of hyperinflation (Weimar, Zimbabwe) have typically resulted from a collapse in production coupled with debts denominated in other currencies that (a) considerably exceed the country's ability to pay and (b) require the attempt to be made anyway.

Nathanael , May 21, 2016 at 8:0am

Notice that Mankiw managed to say nothing about "Economic instability or deflation, and eventually economic depression, is caused when the government prints TOO LITTLE money", which is actually true and happens quite reliably.

Mankiw is a propagandist.

TG , May 17, 2016 at 12:59pm

The true laws of economics:

  1. If it is physically impossible for something to occur, it won't, and finance be damned. Economics is first and foremost a branch of the physical sciences, though most economists have forgotten this.
  2. Supply and demand.
  3. Unintended consequences.
  4. High productivity does not create high wages. High wages create high productivity. If you spend a lot of money on water-conservation technology at the base of Niagara Falls, will it increase the economic value of water there?
  5. The physical utility of a commodity (including labor) is not related to its economic value. Adam Smith did get something right.
  6. Nothing in this universe can grow exponentially for very long. Societies with sustained high fertility rates will always be miserably poor, and only societies that have first reduced their fertility rate can hope to become rich.
  7. A (more-or-less) free market is indeed a powerful and essential optimization mechanism ("the invisible hand") but it is nonlinear. Like all such nonlinear optimization mechanisms, it can and does get stuck in local minima and require external directed efforts to move to a more optimal solution. This is basic math.
  8. Inflation occurs when prices go up. That's it.
  9. "Capitalism" guarantees neither poverty nor prosperity. The market is neutral. Even as the laws of physics are obeyed equally well by a building that stands tall as by one that collapses into a heap of rubble, the laws of the market are also obeyed in miserably poor Bangladesh as well as in prosperous Switzerland. With 100 desperate people competing for every job, wages for the many will be low and profits for the few will be high. And vice versa. Blaming "capitalism" for poverty is silly, as if I threw someone off a cliff and then blamed the law of gravity for their death. Trying to deny market forces is equally silly, like trying to legislate gravity out of existence. It simply must be worked with.
  10. "Free to choose to own or employ slaves", "Free trade includes the ability of big corporations to restrict trade to maximize their profits", "Free to buy politicians and have them loot the public treasury in your interest" … Strict libertarianism is logically incoherent and ethically vile.
bdy , May 18, 2016 at 12:3am

Nice.

I quibble with 6 & 8. "A more or less free market" is a well regulated market. How much "more free" or "less free" a market needs to be to best distribute its product depends entirely on its particular conditions and vagaries. The insinuation that a market should be "stuck in a local minima" before oversight can improve its performance echoes Mankiw's 7th misconstruction, that (in Bill Black's words) "government only has a desirable role when there is a market failure."

I especially disagree that markets are neutral. Markets exist at the pleasure of the Capitalists who create and smother them for profit. Capitalists are forever cajoling "market opportunities" out from under every rock they can turn over. They invent, shape, split, combine, dissect, analyze, produce, reproduce, abandon, corner and strangle markets in pursuit of lucre. There is no market for Ford electric cars in California beyond the handful required by statute, despite ample demand, because individuals at Ford have determined that creating that particular market will eat into the personal profit they might extract from other markets. "Efficient" markets, that only return a gazilionth of a point on investment because of optimal competition, cease to be because the margin is too low to justify the hassle or the capital risk. Switching gears, labor markets in Bangladesh & Switzerland exist when Capitalists decide to hire workers. Hirees agree to be paid what Capitalists choose to pay, whether "freely" or under the duress of the State.

There is no market equivalent to gravity or the law of planetary motion. The model of supply and demand is a hypothetical post rationalization of a shifting negotiation – while it's helpful to a degree, supply/demand doesn't make "lawfull" (or useful) predictions until demand nears infinity (see health care: "how much will that be, doc?" – "how much have you got?", or housing: "how much can you borrow from a fractional reserve player who lends without risk and won't verify your income?")

As the local monopolists of violence, States can engage markets as they see fit. They can supply (Volkswagon & the post office), demand (food stamps, R&D grants), regulate, open (ACA) or close them (pharmaceutical imports) to their hearts desire. Good or bad outcomes depend entirely on the wisdom of the policy.

Whoa. Exhale. To be sure, I inhaled. Too many words when I should just say:

Nice.

Its good we agree that policy should be just and compassionate.

Chauncey Gardiner , May 17, 2016 at 1:12pm

The values and ideology represented in the Economics textbook Bill Black analyzed didn't arise in a vacuum. The points Black lists reflect the ideology, values, ethics and interests of a narrow segment of our society who have accumulated enormous personal wealth through a variety of extra-legal and illegal mechanisms, and who use a small portion of that wealth to fund "Economics Chairs" in our public and private universities; economics "think tanks"; and speeches, books, consulting engagements, and board memberships for "prominent economists".

This matter is really about whose values will control government economic policy and law.

Excellent analysis. Thank you, Bill Black, for all you do and have done.

Lumpenproletariat , May 17, 2016 at 1:16pm

#11

Mankiw is a shill/useful idiot for his oligarchs patrons. #11 explains the idiocy of the previous 10.

steelhead23 , May 17, 2016 at 2:45pm

I see much of the underlying theory of classical economics as simplifications that make the math easier. One of my favorite examples of misallocation of resources was the market for Burbank Russet potatoes in 2001. Basically, producers wanted $6.50 per hundredweight for spuds. The big buyer, Simplot offered farmers $4.50 pre-season. Many farmers decided to wait until harvest, hoping the spot market would give them a better price. I should also mention that in Idaho, farmers not wishing to plant in a given year, could sell their water to other farmers, or to the federal government which uses the water to help salmon and to produce hydropower. Thus, producing potatoes carried the opportunity cost of water leasing. But leasing water leasing to the federal government is culturally taboo in the ag. community. 2001 was a dry year and most of the ag. water was consumed growing spuds.

The outcome was a banner year in production, driving the spot market price to $0.50 per hundredweight, far less than the cost of production. Many acres of potatoes were plowed under – a total loss – to everyone.

My point is – there is no way to know, in advance, what the price of a commodity will be in the future unless you know, or can limit, the rate of production and control demand.

Did the banks which loaned billions to the gas frackers of North Dakota know that production would exceed demand and cause a crash? Perhaps the loan officer might have such concern, but would more likely be most concerned with his/her own bottom line – a meme Yves explores in Econned.

I suppose I am a bit defensive of classical microeconomics because it is elegant. But I am also terribly suspicious of its answers because one never has either the information or the control to be anywhere near as certain as the calculus would suggest.

Mike Thorne , May 17, 2016 at 4:01pm

On point #9: "Prices Rise When the Government Prints Too Much Money". Recent inflation data suggests it's a myth. But if restated as "When government prints money, prices rise on the goods and services that the people who receive the money tend to buy", then it's NOT a myth.

That was the whole problem with the Federal Reserve's damned QE efforts. They printed gobs of money, and it all landed in the pockets of the wealthy. The stuff they buy (stocks, real estate, luxury goods, premium educations, etc.) has seen prices rise MUCH faster than nominal inflation. And the people who didn't get any of the newly printed money (i.e., most of us)… Well, these sad folks couldn't afford to spend any more than before, so anybody who attempted to impose prices hikes on low-end consumer goods saw a loss of sales volume.

Newly-printed money CAN cause inflation, but WHERE the price rises happen depends greatly on the pockets in which the money lands.

Jeff Z , May 17, 2016 at 6:24pm

Excellent Point!

TK421 , May 17, 2016 at 6:32pm

stocks, real estate, luxury goods, premium educations, etc.

But it's hard to produce more of those, so with an increase in money chasing them their prices will rise. If the government handed money to poor people, they would buy food, clothes, cars, televisions, etc. In other words, things that society can produce more of. That's my read, anyway.

Mike Thorne , May 18, 2016 at 8:2am

Partially. Prices for good where quantities are truly fixed (like acres of land in San Francisco) can rise sharply when extra money pours in.

But even when there is opportunity to increase production, manufacturers must purchase equipment (like farm equipment for more food) or hire more workers (thereby tightening the labor market and pushing wages up). These result in price hikes. More modest price hikes than San Francisco real estate, but still real hikes. It's the classic supply vs. demand curve from classic microeconomics.

That said, "QE to the people" is certainly less objectionable than the "QE to the bankers and the 1%" that we've seen over the past five years. Prices would go up, but people would get to buy more things they want or need, and hiring would likely go up as well. [And at a minimum, there needs to be at least *some* growth in the money supply to keep up with population growth. Otherwise we see deflation and the ability to become wealthier by hoarding cash.]

dao , May 17, 2016 at 5:07pm

This was Mankiw's "response" to OWS back in 2011:

"Here is a fact that you might not have heard from the Occupy Wall Street crowd: The incomes at the top of the income distribution have fallen substantially over the past few years.

"According to the most recent IRS data, between 2007 and 2009, the 99th percentile income (AGI, not inflation-adjusted) fell from $410,096 to $343,927. The 99.9th percentile income fell from $2,155,365 to $1,432,890. During the same period, median income fell from $32,879 to $32,396."

This kind of ignorant cluelessness is pretty prevalent among the oligarchy and its supporters like Mankiw. Just like that guy in Davos who simply couldn't understand why there's so much social unrest in the world today. They live in a completely different world.

TK421 , May 17, 2016 at 6:33pm

And since then, nearly every penny of income gains has gone to the 1%.

Expat , May 18, 2016 at 2:3am

The big difference being that $70k to the 99th percentile means the difference between a new Beemer this year or next while $500 for the median family means choosing which child goes hungry for the second half of December.

And of course, Anonymous's excellent point. You are cherry picking old data based on a stock market and real estate bubble crash. Median income families don't "own" real estate and certainly don't own stocks.

Mankiw is either psychotic or was gleefully obfuscating when he presenting that out-dated analysis.

I say Kill the Rich and feed their bodies to the poor. It's not a solution at all (and I am rich myself) but it would be deeply, deeply satisfying!

Jayinbmore , May 18, 2016 at 8:5am

My first exposure to Mankiw's principles was actually an early version of the talk by Yoram Bauman in this video. It hits several of the points Mr. Black makes and is also pretty funny. It definitely demonstrates how Mankiw attempts to cloak his biases in supposedly neutral terms.

Erwin Gordon , May 18, 2016 at 10:2am

As for number 6, I couldn't disagree with you more. Organisational power is dependent on it being enforced BY THE GOVERNMENT. Without that coercion, individuals would find other solutions for the want provided for by that particular organisation. I would suggest that you look at the history of Pennsylvania circa 1681-1690 or Moresnet (in what is now Aachen) circa 1816 until the end of WWI to understand what is possible when the free market really operates.

Nontraditional Student , May 19, 2016 at 6:2am

I am actually a returning undergrad student and starting an econ course next week. I just looked at the text book… and its Mankiw. Should be a fun semester.

Yves Smith , May 19, 2016 at 8:2am

Don't argue with the PR. You need to be strategic. Regurgitate the BS but be sure to read enough corrective material that the toxins don't infect your brain.

Patrick , May 20, 2016 at 5:19pm

I doubt Mankiw will accept 100% estate tax on the justification that the cost of bequests is zero to the recipient. (and thus a 100% estate tax doesn't incur large costs on the recipient)

Asad Zaman , July 13, 2016 at 10:1am

My paper lists four principles claimed to be at the core of modern economics by Mankiw and then shows how all four principles are false: Amir-ud-Din, Rafi and Zaman, Asad, Failures of the 'Invisible Hand' (July 15, 2013). Forum for Social Economics, Vol. 45, Iss. 1, 2016. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2293940 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2293940

[Jun 18, 2016] Greenspan Shocked Disbelief by Robert Borosage

Greenspan phony "Shocked disbelief" reminds classic "...I am shocked - shocked, there is gambling going on in this establishment...." "...here are your winnings..." exchange between Humphrey Bogart & Claude Rains in Casablanca. Compare with "... "Those of us who have looked to the self-interest of lending institutions to protect shareholders' equity, myself included, are in a state of shocked disbelief," he said. ..."
Notable quotes:
"... "Those of us who have looked to the self-interest of lending institutions to protect shareholders' equity, myself included, are in a state of shocked disbelief," ..."
"... Greenspan spurned the Republican acolytes trying desperately to defend the faith and blame the crisis on the Community Reinvestment Act and the powerful lobby of poor people who forced powerless banks to do reckless things. ..."
"... Private greed, not public good, caused this catastrophe: "The evidence now suggests, but only in retrospect, that this market evolved in a manner which if there were no securitization, it would have been a much smaller problem and, indeed, very unlikely to have taken on the dimensions that it did. It wasn't until the securitization became a significant factor, which doesn't occur until 2005, that you got this huge increase in demand for subprime loans, because remember that without securitization, there would not have been a single subprime mortgage held outside of the United States, that it's the opening up of this market which created a huge demand from abroad for subprime mortgages as embodied in mortgage-backed securities. ..."
"... But having admitted the failure of his faith, Greenspan could not abandon it. Credit default swaps had to be "restrained," he admitted. Those who create mortgages should be mandated to retain a piece of them to insure responsible lending. Otherwise, the old faith still applied. No new regulations were needed, because the markets "for the indefinite future will be far more restrained than would any currently contemplated new regulatory regime." ..."
"... The only Guantanamo that the United States has any business running is a concentration camp for the hundreds of wall street executives and their cronies in Bushland that conspired to defraud the American people from their hard earned dollar. ..."
"... There are no free markets in America, any more than there is free lunch. ..."
"... So it wasn't the military-industrial complex that did us in after all . . . ..."
"... It's clear from comments on this contribution that few readers of Truthout believe Alan Greenspan's sorry testimony before Congress. What has faith in something to do with enforcing the policies of fiduciary responsibility already on the books? All these so-called "experts" on capitalism are now coming out to say "I'm sorry." Well, I won't be sorry for them until they are held monetarily and criminally responsible for their actions, inept or not. ..."
"... If it looks like class warfare, as David Harvey, author of Neoliberalism, has stated, call it class warfare and act accordingly. ..."
"... it doesn't take a genius to understand that when financial instruments are created based on crap (subprime mortgages), that eventually problems will occur with those instruments. In fact, Greenspan and his cronies knew that, which is why they resisted these instruments being regulated by the SEC or even the CFTC. ..."
"... Sounds like the "maestro" hit a flat note in his orchestra of greed and deregulation. ..."
"... Did anybody even bother to consult the Math PhDs who created these instruments to run possible scenarios -- just in case? why bother when you know you can scare congress, the president and the treasury and ultimately the people into bailing your ass out of worldwide collapse? ..."
"... Shocked Disbelief is a ploy. When they were all riding high, they didn't give a crap. They were going to come out richer than hell anyway. ..."
"... Where's Ayn Rand when you need her? Give me a break Mr Greenspan. Never let history and reality get in the way of the big unregulated celebration of greed like we have had since "Saint Ronald Wilson Reagan", and the other "Free Market" "government is the problem" ideologues ..."
"... What about the 1994 Act of Congress that required the Fed to monitor and regulate derivatives? The Act Greenspan ignored? ..."
"... "...I am shocked - shocked, there is gambling going on in this establishment...." "...here are your winnings..." exchange between Humphrey Bogart & Claude Rains in Casablanca ..."
Oct 24, 2008 | truthout.org

by: Robert Borosage, The Campaign for America's Future

On October 23, former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan testified before a House Oversight and Government Reform Committee hearing on the role of federal regulators in the current financial crisis.

It marks the end of an era. Alan Greenspan, the maestro, defender of the market fundamentalist faith, champion of deregulation, celebrator of exotic banking inventions, admitted Thursday in a hearing before Rep. Henry Waxman's House Committee and Oversight and Government Reform that he got it wrong.

"Those of us who have looked to the self-interest of lending institutions to protect shareholders' equity, myself included, are in a state of shocked disbelief," he said.

As to the fantasy that banks could regulate themselves, that markets self-correct, that modern risk management enforced prudence: "The whole intellectual edifice, however, collapsed in the summer of last year."

Greenspan spurned the Republican acolytes trying desperately to defend the faith and blame the crisis on the Community Reinvestment Act and the powerful lobby of poor people who forced powerless banks to do reckless things. Greenspan dismissed that goofiness in response to a question from one of its right-wing purveyors, Rep. Todd Platts, R-Pa., noting that subprime loans grew to a crisis only as the unregulated shadow financial system securitized mortgages, marketed them across the world, and pressured brokers to lower standards to generate a larger supply to meet the demand. Private greed, not public good, caused this catastrophe:

"The evidence now suggests, but only in retrospect, that this market evolved in a manner which if there were no securitization, it would have been a much smaller problem and, indeed, very unlikely to have taken on the dimensions that it did. It wasn't until the securitization became a significant factor, which doesn't occur until 2005, that you got this huge increase in demand for subprime loans, because remember that without securitization, there would not have been a single subprime mortgage held outside of the United States, that it's the opening up of this market which created a huge demand from abroad for subprime mortgages as embodied in mortgage-backed securities.

But having admitted the failure of his faith, Greenspan could not abandon it. Credit default swaps had to be "restrained," he admitted. Those who create mortgages should be mandated to retain a piece of them to insure responsible lending. Otherwise, the old faith still applied. No new regulations were needed, because the markets "for the indefinite future will be far more restrained than would any currently contemplated new regulatory regime."

Now hung over from their bender, the banks could be depended upon to remain sober "for the indefinite future." Or until taxpayers' money relieves their headaches, and they are free to party once more.


IN ACCORDANCE WITH TITLE 17 U.S.C. SECTION 107, THIS MATERIAL IS DISTRIBUTED WITHOUT PROFIT TO THOSE WHO HAVE EXPRESSED A PRIOR INTEREST IN RECEIVING THE INCLUDED INFORMATION FOR RESEARCH AND EDUCATIONAL PURPOSES. TRUTHOUT HAS NO AFFILIATION WHATSOEVER WITH THE ORIGINATOR OF THIS ARTICLE NOR IS TRUTHOUT ENDORSED OR SPONSORED BY THE ORIGINATOR.

"VIEW SOURCE ARTICLE" LINKS ARE PROVIDED AS A CONVENIENCE TO OUR READERS AND ALLOW FOR VERIFICATION OF AUTHENTICITY. HOWEVER, AS ORIGINATING PAGES ARE OFTEN UPDATED BY THEIR ORIGINATING HOST SITES, THE VERSIONS POSTED ON TO MAY NOT MATCH THE VERSIONS OUR READERS VIEW WHEN CLICKING THE "VIEW SOURCE ARTICLE" LINKS.

Comments

This is a moderated forum. It may take a little while for comments to go live.

The only Guantanamo that the

Sun, 10/26/2008 - 23:37 - Captain America (not verified)

The only Guantanamo that the United States has any business running is a concentration camp for the hundreds of wall street executives and their cronies in Bushland that conspired to defraud the American people from their hard earned dollar.

What they did dwarfs the damage caused to this country by 911, (no disrespect for the many innocents who died). However, here, every single citizen is a victim of fraud and corruption on a scale that was heretofore inconceivable. Greenspan, Bush and now Paulson have done more than Bin Laden and his hordes could do in a 100 years.

By the way, if you protest YOU wind up locked up for being un-American. What happened America ?

There are no free markets in

Sun, 10/26/2008 - 19:27 - pink elephant (not verified)

There are no free markets in America, any more than there is free lunch. The game was always fixed and Greenspan was the ultimate shill for the fixers. The past thirty years have been an orgy of greed with common sense shoved aside for the sake of uncommon expediency. Americans became infatuated by arcane formulas and dense incomprehensible mathematics to the point that they forget simple arithmetic. America wake up it was only a dream, and a bad one at that.

So it wasn't the

Sun, 10/26/2008 - 19:07 - Anonymous (not verified)

So it wasn't the military-industrial complex that did us in after all . . .

It's clear from comments on

Sun, 10/26/2008 - 15:40 - afrothethics (not verified)

It's clear from comments on this contribution that few readers of Truthout believe Alan Greenspan's sorry testimony before Congress. What has faith in something to do with enforcing the policies of fiduciary responsibility already on the books? All these so-called "experts" on capitalism are now coming out to say "I'm sorry." Well, I won't be sorry for them until they are held monetarily and criminally responsible for their actions, inept or not. The truth is as plain as the nose on your face: Greenspan, the Federal Reserve, the investment banks, the Bush administration and several members of Congress unobtrusively acted to consciously and knowingly to rob the national treasury for the sake of capitalism's sacred cow: capital accumulation on behalf of the nation's political and economic elite. If it looks like class warfare, as David Harvey, author of Neoliberalism, has stated, call it class warfare and act accordingly.

We have heard statements

Sun, 10/26/2008 - 10:11 - DJK (not verified)

We have heard statements like "the mathematical models used for knowing the behavior of derivatives based on subprime mortgages were too difficult to understand", etc. But it doesn't take a genius to understand that when financial instruments are created based on crap (subprime mortgages), that eventually problems will occur with those instruments. In fact, Greenspan and his cronies knew that, which is why they resisted these instruments being regulated by the SEC or even the CFTC. And this is why they turned a blind eye to many of the rating agencies giving many of these instruments AAA ratings. I am sure that a real investigation will reveal numerous instances of fraudulent activity in conjunction with this debacle. Those perpetrators must be identified and brought to justice. While this will not fix our current problem, it hopefully should serve as a deterrent to those who would in the future attempt to again engage in such activities.

Well here you have it a

Sun, 10/26/2008 - 08:13 - Robert Iserbyt (not verified)

Well here you have it a confessional lie from the biggest fraud perpetrator in the history of American finance Why the markets ever listened to this criminal in the first place is evidence that our entire nation should be required to take a full year of real unfettered economics just in case they don't understand what is going on now. All the pundits on MSNBC and all the talking heads should be removed from the airwaves. The Bailout what will that do? the answer lies before you.

Sounds like the "maestro"

Sun, 10/26/2008 - 02:02 - Anonymous (not verified)

Sounds like the "maestro" hit a flat note in his orchestra of greed and deregulation. Come on, do you really think we are all so stupid to buy into the story that you couldn't predict a melt down knowing that those writing the subprimes held no responsibility for their actions? That's like giving a "get out of jail card" to someone who just created a felony! Did anybody even bother to consult the Math PhDs who created these instruments to run possible scenarios -- just in case? why bother when you know you can scare congress, the president and the treasury and ultimately the people into bailing your ass out of worldwide collapse?

I'm a former real estate

Sun, 10/26/2008 - 00:24 - two7five7one (not verified)

I'm a former real estate broker and my son is a mortgage broker. From about 2004 through the beginning of this "greatest financial crisis since '29", we frequently talked on the phone about the disaster which would ensue when the real estate value appreciation stopped, and people were no longer fueling the economy with money borrowed against their equity, and the sub-prime loan fiasco would end. We knew it would be disastrous, and both of us were astonished that neither the FED nor congress was willing to say or do anything about it. Anyone who has witnessed over the years the cycle of boom/bust/boom/bust in the real estate market knew that after eleven years of unprecedented "boom" -- '96 through '2007 -- the "bust" would be like an earthquake. Paulson and Greenspan and their ilk now denying that they suspected this is just is just their lying to protect the GOP which was benefitting from the booming economy. They should both end up in prison, with all of the GOP members of congress who have had their hands in the cash register.

Dance clown, dance. First

Sat, 10/25/2008 - 23:48 - mysterioso (not verified)

Dance clown, dance. First you were against the FED until you became head of the FED. Then you were for trickle down economics and letting the "system" regulate itself until you saw the inevitable destruction it caused. Dance clown, dance. You should be the first one sent to prison under the "Un-American activities act". The arrogance of your testimony before the committee was appalling. You honestly couldn't believe you were wrong !!!

Shocked disbelief, my foot.

Sat, 10/25/2008 - 23:35 - slw (not verified)

Shocked disbelief, my foot. Many of us predicted EXACTLY this outcome.

This is like telling the Fox

Sat, 10/25/2008 - 22:43 - topview (not verified)

This is like telling the Fox to watch the Hens and then walking away and trusting him to do the right thing. Government has to return to regulation and see that there is no hanky, Banky going on anymore. Monopolies have to be busted up, like the Communication industry's, the Drug industries and any other Corporations that control to much of the way the Country operates. No more Outsourcing any Government duties.

Shocked Disbelief is a ploy.

Sat, 10/25/2008 - 22:00 - radline9 (not verified)

Shocked Disbelief is a ploy. When they were all riding high, they didn't give a crap. They were going to come out richer than hell anyway.

Where's Ayn Rand when you

Sat, 10/25/2008 - 20:53 - anglohistorian (not verified)

Where's Ayn Rand when you need her? Give me a break Mr Greenspan. Never let history and reality get in the way of the big unregulated celebration of greed like we have had since "Saint Ronald Wilson Reagan", and the other "Free Market" "government is the problem" ideologues. We can spend trillions on war and corporate bailouts, but we can't have a single payer health system? We can't rebuild our infrastructure? Say it again- give me a break!

What about the 1994 Act of

Sat, 10/25/2008 - 20:41 - Jtmonrow (not verified)

What about the 1994 Act of Congress that required the Fed to monitor and regulate derivatives? The Act Greenspan ignored?

"...I am shocked - shocked,

Sat, 10/25/2008 - 20:29 - Anonymous (not verified)

"...I am shocked - shocked, there is gambling going on in this establishment...." "...here are your winnings..." exchange between Humphrey Bogart & Claude Rains in Casablanca

This would be the same

Sat, 10/25/2008 - 19:50 - dtroutma (not verified)

This would be the same "shocked disbelief" expressed by Willie Sutton's mother?

shouldn't Greenspan give his

Sat, 10/25/2008 - 18:06 - Anonymous (not verified)

shouldn't Greenspan give his salary and bonus back to taxpayers?

[May 20, 2016] Gerald Friedman: How the Dogmatic Despair of Mainstream Economists Brought You Donald Trump

Notable quotes:
"... By Gerald Friedman, Professor of Economics, University of Massachusetts, Amherst. A version of this post first appeared at the Institute for New Economic Thinking website ..."
"... Lesser Depression ..."
"... The reason why elite economists and politicians were so angry at my analysis of Sanders' proposals was that it disrupted a consensus that nothing can be done by government to improve the performance of the economy. After all, if things are already as good as they can be, it is irresponsible pie-in-the-sky to even suggest to the general public that we can do better. Instead, the task of economists and other policy elites becomes to explain to the general public why they should accept stagnant incomes and rising inequality, and applaud the anemic growth of recent years as the best possible outcome. But the real danger of such thinking is that it leaves liberals like Hillary Clinton with few policy options to offer in response to the siren song of demagogues like Donald Trump. The self-proclaimed "responsible" elite economists see their role as to persuade the public that nothing can be done, in the hope of heading off the challenge of those who would capitalize on the electorate's appetite for change. They have to slap down critics. "Responsible" elite economists have to keep the party of "good arithmetic" from overpromising at all costs. It should not surprise us, though, that those whose living standards have suffered most from stagnant growth are more inclined to believe politicians promising change. ..."
"... John Maynard Keynes showed how active government policy can raise employment and output; his followers, including Joan Robinson and Nicholas Kaldor, showed how full employment encourages further investments and leads businesses to find ways to raise labor productivity to match increasing product demand. New Deal American economists, such as Rexford Tugwell and John Maurice Clark, showed how active government policy can raise growth rates with investments in infrastructure, in public services, in human capital development, and in research and development. By listening to these ideas, economists associated with liberal American politics helped produce 25 years of relatively rapid and egalitarian growth after World War II. Abandoning these ideas, we have suffered 30 years of relatively slow growth and rising inequality, culminating in the current Lesser Depression. ..."
"... I had dinner last night with two excellent people who happen to be doing well at this time. They could not comprehend why anyone would be voting for Trump, whom they saw as a dangerous lunatic. They have supported Sanders and voted for him in the NY primary, but are absolutely going to vote for Clinton in the Fall. What I view as the credible case against Clinton has not reached them with any strength or registered at all. I was asked (because I had said nothing while they talked–I hate this kind of confrontation) what problem people could have with Hillary? I said: Libya, Ukraine, and Nicaragua. They really didn't know what I was talking about and although I spoke up for why I thought this made her a neocon like the ones that surrounded Dubya, they simply didn't know any of the details and we left it at that. ..."
"... HRC's recap of Reaganite Latin America policy is her most vile achievement. If anything demonstrates a continuity of imperialist strategy across administrations, that's it. ..."
"... " I said: Libya, Ukraine, and Nicaragua. They really didn't know what I was talking about and although I spoke up for why I thought this made her a neocon like the ones that surrounded Dubya, they simply didn't know any of the details and we left it at that." ..."
"... I run into this all the time. Utter and complete foreign policy illiteracy, particularly from otherwise politically correct millennials who know so little that Hillary gets a complete pass. ..."
"... This is a common story and illustrates that our current detachment from the world around us and our fellow citizens is coming to an end. We are being forced out of our individual bubbles. Modern corporations have supplied the populations of the world with abundance of goods, but in order to accomplish this feat, have destroyed and are destroying the cultural glue, if you will, that holds society together. ..."
"... TINA will be maintained by propaganda and physical force. We see that the propaganda is starting to weaken because the contradictions of the message can no longer be hidden. The destruction is too widespread and the inequality can no longer be hidden. You can hollow out a social system only so much before it collapses. The collapses we are witnessing is the promise of democracy. A collapse of the ideals of moderation and compromise. ..."
"... We are entering a phase of civil war. It is still carried out in a polite manner and intellectually, the discussion is still couched in Orwellian doublespeak. However, criticisms of the ruling elite are becoming more straightforward and more people are waking up to the fact that the system is rigged against them. ..."
"... This civil war is a battle over leadership. It is a battle to demand good government instead of no government. It is a battle to demand a government for and by the people. A battle for the common good. Evaluated not in some abstract terms like "trickle down" economics, but direct support and action. The hearts and minds of the population was won over long ago to wholeheartedly support capitalism and private ownership of the world's resources. This is proving to be a disaster. ..."
"... Supporters of unfettered capitalism know only one way. Privatization of ALL the worlds resources and potential. They showed their hand in 2008 with the bailouts and implementation of austerity policies. In their minds, there is no turning back. To compromise means failure. For them, TINA is real and logical. This is the perspective of owners of capital. They gain strength and advantage from seeming to compromise, but in the end know they can always reverse course and regain private control. Subterfuge and force allows the resilience of capitalism as the reigning social order. ..."
"... Jonathan Haidt is a psychologist, sometimes featured in the New York Times, who apparently believes the capability of people to be convinced by reasoned argument is not strong. From my limited reading of his work, he suggests that humans are instinctive beings who, when they have strong beliefs, their reasoning powers are used to justify these beliefs, not to cast doubt about these beliefs. ..."
"... For example, I believe HRC is little more than a well-connected and well traveled mediocrity, with a record of few positives and many egregious negatives that justifies this assessment. I view her as potentially more damaging to the USA, as President, than Trump. ..."
"... Successful big ideas and big projects require cheap abundant energy, resources and intelligent design. It'll be mighty funny when the Keynesians finally implement their plan to overhaul the national highway infrastructure, creating tons of high paying jobs and speeding up the economy–right when our access to cheap oil collapses. That's dumb design at its finest, yet this sort of thing is almost certainly the best that the lobotomized Keynesian planners will be able to think up and do. ..."
"... A truly innovative program to get the economy moving in a positive direction would be to outlaw personal vehicles and rebuild the nation's railway network. ..."
"... I share your antipathy toward freeways. I remember the big Freeway they built in Fresno when I was a child, destroying hundreds, if not thousands of modest homes (we had to move from a grand rental to a dilapidated house that cost more – were the landlords behind getting rid of a surplus of houses????) – to save maybe – maybe at the most 3 minutes in transit time over driving an existing surface street. Jobs were part of the rationale. ..."
"... "Sorry, nothing more can be done for you." TINA. ..."
"... "How can I help you today?" ..."
May 19, 2016 | nakedcapitalism.com

By Gerald Friedman, Professor of Economics, University of Massachusetts, Amherst. A version of this post first appeared at the Institute for New Economic Thinking website

The ferocious reaction to my assessment that Senator Bernie Sanders' economic and health care proposals could create long-term economic growth shows how mainstream economists who view themselves as politically liberal in America have abandoned progressive politics to embrace a political economy of despair. Rationalizing personal disappointment and embracing market-centric economic theories according to which government can do little more than fuss around the edges, their conclusions - and the political leadership that embraces them - have little to offer millions of angry ordinary people for whom the economy simply isn't working.

It has certainly been a rough seven years for the economists in the Obama Administration. While avoiding a Great Depression, the Administration has presided over what Paul Krugman and Brad DeLong call a " Lesser Depression ." One might almost forgive them for a certain defeatism after seven years of painfully slow economic recovery, and the dismay of seeing urgently needed programs blocked by the Republican congressional majority. After so many compromises and let-downs, perhaps it is easier to tell those who expect more that it just can't happen. There is comfort in the Thatcherite phrase, "There Is No Alternative" (TINA).

Combined with orthodox neoclassical microeconomics, however, rationalization has produced a toxic political economy that abandons progressive ideals and surrenders political space to xenophobes and the populist rightwing (see: Donald Trump). The mainstream economists who have attacked my embrace of Keynesian economics have abandoned, in practice, the notion that government can effectively intervene in the economy to raise levels of employment, and to promote economic growth and equity. Instead, they have returned to pre-Keynesian Classical thinking, where the very suggestion that government action can raise growth rates or wages is taken to be obviously wrong. Criticisms of the orthodox model and its conservative policies are deemed worthy of scorn, to be dismissed tout court because they are obviously at variance not only with textbook economics, but with what we need to believe in order to accept failure .

The mechanism of economic policy paralysis among the liberals who espouse market-centric economics works like this: If we accept the (flawed) premise that the total supply of goods and services equals total demand, then we can agree with the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) that potential output is best measured by observing actual output. And, with that - presto! - unemployment magically disappears, and we no longer suffer from slow growth. Conveniently align growth projections with the otherwise-disappointing performance during the Lesser Depression, and, as the CBO has done, estimates of potential growth now equal actual growth: Instead of the 3 percent average annual growth of the 1959-2007 period, not to mention the 4 percent growth 1947-73, we are now told to accept 2 percent growth not as a disappointment, but as recognition of an unfortunate necessity. Such reevaluations say to policy elites, "Hey, we are doing as well as can be expected." To the general public, the message is: "Sorry, nothing more can be done for you." TINA.

The reason why elite economists and politicians were so angry at my analysis of Sanders' proposals was that it disrupted a consensus that nothing can be done by government to improve the performance of the economy. After all, if things are already as good as they can be, it is irresponsible pie-in-the-sky to even suggest to the general public that we can do better. Instead, the task of economists and other policy elites becomes to explain to the general public why they should accept stagnant incomes and rising inequality, and applaud the anemic growth of recent years as the best possible outcome. But the real danger of such thinking is that it leaves liberals like Hillary Clinton with few policy options to offer in response to the siren song of demagogues like Donald Trump. The self-proclaimed "responsible" elite economists see their role as to persuade the public that nothing can be done, in the hope of heading off the challenge of those who would capitalize on the electorate's appetite for change. They have to slap down critics. "Responsible" elite economists have to keep the party of "good arithmetic" from overpromising at all costs. It should not surprise us, though, that those whose living standards have suffered most from stagnant growth are more inclined to believe politicians promising change.

It was only by rejecting classical economics that Franklin Roosevelt was able to save the American economy and bring about a revolution in social policy. And only by rejecting the new classical economics and the policy of so-called responsible elite economists can Clinton meet our current economic crisis.

John Maynard Keynes showed how active government policy can raise employment and output; his followers, including Joan Robinson and Nicholas Kaldor, showed how full employment encourages further investments and leads businesses to find ways to raise labor productivity to match increasing product demand. New Deal American economists, such as Rexford Tugwell and John Maurice Clark, showed how active government policy can raise growth rates with investments in infrastructure, in public services, in human capital development, and in research and development. By listening to these ideas, economists associated with liberal American politics helped produce 25 years of relatively rapid and egalitarian growth after World War II. Abandoning these ideas, we have suffered 30 years of relatively slow growth and rising inequality, culminating in the current Lesser Depression.

The debate over my little report showed how mainstream economics has left us with a smugly certain macroeconomics lacking in imagination, and offering no effective policies to move beyond economic stagnation and escalating inequality. If these economists cannot do better, then we risk more than personal disappointment; we gamble our liberal political economy against the likes of Donald Trump and Ted Cruz. Hillary Clinton can do better. And Americans deserve better.

James Levy , May 19, 2016 at 6:31 am

A very bold thing for a man like this to say. I know he will be criticized (vilified?) for his misplaced belief that Clinton can "do better", but considering who this man is and where he is coming from, condemning him at this stage of the game would be churlish. He's taken on The Bigs and the stifling orthodoxy they embody and for that we owe him.

I had dinner last night with two excellent people who happen to be doing well at this time. They could not comprehend why anyone would be voting for Trump, whom they saw as a dangerous lunatic. They have supported Sanders and voted for him in the NY primary, but are absolutely going to vote for Clinton in the Fall. What I view as the credible case against Clinton has not reached them with any strength or registered at all. I was asked (because I had said nothing while they talked–I hate this kind of confrontation) what problem people could have with Hillary? I said: Libya, Ukraine, and Nicaragua. They really didn't know what I was talking about and although I spoke up for why I thought this made her a neocon like the ones that surrounded Dubya, they simply didn't know any of the details and we left it at that.

so , May 19, 2016 at 7:10 am

Sad. There is them and there are us. Empathy. Hard to have when your busy all the time.

jsn , May 19, 2016 at 7:16 am

I've had many similar recent encounters. I find that if I ask for a positive reason to vote Clinton, the first three or four reasons they raise can be dismissed by single phrase references to past betrayals, Sister Solja, End of Welfare, Nafta etc. and the next few by scandals, Lewensky or what should be scandals as you mentioned. As a rule after four or five tries I get to watch them self censor before each subsequent try and don't have to make any negative claims myself.

I doubt I've changed minds, but they no longer doubt mine.

Torsten , May 19, 2016 at 7:54 am

I would have first pointed to Honduras. And Haiti:

https://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/post-partisan/wp/2016/03/10/hillary-clinton-needs-to-answer-for-her-actions-in-honduras-and-haiti/

What did she do in Nicaragua?

hemeantwell , May 19, 2016 at 8:01 am

I think that was a slip, but an historically correct one I can completely sympathize with.

HRC's recap of Reaganite Latin America policy is her most vile achievement. If anything demonstrates a continuity of imperialist strategy across administrations, that's it.

bowserhead , May 19, 2016 at 8:46 am

" I said: Libya, Ukraine, and Nicaragua. They really didn't know what I was talking about and although I spoke up for why I thought this made her a neocon like the ones that surrounded Dubya, they simply didn't know any of the details and we left it at that."

I run into this all the time. Utter and complete foreign policy illiteracy, particularly from otherwise politically correct millennials who know so little that Hillary gets a complete pass.

Norb , May 19, 2016 at 9:01 am

This is a common story and illustrates that our current detachment from the world around us and our fellow citizens is coming to an end. We are being forced out of our individual bubbles. Modern corporations have supplied the populations of the world with abundance of goods, but in order to accomplish this feat, have destroyed and are destroying the cultural glue, if you will, that holds society together.

TINA will be maintained by propaganda and physical force. We see that the propaganda is starting to weaken because the contradictions of the message can no longer be hidden. The destruction is too widespread and the inequality can no longer be hidden. You can hollow out a social system only so much before it collapses. The collapses we are witnessing is the promise of democracy. A collapse of the ideals of moderation and compromise.

We are entering a phase of civil war. It is still carried out in a polite manner and intellectually, the discussion is still couched in Orwellian doublespeak. However, criticisms of the ruling elite are becoming more straightforward and more people are waking up to the fact that the system is rigged against them.

This civil war is a battle over leadership. It is a battle to demand good government instead of no government. It is a battle to demand a government for and by the people. A battle for the common good. Evaluated not in some abstract terms like "trickle down" economics, but direct support and action. The hearts and minds of the population was won over long ago to wholeheartedly support capitalism and private ownership of the world's resources. This is proving to be a disaster.

Supporters of unfettered capitalism know only one way. Privatization of ALL the worlds resources and potential. They showed their hand in 2008 with the bailouts and implementation of austerity policies. In their minds, there is no turning back. To compromise means failure. For them, TINA is real and logical. This is the perspective of owners of capital. They gain strength and advantage from seeming to compromise, but in the end know they can always reverse course and regain private control. Subterfuge and force allows the resilience of capitalism as the reigning social order.

I bring up the notion of a civil war because these ideas are too important to be left to chance. In America, the citizenry has been complacent with their lot in life and so have lost control over their fate. As the world changes around them, they desperately attempt to hold onto their position while not realizing they are supporting their own impoverishment. Speaking ideas of the common good -for ALL- and notions of public ownership of land, natural resources, citizens natural rights to jobs, basic income, and healthcare divide family and friends. Those who are comfortable don't want to cause trouble and those feeling the pressures brought down upon them by an unrelenting system are too weak and fearful to act.

In a sense, the revolution has already begun. It is the revolution to convince people that there is a better and different way to live our lives.

John Wright , May 19, 2016 at 10:11 am

Jonathan Haidt is a psychologist, sometimes featured in the New York Times, who apparently believes the capability of people to be convinced by reasoned argument is not strong. From my limited reading of his work, he suggests that humans are instinctive beings who, when they have strong beliefs, their reasoning powers are used to justify these beliefs, not to cast doubt about these beliefs.

This can explain why attempting to convince someone to change their political/religious beliefs is fated to be largely futile.

For example, I believe HRC is little more than a well-connected and well traveled mediocrity, with a record of few positives and many egregious negatives that justifies this assessment. I view her as potentially more damaging to the USA, as President, than Trump.

Per Haidt, maybe my beliefs are instinctive and I am willfully blind to all of Clinton's accomplishments over the last 40 years.

human , May 19, 2016 at 10:48 am

ROTFLMAO

david s , May 19, 2016 at 6:51 am

I think that if there are to be any Keynesian big ideas and projects that will help lift us out of this stagnation, they will much more likely come from a Trump Administration than a Clinton one.

jgordon , May 19, 2016 at 7:47 am

Successful big ideas and big projects require cheap abundant energy, resources and intelligent design. It'll be mighty funny when the Keynesians finally implement their plan to overhaul the national highway infrastructure, creating tons of high paying jobs and speeding up the economy–right when our access to cheap oil collapses. That's dumb design at its finest, yet this sort of thing is almost certainly the best that the lobotomized Keynesian planners will be able to think up and do.

A truly innovative program to get the economy moving in a positive direction would be to outlaw personal vehicles and rebuild the nation's railway network. But this society isn't even anywhere close to having something so useful on its agenda. So we'll do some Keynesian program, funnel the few remaining resources we have left down into some stupid dead end rathole, and then in a couple of years we'll be envious here in America of the extravagant lifestyles that the Mexicans are leading. Hell Trump's wall will be a lot more useful keeping the Mexicans in who are trying to flee. That is the end result of Keynesian programs in a delusional society with bass-ackward priorities. Way more harm than good.

fresno dan , May 19, 2016 at 10:11 am

I share your antipathy toward freeways. I remember the big Freeway they built in Fresno when I was a child, destroying hundreds, if not thousands of modest homes (we had to move from a grand rental to a dilapidated house that cost more – were the landlords behind getting rid of a surplus of houses????) – to save maybe – maybe at the most 3 minutes in transit time over driving an existing surface street. Jobs were part of the rationale.

I have been gone 20 years, and they had gone on a real freeway building tear while I was gone. The whole city crisscrossed with freeways laid out as if someone had thrown a bowl of spaghetti on a map – apparently so every neighborhood can enjoy the sound of traffic.

Really, Fresno is just not that physically big to justify all these freeways. And with its high unemployment and no real "center" there aren't any places with traffic congestion anyway – but you get these dubious justifications that millions of dollars are wasted because an implausible auto trip is 4 minutes longer without the freeway….

david s , May 19, 2016 at 6:55 am

There seems to be a developing narrative that the Obama Administration has just been brimming with big ideas that have been thwarted by evil Republicans.

I don't remember it this way. I do remember an Obama Administration that turned to austerity shortly after the 2009 stimulus, and one that has been patting itself on the back all along about what a great job it has done.

"All across America, families are tightening their belts and making hard choices. Now, Washington must show that same sense of responsibility."
President Obama, April 2009(!)

Akronite , May 19, 2016 at 7:56 am

Now that the pictures we snapped of Obama are finally beginning to develop, where we thought we had photographed his lush jungle, we're now seeing just a single thin sapling planted for "the future." And Clinton will soon have a picture of her snapped at this sad tree, with her big lying smile.

hemeantwell , May 19, 2016 at 8:09 am

I don't think Friedman is saying this, unless Rex Tugwell has been secretly disinterred and is serving under Obama. The capitalist ideological counteroffensive that got going in the 70s has been hegemonically successful. Friedman doesn't acknowledge that enough, he instead focuses on what sounds more like disciplinary politics.

flora , May 19, 2016 at 8:22 am

Great post. Thanks.

JLCG , May 19, 2016 at 8:26 am

This type of article or perhaps, all articles about the Economy, deal with the Economy as a substance to which people are appended as accidents. The economy is the sum total of the effort of the people and if the people think that enjoying this very present is preferable to an effort to build a future nothing can be done about it. It is the mind of the people that has to be changed. Wars are very good mechanisms for that.

Carla , May 19, 2016 at 9:14 am

I can't remember if I got this link from an NC comment, or elsewhere. In any case, it's a scary read: "The 14 Defining Characteristics of Facism," augmented by a selection from "They Thought They Were Free." http://rense.com/general37/fascism.htm

Brings Obama and HRC to mind just as much as Trump, if not more.

sinbad66 , May 19, 2016 at 10:05 am

Read "Democracy, Incorporated" by Sheldon Wolin: http://www.amazon.com/Democracy-Incorporated-Managed-Inverted-Totalitarianism/dp/069114589X/ref=sr_1_1?ie=UTF8&qid=1463666525&sr=8-1&keywords=democracy+incorporated

Explains it all….

fresno dan , May 19, 2016 at 9:57 am

"The ferocious reaction to my assessment that Senator Bernie Sanders' economic and health care proposals could create long-term economic growth shows how mainstream economists who view themselves as politically liberal in America have abandoned progressive politics to embrace a political economy of despair."
==========================

Here is the problem: "a political economy of despair" – accepting that economists are a real objective academic discipline is a BIG mistake – the idea that these technocrats, who never seem to recognize how much fraud, rent seeking, and capture of the political system
((because the people paying them don't WANT THEM TO)),
decides things like how much inequality there is, which than decides how much demand there is, and NOT knowing, and apparently NOT WANTING TO KNOW, that it is a POLITICAL economy, and politics decides how resources are often allocated.
We can have single payer heath care if we choose it and free college education (it wasn't all that long ago that I went to a CA college essentially for free). HOW is it college used to be free when GDP was less than 1/6 of what it is now??????
It just doesn't make sense that we used to be able to afford free college and we can't now. It is a POLITICAL decision – when Krugman says Sanders plan is "too expensive" Krugman is making a political decision – not some objective scientific assessment. And if he is not even smart enough to ponder why it used to be free and it is not free now – well, theres your problem right there!

Punxsutawney , May 19, 2016 at 10:22 am

Nice to see this article. When I talk about economics, most people who know anything, only know what someone on TV tells them, so they often question, well who agrees with you? Nice to have another name to list.

And then…

"Sorry, nothing more can be done for you." TINA.

Of course for those at the tippy-top, "How can I help you today?"

[May 20, 2016] Economic Models Must Account for Power Relationships

economistsview.typepad.com
I have a new column:
Economic Models Must Account for Who Has the Power'' : Nobel Prize winning economist Joseph Stiglitz recently highlighted two schools of thought on how income is distributed to different groups of people in the economy. Which school is correct has important implications for our understanding of the forces that have caused the rise in inequality, and for the policies needed to reverse this trend. It also relates to another controversy that has flamed up recently, how economics should be taught in principles of economics courses. ...

Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 06:09 AM in Economics , Market Failure | Permalink Comments (22)


Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post. anne : , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 06:27 AM
Excellent approach, incisive writing.
kthomas -> anne... , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 10:55 AM
Im suprised you are so enamoured of Stiglitz. He does not put up with BS.

Still, you are right. As usual.

DrDick : , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 06:50 AM
Awesome. Thanks for this.
Adamski : , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 07:22 AM
Good one from the Stig, also.

And according to Sraffa's side in the Cambridge capital controversy labour and capital do not receive their marginal products, which leaves the distribution of income to some extent socially or politically determined.

Now please make a donation to Project Syndicate, and check out Robert Skidelsky at the same site.

New Deal democrat : , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 08:21 AM
Excellent. It will be taught in graduate school, long after the little ones have been indoctrinated in reactionary thought be Econ 101.

P.S. The school of thought that accepts inequality as a Teh Awesome result of merit cannot explain why inherited wealth should be allowed to accumulate - another aspect of how power writes the economic rules.

pgl -> New Deal democrat... , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 09:33 AM
"It will be taught in graduate school, long after the little ones have been indoctrinated in reactionary thought be Econ 101."

Joan Robinson's writing on market power was required reading when I was in graduate school. My undergrad profs touched on this issue but not as much. I wonder if Greg Mankiw teaches market imperfections to his undergrad students at Harvard.

two beers -> pgl... , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 09:42 AM
"I wonder if Greg Mankiw teaches market imperfections to his "undergrad students at Harvard."

According to theoclassical doctrine, all market imperfections are the result of gummint innerference. Left to themselves, markets hum with music of the perfect spheres.

pgl -> two beers... , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 11:52 AM
"theoclassical doctrine". My new favorite term. Excellent and thanks.
RC AKA Darryl, Ron : , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 08:25 AM
We are way past just one or the other of those explanations being true. Opportunities come in many forms, but just not for many people. Competition becomes limited in the womb and then they go from there. Better schools across all zip codes and public day care with universal pre-K would be a start. Even that is doomed to the catch-22 of making a better informed public requires a better informed public to demand being better informed. Down east they say "You can't get thar from here."

I was fortunate enough to grow up in Prince William County VA in the late sixties just as it was beginning to boom from growth proximate to the DC Beltway. We had a new and progressive school system even relative to NoVA. Still by the 7th grade it was evident to me that the pedagogy related to reality in dogmatic POVs that were only relevant to the next generation of yuppie kids that had gotten a half step advantage in some various way from their parents.

My half step came from an unusual source though. My dad was illiterate and my mom only finished the 8th grade, but they were stoics with exceedingly powerful work ethics transferred more by their example of excellence in every menial thing that they did rather than by belittling and cajoling me. My dad was the best hunter, the most successful fisherman, grew the most beautiful and bountiful garden, and was self-sufficient in caring for his car and home. His position with the state highway department was limited by his illiteracy to maintenance superintendent, but due to his ability he still got to supervise the construction of roads and bridges without the benefit of commensurate pay.

My mom was the best cook, kept the cleanest house, and as at home day care for a few friends was the best a dealing with troubled children from potty training to outbursts of anger. It was a tough act to follow. Furthermore it did not fit the status quo mold that public schools were designed to reinforce. My half step freed me to reject the intellectual authority of my instructors even though their administrative authority was still sacrosanct in my home. I did well in school and even better on tests eking by to enter the Honor Society and passing the SAT test well enough to qualify for Mensa, but I dropped out of college first semester mostly just to relocate away from home to find a job in the city. So, I got drafted and went to Viet Name, but was lucky enough to survive and develop a successful career in IT systems management large systems capacity planning and performance management. The best break that I got was being laid off in June 2015 with a severance package good enough to afford me a retirement income equal after the change in expenses from leaving the professional world behind to what I had been making while working.

The moral to my story is that one can despise our education system and still do very well by themselves with it. One can reject our higher education and still do very well by themselves without it. One can despise our corporate "meritocracy" system and still have a successful career and maybe even a comfortable retirement, but the ladder has been raised for the latter. How anyone can be successful in school and/or in career without recognizing their own half step advantage or recognizing the intellectually and morally vacant institutions that they traversed in their journey is deeply puzzling to me.

RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 08:35 AM
P.S. I had the good fortune to relocate from Prince William County to Orange County VA in summer 1966 before my senior year in high school when my dad cashed out his state retirement fund saving to start an electric motor/ john boat livery and concession stand at Lake Orange, a VA Game and Fisheries Commission state fishing lake.
The high school teachers were probably just as intelligent as in Manassas Park, but far more socially challenged at least in the academic curriculum. Still, the kids with that half step from their successful parents did well enough to attend decent colleges, but academic performance overall was much lower than it had been in Manassas Park back in Prince William County. The kids in Orange with really successful parents all attended private prep schools.
RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 08:47 AM
P.P.S. Relative to the thread topic then we have a fairly rigid establishment that favors the haves and keeps the have-nots at bay. Monopoly rents are just one of the luxurious rent extracting tools of an aristocracy of social exclusion. Bankers, proto-industrialists, and slave owners established the meme of republicanism as the conservative power that protects us all from tyranny of the majority, but perhaps a little too well. More importantly they established the US Constitution as a nearly inviolable foundation for preserving their world view of well-deserved elite privilege. And they did it all in the name of democracy while showing Thomas Paine the door.
anne -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 08:54 AM
Interesting and really nicely described.
RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> anne... , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 10:06 AM
It's a cool rainy day in central VA. Being retired and primarily a person of outdoor interests then today I have an abundance of time to waste. And commenting on the EV blog sure beats a colonoscopy, which is what I will be getting this time next week :<)

TMI? Yeah, tell me about it.

BigBozat -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron... , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 12:00 PM
"Down east they say "You can't get thar from here."

Actually, they say "Ya cain't get thay-uh frum he-yah." And they usually pre-pend a big, fullsome "Ayuh".

RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> BigBozat... , Thursday, May 19, 2016 at 05:09 AM
THANKS! In any case, they are often correct :<)
Dan Kervick : , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 08:50 AM
Jonathan Nitzan and Shimshon Bichler have developed an account of capitalism over sever years summarized by the slogan "Capital as Power."

http://www.capitalaspower.com/

two beers : , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 09:58 AM
There is no Nobel Prize in economics.
JohnH : , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 10:16 AM
John Kenneth Galbraith used to write about countervailing power. Unfortunately Galbraith has been pretty much consigned to the dustbin. Even when he was writing, economics courses did not talk about his ideas much...I guess he did not use enough math symbols.

Business has long understood the concept of what I'll call leverage points...critical intellectual property, experience, and know how. Control of these critical factors is a key to pricing power and profitability. As one example, Symbol Technologies dominated the handheld bar code scanner market for years, not because they had superior technology or marketing, but because they held the patent on the trigger, which was critical to activating the scanner for reading. Their market power affected not only competitors but suppliers and customers as well.

Leverage points like this are commonplace in business today. Yet I'm not aware that economics, with its orientation towards competitive markets, has ever tried to model this common behavior or even dealt with it.

Likewise, businesses have also understood the importance of market and marketing channel domination to their long term survival and profitability. Firms who fail to dominate must specialize. These concepts are considered elementary in business schools. Yet I don't know that economists have ever managed (or even tried) to incorporate them into their models.

It might help if more economists took business courses to understand how the game is played...

Denis Drew : , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 11:16 AM
Re-organize labor -- make union busting a MARKET WARPING (not job firing) felony ...

... re-make America into one big Costco.

Longtooth : , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 12:36 PM
I still say that until economists can reach consensus on the objective of an economy, they remain divided on the objective. Simply defining it as "for the general good" is a cop-out --- and economists and everybody else know this full well. Define what "general good means"....then see if consensus can be reached. I seriously conclude this cannot be done, since only by compromises can they reach consensus, and this means defining the objective in subjective, vague terms... just like "the general good" is vague and subjective.

The cop-out used by economists is at the heart of what Thomas' blog subject is about: Policy makers .. i.e. gov't decides the objectives of an economy, which is to say that economic power defines it. And of course economic power will define it to maintain and extend their economic power.... and at the very least to minimize any erosion thereof.

So one must wonder how, if gov't is controlled by economic power, that gov't will NOT insure the maintenance and extension of that economic power? Is it possible in a democracy defined by the U.S. constitution to significantly reduce the economic power of those who have it? The constitution in fact makes it impossible.

Even when congress occasionally finds a large enough majority to make law to erode or reduce economic power in gov't, the constitution enables 5 people in robes to deem it unconstitutional OR the next congress, or the next will make law that erode or reduce the effect of prior congress's law(s) that reduced or eroded economic power.

If this were not the case we'd long since have had universal single payer health care, strong labor unions, tax policies that don't give unearned income a huge break, and don't give offshore income an out by not taxing it until its "repatriated", welfare systems that don't keep people in poverty, and an educational system that provide free & equal education to all (not one that gives communities, county's, and States with the highest incomes & property values the best education and everybody else with a lesser one.

Nor, will I add would it be possible to rape the nation's environment by contaminating the nation's rivers, soils, and the air with green-house gases .. not just "paying" fines after the fact for doing so or putting low cost "caps" on green-house gas emissions.

So what does "the general good" actually mean? Economists can't agree on it, nor the means of achieving it of course nor can policy makers.... and this is the fundamental problem not being addressed.

Denis Drew : , Tuesday, May 17, 2016 at 02:32 PM
Make America one big Costco -- re-unionize.
Chris G : , -1
Nice column.

One comment: You wrote "...individuals are rewarded according to their contributions to the economic well being of society. Those who contribute the most to the production of the goods and services we all enjoy receive the highest rewards and climb to the top of the income distribution." I would add that having power includes being able to dictate that rewards are allotted according to economic contributions as opposed to other contributions. Cue my go-to Chris Lasch quote: "... individuals cannot learn to speak for themselves at all, much less come to an intelligent understanding of their happiness and well-being, in a world in which there are no values except those of the market.... the market tends to universalize itself. It does not easily coexist with institutions that operate according to principles that are antithetical to itself: schools and universities, newspapers and magazines, charities, families. Sooner or later the market tends to absorb them all. It puts an almost irresistible pressure on every activity to justify itself in the only terms it recognizes: to become a business proposition, to pay its own way, to show black ink on the bottom line. It turns news into entertainment, scholarship into professional careerism, social work into the scientific management of poverty. Inexorably it remodels every institution in its own image."

[Apr 29, 2016] A Conversation With Joseph Stiglitz

Notable quotes:
"... Alternative theories would have led to very different policies. For instance, the tax cut in 2001 and 2003 under President Bush. Economists that are very widely respected were cutting taxes at the top, increasing inequality in our society when what we needed was just the opposite. Most of the models used by economists ignored inequality. They pretended that macroeconomy was unaffected by inequality. I think that was totally wrong. The strange thing about the economics profession over the last 35 year is that there has been two strands: One very strongly focusing on the limitations of the market, and then another saying how wonderful markets were. Unfortunately too much attention was being paid to that second strand. ..."
"... ditto...everyone from Tyler Cohen to Mark Perry of the AEI does daily posts about the markets working for everything...a daily "Market Failure in Everything" would provide a useful alternative to that point of view... ..."
"... Nobel-prize winner Joseph Stiglitz said monetary policies have exacerbated inequality and need to be redirected to better target getting money flowing into economies and helping small and medium-size businesses. ..."
"... policies such as quantitative easing were a "version of trickle-down economics" and the subsequent increase in asset prices only affected the wealthiest in society ..."
"... "The key problem is the access of credit to small and medium-size enterprises, is getting that flow of money into the real economy," Stiglitz said. It's "nice to have a stock market bubble if you have a lot of stock. But if you are in the bottom 80 percent of America, you have a little stock and you can feel a little good about the stock going up. But let's face it, the overwhelming bulk of our stock market is owned by the 1 percent." ..."
"... Oh my god. He lumps in Bernanke with Greenspan. What are the Fed worshippers going to do now? Their deity is under attack from Stiglitz. Of course it is nothing but fact that bernanke denied that bubbles in real estate were possible OR that a bubble could become s problem for the economy. Hats off to Stiglitz. ..."
"... How much more evidence do we need that the current trickle down monetary policy has failed? "The weak growth for the quarter puts this recovery even further behind any prior recovery at the same stage. After eight and a quarter years, the economy is only 10.1 percent larger than its pre-recession level of output. A more typical recovery would have seen at least twice as much growth." ..."
April 28, 2016 | economistsview.typepad.com
From an interview of Joe Stiglitz :
...White: ... To what extent do you feel economist and economic theory is culpable for the crisis? What is the role of an economist going forward?
Stiglitz: The prevalent ideology-when I say prevalent it's not all economists- held that markets were basically efficient, that they were stable. You had people like Greenspan and Bernanke saying things like "markets don't generate bubbles." They had precise models that were precisely wrong and gave them confidence in theories that led to the policies that were responsible for the crisis, and responsible for the growth in inequality. Alternative theories would have led to very different policies. For instance, the tax cut in 2001 and 2003 under President Bush. Economists that are very widely respected were cutting taxes at the top, increasing inequality in our society when what we needed was just the opposite. Most of the models used by economists ignored inequality. They pretended that macroeconomy was unaffected by inequality. I think that was totally wrong. The strange thing about the economics profession over the last 35 year is that there has been two strands: One very strongly focusing on the limitations of the market, and then another saying how wonderful markets were. Unfortunately too much attention was being paid to that second strand.
What can we do about it? We've had this very strong strand that is focused on the limitations and market imperfections. A very large fraction of the younger people, this is what they want to work on. It's very hard to persuade a young person who has seen the Great Recession, who has seen all the problems with inequality, to tell them inequality is not important and that markets are always efficient. They'd think you're crazy. ...

When I first started blogging, I used to do posts with the title "Market Failure in Everything." as a counter to "the prevalent ideology." Maybe I should revive something similar.

teve Bannister : , Thursday, April 28, 2016 at 07:03 AM

Agreed.
rjs -> Steve Bannister... , Thursday, April 28, 2016 at 02:14 PM
ditto...everyone from Tyler Cohen to Mark Perry of the AEI does daily posts about the markets working for everything...a daily "Market Failure in Everything" would provide a useful alternative to that point of view...
Paul Mathis, Thursday, April 28, 2016 at 07:11 AM
Nothing about Ricardian Equivalence or RBC fallacies.

While inequality is certainly important for consumption demand, PCE has not been a significant problem in the recovery. OTOH, reduction of the federal budget deficit explains virtually all of the deficient demand we have experienced. Obama and the Dems bought into RE and are paying the price now.

JohnH, Thursday, April 28, 2016 at 07:31 AM
Another interview with Stiglitz:

"Nobel-prize winner Joseph Stiglitz said monetary policies have exacerbated inequality and need to be redirected to better target getting money flowing into economies and helping small and medium-size businesses.

In a Bloomberg Television interview Tuesday with Francine Lacqua and Michael McKee in New York, he said policies such as quantitative easing were a "version of trickle-down economics" and the subsequent increase in asset prices only affected the wealthiest in society.

"The key problem is the access of credit to small and medium-size enterprises, is getting that flow of money into the real economy," Stiglitz said. It's "nice to have a stock market bubble if you have a lot of stock. But if you are in the bottom 80 percent of America, you have a little stock and you can feel a little good about the stock going up. But let's face it, the overwhelming bulk of our stock market is owned by the 1 percent."

Stiglitz's comments come as some central banks around the world are being forced to delve deeper into their policy tools to help support their economies. As policy makers struggle to find a way out of the economic malaise, some have even raised the idea of helicopter money, which aims to direct cash straight to consumers.

The Columbia University professor, who said the Federal Reserve can do more to "channel" money to small companies and the economy, was also critical of negative rates. This is partly because of their potential impact on lending.

"The dangers of negative interest rates -- if you don't manage it extraordinarily well; some countries are doing it reasonably well, some are not -- is that it actually weakens the banking system," he said. "If it weakens the banking system, the banks are going to provide even less credit. While it might have some effect on financial markets, in terms of what we really should be concerned about, which is the flow of credit to businesses, that's not working."
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-04-26/stiglitz-says-misdirected-monetary-policies-increased-inequality

What's the point of low interest rates, if they only serve the interests of Wall Street banks and their wealthy clientele? Oh, right! That IS the point. And most economists are just fine with that.

BenIsNotYoda, Thursday, April 28, 2016 at 07:59 AM
Oh my god. He lumps in Bernanke with Greenspan. What are the Fed worshippers going to do now? Their deity is under attack from Stiglitz. Of course it is nothing but fact that bernanke denied that bubbles in real estate were possible OR that a bubble could become s problem for the economy. Hats off to Stiglitz.
anne, Thursday, April 28, 2016 at 08:17 AM
http://cepr.net/data-bytes/gdp-bytes/gdp-2016-04

April 28, 2016

Falling Investment and Rising Trade Deficit Lead to Weak First Quarter
By Dean Baker

Health care costs remain well-contained, barely growing as a share of GDP.

GDP grew at just a 0.5 percent annual rate in the first quarter. This weak quarter, combined with the 1.4 percent growth rate in the 4th quarter, gave the weakest two quarter performance since the 3rd and 4th quarters of 2012 when the economy grew at just a 0.3 percent annual rate.

Growth was held down by both a sharp drop in non-residential investment and a further rise in the trade deficit. Equipment investment fell at an 8.6 percent annual rate, while construction investment dropped at a 10.7 percent annual rate. The latter is not a surprise, given the overbuilding in many areas of the country. The drop in equipment investment was undoubtedly in part driven by the worsening trade situation, as many factories curtailed investment plans as U.S.-made products lost out to foreign competition, weakening demand growth. There was also a drop in information processing equipment, indicating that those who are expecting that robots will replace us all will have to wait a bit longer.

The rise in the trade deficit was due to a 2.6 percent drop in exports, as imports were nearly flat for the quarter. Trade subtracted 0.34 percentage points from growth for the quarter.

Consumption continued to grow at a modest 1.9 percent annual rate, adding 1.27 percentage points to growth. Consumption growth was held down in part by weaker demand for new cars, which subtracted 0.33 percentage points from growth for the quarter. This was the second consecutive decline in the sector. It is likely that car purchases will be up somewhat in future quarters.

The savings rate for the quarter was 5.2 percent, which is up slightly from the 5.0 percent from the prior three quarters and the 4.8 percent rates from 2013 and 2014, before people started saving their oil dividends. But seriously, there may be some modest room for this rate to decline, but for the most part consumption growth will depend on income growth going forward.

Health care services added 0.26 percentage points to growth, its smallest contribution since a reported decline in the first quarter of 2014. Spending in the sector remains well contained, growing at just a 3.8 percent annual rate over the last quarter and by 4.4 percent over the last year in nominal spending.

Housing grew at a 14.8 percent annual rate, adding 0.49 percentage points to growth. Housing has being growing at a double digit rate since the fourth quarter of 2014. While the sector is likely to continue to grow in subsequent quarters, the pace is almost certain to slow.

The government sector was a modest positive in the quarter, growing at a 1.2 percent rate. State and local spending increased at a 2.9 percent annual rate, more than offsetting a 1.6 percent drop in federal spending, all of it on the military side. Future quarters are likely to show comparable growth, although the composition may be somewhat different.

A slower rate of inventory accumulation reduced growth by 0.33 percentage points, as final sales of domestic product grew at a 0.9 percent rate. This is the third consecutive quarter in which the pace of inventory accumulation slowed, although the current pace is not especially low. It is likely that inventories will grow somewhat more quickly in the rest of the year, being at least a small positive in the growth story.

The weak growth for the quarter puts this recovery even further behind any prior recovery at the same stage. After eight and a quarter years, the economy is only 10.1 percent larger than its pre-recession level of output. A more typical recovery would have seen at least twice as much growth.

[Graph]

On the whole this is a weak report. The headline 0.5 percent figure probably overstates the weakness somewhat, but it is not a good sign when two consecutive quarters have an average growth rate of less than 1.0 percent. Inflation remains well under control, although there was a modest uptick in the rate of inflation shown by the core personal consumption expenditure deflator to 1.7 percent over the last year. Nonetheless, with an economy barely growing and an inflation rate that remains below target, it is difficult to envision the Federal Reserve raising interest rates further any time soon.

JohnH, Thursday, April 28, 2016 at 08:48 AM
How much more evidence do we need that the current trickle down monetary policy has failed? "The weak growth for the quarter puts this recovery even further behind any prior recovery at the same stage. After eight and a quarter years, the economy is only 10.1 percent larger than its pre-recession level of output. A more typical recovery would have seen at least twice as much growth."
rayward, Thursday, April 28, 2016 at 09:11 AM
Market failures aren't really market failures but market responses to market conditions. They are failures only in the sense that something deemed bad (e.g., falling home prices) is the market response. An extreme example is what's being called secular stagnation, which is just the market response to the shift of an enormous volume of production and income from the U.S. and Europe to China and other like places with much higher levels of inequality and savings. It's a market failure only in the sense that something bad (wage stagnation, slow economic growth) happened in the U.S. and Europe. Those responsible for the shift in production and income to China et al. (i.e., U.S. and European business executives) were either ignorant of the likely market response or didn't care as long as it increased profits (via lower costs). But that's not a market failure, it's an executive failure.
Peter, -1
"I think almost surely both Hillary and Bernie Sanders are very very committed to a pro-equality agenda, and the differences are more in details, more in one's confidence in their ability to execute this in a political context."

Disappointing. I guess we'll find out if he's right. Also his suggestion that the economy would have done just as well with no QEs is very disappointing.

"Stiglitz: I think they were right. They originally said, "When we hit 6 percent that's full employment." Now they know that 4.9 isn't full employment, there's weak labor market. They should have focused more on improving the channel of credit to make sure that money was going to small and medium-sized enterprises They should have said to the bank-like some other countries have done-if you want access to the Fed window you have to be lending to SMEs. "

Which was Bernie's suggestion. Hillary has said nothing.

[Jan 26, 2016] Public Investment: has George Started listening to Economists?

Notable quotes:
"... The case for additional public investment is as strong in the UK (and Germany ) as it is in the US. Yet since 2010 it appeared the government thought otherwise. ..."
"... However since the election George Osborne seems to have had a change of heart. ... ..."
economistsview.typepad.com

Simon Wren-Lewis:

Public investment: has George started listening to economists?: I have in the past wondered just how large the majority among academic economists would be for additional public investment right now.

The economic case for investing when the cost of borrowing is so cheap (particularly when the government can issue 30 year fixed interest debt) is overwhelming. I had guessed the majority would be pretty large just by personal observation. Economists who are not known for their anti-austerity views, like Ken Rogoff, tend to support additional public investment.

Thanks to a piece by Mark Thoma I now have some evidence. His article is actually about ideological bias in economics, and is well worth reading on that account, but it uses results from the ChicagoBooth survey of leading US economists. I have used this survey's results on the impact of fiscal policy before, but they have asked a similar question about public investment. It is
"Because the US has underspent on new projects, maintenance, or both, the federal government has an opportunity to increase average incomes by spending more on roads, railways, bridges and airports."
Not one of the nearly 50 economists surveyed disagreed with this statement. What was interesting was that the economists were under no illusions that the political process in the US would be such that some bad projects would be undertaken as a result (see the follow-up question). Despite this, they still thought increasing investment would raise incomes.
The case for additional public investment is as strong in the UK (and Germany) as it is in the US. Yet since 2010 it appeared the government thought otherwise. ...
However since the election George Osborne seems to have had a change of heart. ...

[Jan 14, 2016] Neoliberalism was also economics departments orthodoxy for decades

Notable quotes:
"... It should never be forgotten that the conservative orthodoxy -- of low taxes on the wealthiest, deregulation of finance, small govt deficits, and the need for inequality to spur individual initiative -- was also economics departments orthodoxy for decades. Economists put their imprimatur on this whole mess, with VERY few exceptions. ..."
"... 70% of the population STILL believes that federal deficits are a big problem, and also believes that this is standard economic orthodoxy. Until the crash, most people were ready to accept some degree of privatization of Social Security, and Martin Feldstein pushed on this repeatedly with no counterargument from the economics departments. The Clinton economic team was instrumental in pushing financial deregulation, upon the supposed orthodoxy that it is good for the economy. Even the worst nonsense in Friedmans Capitalism and Freedom and Free to Choose barely saw any push-back from other economists in the op-ed pages. ..."
"... Reaganomics was approved by most economists either through mood affiliation or intellectual incompetence. That 70% currently includes college graduates who took economics classes and traders on Wall Street. ..."
"... Nonsense. Polls of profession economists opinions abound. Reaganomics/neoliberalism has predominated in economics until recently. On a few big issues (notably, on whether the size of federal deficits as % of GDP should be reduced) the split remained even. ..."
economistsview.typepad.com

Lee A. Arnold :

It should never be forgotten that the "conservative orthodoxy" -- of low taxes on the wealthiest, deregulation of finance, small gov't deficits, and the need for inequality to spur individual initiative -- was also "economics departments orthodoxy" for decades. Economists put their imprimatur on this whole mess, with VERY few exceptions.

It's been a first-rate intellectual scandal, perpetrated by some of the biggest names in the economics racket, and with most of the lesser lights tagging along, for fear of ostracism.

And most of them STILL don't have a clear view of what the real problems are.

Lee A. Arnold -> anne...
70% of the population STILL believes that federal deficits are a big problem, and also believes that this is standard economic orthodoxy. Until the crash, most people were ready to accept some degree of privatization of Social Security, and Martin Feldstein pushed on this repeatedly with no counterargument from the economics departments. The Clinton economic team was instrumental in pushing financial deregulation, upon the supposed orthodoxy that it is good for the economy. Even the worst nonsense in Friedman's "Capitalism and Freedom" and "Free to Choose" barely saw any push-back from other economists in the op-ed pages.

"Conservative orthodoxy" can be laid squarely at the feet of the economics departments, up until the crash. If the ones who are supposed to know better, don't make a concerted effort to refute the tons of nonsense spouted in the name of economics, then they should resign their tenure.

Lee A. Arnold -> pgl...
It most certainly WAS taken as the orthodoxy. Reaganomics was approved by most economists either through mood affiliation or intellectual incompetence. That 70% currently includes college graduates who took economics classes and traders on Wall Street.
pgl -> Lee A. Arnold ...
"Reaganomics was approved by most economists either through mood affiliation or intellectual incompetence."

Not even remotely true. Criticized by liberal economists. Blasted by the conservative economists who refused to work for the Reagan White House. Even blasted by a young Greg Mankiw but that is before he drank the Bush Kool Aid.

Lee - your claim here is just wrong. And the more you defend it, the worse it gets.

Lee A. Arnold -> pgl...
Nonsense. Polls of profession economists' opinions abound. Reaganomics/neoliberalism has predominated in economics until recently. On a few big issues (notably, on whether the size of federal deficits as % of GDP should be reduced) the split remained even.

(1992 -- responses from 464 US economists):

  • "A large federal budget deficit has an adverse effect on the economy" 78.7% agree (includes 'agree with provisos').
  • "The money supply is a more important target that interest rates for monetary policy" 56.7% agree.
  • "As the USSR moves toward a market economy. a rapid and total reform (i.e., "going cold turkey") would result in a better outcome than a slow transition" 57.6% agree.
  • "A minimum wage increases unemployment among young and unskilled workers" 78.9% agree.
  • "An economy in short-run equilibrium at a real GNP below potential GNP has a self-correcting mechanism that will eventually return it to potential GNP" 50.8% agree.
  • "Changes in aggregate demand affect real GNP in the short run but not in the long run" 52.8% agree.
  • "Lower marginal income tax rates reduce leisure and increase work effort" 55.4% agree. (Alston et al., "is there a global economic consensus?" AEA Papers and Proceedings, 1992)

[Jan 06, 2016] Another Slow Year for the Global Economy

Notable quotes:
"... Sometimes … demand is restricted by the fact that nobody has any money in their pocket. ..."
"... the only takeaway is that most economists are nothing more than rancid witch doctors doing backflips to skirt the basic explanation that aggregate demand has been deliberately sabotaged. ..."
"... Modern neoliberal economics is just an ideology not a science. It exists to justify the current distribution of wealth with pseudoscientific nonsense written in abstruse mathematical language. Milton Friedman was to economics what T.D. Lysenko was to Soviet biology. Pseudoscience in service to the ruling class. ..."
"... [Economists are] clueless about the real world because their fat paycheck magically appears in their bank account, while producing nothing. ..."
Jan 06, 2016 | naked capitalism

By Ashoka Mody, Professor of Economics at Princeton. Originally published at Project Syndicate

For starters, world trade is growing at an anemic annual rate of 2%, compared to 8% from 2003 to 2007. Whereas trade growth during those heady years far exceeded that of world GDP, which averaged 4.5%, lately, trade and GDP growth rates have been about the same. Even if GDP growth outstrips growth in trade this year, it will likely amount to no more than 2.7%.

The question is why. According to Christina and David Romer of the University of California, Berkeley, the aftershocks of modern financial crises – that is, since World War II – fade after 2-3 years . The Harvard economists Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff say that it takes five years for a country to dig itself out of a financial crisis. And, indeed, the financial dislocations of 2007-2008 have largely receded. So what accounts for the sluggish economic recovery?

One popular explanation lies in the fuzzy notion of "secular stagnation": long-term depressed demand for goods and services is undermining incentives to invest and hire. But demand would remain weak only if people lacked confidence in the future. The only logical explanation for this enduring lack of confidence, as Northwestern University's Robert Gordon has painstakingly documented and argued , is slow productivity growth.

Before the crisis – and especially from 2003 to 2007 – slow productivity growth was being obscured by an illusory sense of prosperity in much of the world. In some countries – notably, the United States, Spain, and Ireland – rising real-estate prices, speculative construction, and financial risk-taking were mutually reinforcing. At the same time, countries were amplifying one another's growth through trade.

Central to the global boom was China, the rising giant that flooded the world with cheap exports, putting a lid on global inflation. Equally important, China imported a huge volume of commodities, thereby bolstering many African and Latin American economies, and purchased German cars and machines, enabling Europe's largest economy to keep its regional supply chains humming.

This dynamic reversed around March 2008, when the US rescued its fifth-largest investment bank, Bear Sterns, from collapse. With the eurozone banks also deeply implicated in the subprime mortgage mess and desperately short of US dollars, America and much of Europe began a remorseless slide into recession. Whereas in the boom years, world trade had spread the bounty, it was now spreading the malaise. As each country's GDP growth slowed, so did its imports, causing its trading partners' growth to slow as well.

The US economy began to emerge from its recession in the second half of 2009, thanks largely to aggressive monetary policy and steps to stabilize the financial system. Eurozone policymakers, by contrast, rejected monetary stimulus and implemented fiscal austerity measures , while ignoring the deepening distress of their banks. The eurozone thus pushed the world into a second global recession.

Just when that recession seemed to have run its course, emerging economies began to unravel. For years, observers had been touting the governance and growth-enhancing reforms that these countries' leaders had supposedly introduced. In October 2012, the IMF celebrated emerging economies' "resilience." As if on cue, that facade began to crumble, revealing an inconvenient truth: factors like high commodity prices and massive capital inflows had been concealing serious economic weaknesses, while legitimizing a culture of garish inequality and rampant corruption .

These problems are now being compounded by the growth slowdown in China, the fulcrum of global trade. And the worst is yet to come. China's huge industrial overcapacity and property glut needs to be wound down; the hubris driving its global acquisitions must be reined in; and its corruption networks have to be dismantled.

In short, the factors that dragged down the global economy in 2015 will persist – and in some cases even intensify – in the new year. Emerging economies will remain weak. The eurozone, having enjoyed a temporary reprieve from austerity, will be constrained by listless global trade. Rising interest rates on corporate bonds portend slower growth in the US. China's collapsing asset values could trigger financial turbulence. And policymakers are adrift, with little political leverage to stem these trends.

The IMF should stop forecasting renewed growth and issue a warning that the global economy will remain weak and vulnerable unless world leaders act energetically to spur innovation and growth. Such an effort is long overdue.


ArkansasAngie , January 6, 2016 at 6:17 am

"But demand would remain weak only if people lacked confidence in the future"

Sometimes … demand is restricted by the fact that nobody has any money in their pocket.


James Levy, January 6, 2016 at 6:45 am

Is he kidding:

The only logical explanation for this enduring lack of confidence, as Northwestern University's Robert Gordon has painstakingly documented and argued, is slow productivity growth.

Real wages for a hefty percentage of the population haven't risen since 1971. Most people are treading water or losing ground. Over 90% of the modest gains since the 2008 crash have gone to 1% or less of the population. But the problem is productivity! And this guy has a tenured job at Princeton. Standards for employment there must include smug self-assurance, ideological blinders, and the inability to assimilate any facts not cogent to people richer than you are.


Jim Haygood, January 6, 2016 at 11:37 am

If Princeton's most illustrious alumnus can finally make some serious loot in the private sector, soon the author will be toiling at the Bernanke School of Economics.

Skippy, January 6, 2016 at 8:18 am

Productivity is the cocaine of the labour pool, like the old cocaine ad of the 80s in Calif [during the epidemic].

White square room about 6M X 6M, top shelf sale executive sort doing laps like a con and the verse goes like…. I do cocaine because I'm more productive… so I make more money… so I can do more cocaine… over and over and with each litany increases his speed until a blur….

Skippy…. the end is a wrung out wretch sitting on the step of some low socioeconomic apt talking about losing, wife, kids, job, everything…. w burnt out dopamine receptors as a lullaby till morte'

efschumacher, January 6, 2016 at 8:50 am

Here in the US:it's not like there's a shortage of work to be done to fix the massively inappropriate national infrastructure – to make it human sustainable – I mean for the 'little people'. There is of course the perennial lack of congressional vision and long term planning. There lies a huge root of the problem.

RabidGandhi, January 6, 2016 at 9:12 am

Is this meant as a good cop/bad cop contrast piece with the Ann Pettifor post?

Here, I gave up any hope of Mody being at all earnest when he cited Rogoff and Reinhart (!!!). Then the rest of the article completely self-destructs: weak productivity and insufficient innovation are the issue?

When combined with yesterday's NYT article on inequality, the only takeaway is that most economists are nothing more than rancid witch doctors doing backflips to skirt the basic explanation that aggregate demand has been deliberately sabotaged.

Stephen Gardner, January 6, 2016 at 9:33 am

Modern neoliberal economics is just an ideology not a science. It exists to justify the current distribution of wealth with pseudoscientific nonsense written in abstruse mathematical language. Milton Friedman was to economics what T.D. Lysenko was to Soviet biology. Pseudoscience in service to the ruling class.

cnchal, January 6, 2016 at 9:43 am

. . . the only takeaway is that most economists are nothing more than rancid witch doctors doing backflips to skirt the basic explanation that aggregate demand has been deliberately sabotaged.

They are the useless eaters. [Economists are] clueless about the real world because their fat paycheck magically appears in their bank account, while producing nothing.

Here is Mody

The US economy began to emerge from its recession in the second half of 2009, thanks largely to aggressive monetary policy and steps to stabilize the financial system.

Totally clueless.

susan the other, January 6, 2016 at 2:02 pm

"Lack of confidence" – let me count the ways. This is a phrase to match every vacuous denial of human economic chaos ever pontificated. Yuck.

[Jan 01, 2016] Economics Joke Time

Notable quotes:
"... GDP. Great deposits of poo. ..."
"... [The financial crisis is worse than thought …] ..."
"... – Yes Prime Minister, A Real Partnership ..."
"... Economists: purveyors of fictions upon which the superstructure of organized robbery is raised. ..."
"... "Market Failure" is the name that economists who believe that the market cannot ever fail use when the market fails. ..."
"... "Economists put decimal points in their forecasts to show that they have a sense of humour" ..."
"... "Did you ever think that making a speech on economics is a lot like pissing down your leg? It seems hot to you, but it never does to anyone else." ..."
December 30, 2015 | naked capitalism
Posted on by

... ... ...

The Standup Economist has a routine that has become a classic:

And of course, there are the economist variants of the lightbulb joke, originating in a 1994 Wharton Journal, as later recapped in Forbes:

Q: How many economists does it take to change a light bulb?

A1: None. The darkness will cause the light bulb to change by itself.

A2: None. If it really needed changing, market forces would have caused it to happen.

A3: None. If the government would just leave it alone, it would screw itself in.

A4: None. There is no need to change the light bulb. All the conditions for illumination are in place.

A5: None. Because, look! It's getting brighter! It's definitely getting brighter!!!

A6: None. They're all waiting for the unseen hand of the market to correct the lighting disequilibrium.

tony, December 30, 2015 at 6:12 am

Q: What do you call an economist that makes a prediction?

A: Wrong.

ben, December 30, 2015 at 3:28 pm

Two economists are walking on the street. They notice a pile of horseshit, and the older one says to the younger one: "I'll pay you twenty thousand if you eat that." The younger one ponders for a moment, then agrees and eats it. They walk a bit more and run into another pile of horse feces. So the younger one tells the elder: "I'll pay you twenty thousand if you eat that!". The older economist considers the offer and starts eating. After a while the younger economists stops and asks: "What was the point of this? We both ate a pile shit and neither of us got richer." The older one answers: "What are you talking about? We both produced and received twenty thousand worth in income and services."

GDP. Great deposits of poo.

Clive, December 31, 2015 at 5:41 am

"This economy is really terrible."

"How bad is the economy?"

"The economy is so bad, this year oysters are making fake pearls…"

"The economy is so bad, organised crime just laid off 10 judges…"

(and so on)


Paul Jonker-Hoffrén, December 30, 2015 at 7:27 am

"Knock Knock!"

"Who's there?"

"It's Return to Growth!"

Two years later…

"Knock Knock!"

"Who's there?"

"It's Return to Growth!"

And ad finitum…

Clive, December 30, 2015 at 6:21 am

"Knock Knock"

"Who's there?"

"Janet Yellen"

"Well there's no need to shout, I heard you knocking"

Joaquin Closet, December 30, 2015 at 7:42 am

The number of economists is the only thing that contradicts the Law of Supply and Demand.

craazyboy, December 30, 2015 at 9:00 am

Q: How many economists does it take to change a light bulb?

A: Three. A micro-economist to hold the ladder, a macro-economist to rotate the room, and a university economist to develop the math model and forecast how long it will take.

Ulysses, December 30, 2015 at 9:56 am

A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job at an oil company.

The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?" The mathematician replies "Four." The interviewer asks "Four, exactly?" The mathematician looks at the interviewer hard and says "Yes, four, exactly."

Then the interviewer calls in the accountant and asks the same question "What do two plus two equal?" The accountant says "On average, four – give or take ten percent, but on average, four."

Then the interviewer calls in the economist and poses the same question "What do two plus two equal?" The economist gets up, locks the door, closes the shade, sits down next to the interviewer and says, "What do you want it to equal"?

Paul Tioxon, December 30, 2015 at 10:02 am

What do you call a cruise ship sinking with 500 PhD economists chained below deck?

A good start.

allan, December 30, 2015 at 10:03 am

Frederic Mishkin.

Yves Smith, December 30, 2015 at 4:32 pm

Oh, that is good!

Paul

An economist is someone who will tell you tomorrow why what they predicted yesterday didn't happen today.

An economist, a physicist, and an engineer are stranded on an island with a can of food, and no opener.

The engineer says, "Let's smash the can open with a rock and eat".
The physicist replies, "Naw, that's going to splatter the food all over the place. Let's light a fire, the expanding gases will force the can to pop open and presto: warm food!"
The economist says, "Bad idea: the can will explode and the food will be all over the place. Now… let's assume we have a can opener…."

Blue Meme

A physician, an engineer, and an economist were discussing who among them belonged to the oldest profession. The physician said, "Remember, on the sixth day God took a rib from Adam and fashioned Eve, making him the first surgeon. Therefore, medicine is the oldest profession."

The engineer replied, "But, before that, God created the heavens and earth from chaos, thus he was the first engineer. Therefore, engineering is an older profession than medicine."

Then, the economist spoke up. "Yes," he said, "But who do you think created the chaos?"

aj

The First Law of Economists: For every economist, there exists an equal and opposite economist.
The Second Law of Economists: They're both wrong.

fresno dan

Pareto's law of optimal economic theory:
an economic theory has reached an optimal state when no other economist can make it wronger

pat b

The Third Law of Economists : The two economists theories don't add up.

twonine

"Economics is extremely useful as a form of employment for economists."
― John Kenneth Galbraith

gordon

JKG has some excellent one-liners. My favourite:

"The trouble with competition is that in the end somebody wins."

Joe Hill

"Again, since I'm not an economist I really have no idea what the wrong solution is."

~ @RudyHavenstein

Ramanan

[The financial crisis is worse than thought …]

James Hacker: Bernard, Humphrey should have seen this coming and warned me.

Bernard Woolley: I don't think Sir Humphrey understands economics, Prime Minister; he did read Classics, you know.

James Hacker: What about Sir Frank? He's head of the Treasury!

Bernard Woolley: Well I'm afraid he's at an even greater disadvantage in understanding economics: he's an economist.

– Yes Prime Minister, A Real Partnership

JEHR

More economist jokes here: http://www3.nd.edu/~jstiver/jokes.htm

flora

Economists: purveyors of fictions upon which the superstructure of organized robbery is raised.
(apologies to Ambrose Bierce)

Synoia

Q: What do you call an Economist who tells the truth?

A: Unemployed.

Ivy

If you laid all the economists end to end,

it would probably be a good thing.

They still wouldn't reach a conclusion.

ben

A farmer and two bankers are shipwrecked on an island. Two weeks later help finally arrives. The bankers greet their rescuer who remarks how well they look.

BankerA: "we realised the potential of the natural resources on this island were tremendous".

BankerB: "I created some fiat money, we divided it up. I lent BankerA ten times my share for a coconut farm startup, he invested ten times his share in an accountancy startup."

Rescuer: "well that's amazing, only where is it all, I don't see any produce – how did you actually survive?"

BankerA: "We each used our debt to invest in futures given the fertile land it was clear the land could generate wealth once labour was applied. We both realised significant paper profits. Oh and we ate the farmer"

--

Bankers live off our backs.

Nortino

What did the supply curve say to the demand curve?

If you shift a little to the right, I'll give you some more of what you want.

_________

Why did the economist cross the road?

Because his models predicted he would.

TG

"Market Failure" is the name that economists who believe that the market cannot ever fail use when the market fails.

Synoia

Hmm, it seems you should take your own advice to heart. :-)

What is a person called who claims to predict the future and has a history of 100% failure in predictions?

a) A Charlatan
b) An Economist
c) A prophet

afreeman

In the same vein:
econ entropy: money invented from hot air evaporates, what do you expect?

Warren

"Economists put decimal points in their forecasts to show that they have a sense of humour"
- William Gilmore Simms (https://twitter.com/TheBrowser/status/680887672890589184?s=17)

TG

How many economists does it take to screw in a lightbulb?

Only one, but the lightbulb has to be hanging from the ceiling. Because economists can only screw things up.

Minnie Mouse

It takes one economist to change a light bulb and take the entire power grid down.

James McFadden

"Did you ever think that making a speech on economics is a lot like pissing down your leg? It seems hot to you, but it never does to anyone else." Lyndon Johnson

[Dec 30, 2015] On Pareto Optimality

Notable quotes:
"... the ideal markets that would produce Pareto Optimal allocations don't actually exist ..."
"... moving from actually existing non-ideal markets to ideal markets WOULD NOT BE Pareto Optimal even if it was possible to do so, which it isn't. ..."
"... In short, Pareto Optimality is a just so story that has absolutely no bearing on the real world other than as an ideological justification for tons of bullshit. ..."
"... The next step in graduate students' indoctrination is to teach them that although Pareto Optimal reallocations are implausible, you can get around that with a "principle of compensation." The principle, too is based on a same yardstick fallacy. But never mind the Pareto Optimality smokescreen and the compensation smokescreen have constrained economists to think in terms of doing what is best for the wealthiest. Funny how that happens. ..."
Dec 30, 2015 | Economist's View
Sandwichman, December 30, 2015 at 10:06 AM
"Graduate students of economics learn, early in their careers, that markets allocations are Pareto Optimal."

What they don't learn is that

1. the ideal markets that would produce Pareto Optimal allocations don't actually exist and

2. moving from actually existing non-ideal markets to ideal markets WOULD NOT BE Pareto Optimal even if it was possible to do so, which it isn't.

In short, Pareto Optimality is a just so story that has absolutely no bearing on the real world other than as an ideological justification for tons of bullshit.

The next step in graduate students' indoctrination is to teach them that although Pareto Optimal reallocations are implausible, you can get around that with a "principle of compensation." The principle, too is based on a same yardstick fallacy. But never mind the Pareto Optimality smokescreen and the compensation smokescreen have constrained economists to think in terms of doing what is best for the wealthiest. Funny how that happens.

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

Pareto Optimality is a just so story that has absolutely no bearing on the real world other than as an ideological justification for tons of bull----.

[ Agreed completely and I think this an important conclusion. ]

Paine said in reply to anne

Yes

Sandy gets the guts of it

Though

The compensation principle is precisely what Pareto rule is all about

Yes we can scramble the goods all we want so long as in the end everyone is at least as well off as before the scramble

In a pure exchange model this is less exciting then in a one period production model

Going on to an inter temporal model with an infinite horizon gets into real juicy Wonderlands

The academy makes it's living as much by distracting fine minds as training them

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

The next step in graduate students' indoctrination is to teach them that although Pareto Optimal reallocations are implausible, you can get around that with a "principle of compensation." The principle, too is based on a same yardstick fallacy. But never mind the Pareto Optimality smokescreen and the compensation smokescreen have constrained economists to think in terms of doing what is best for the wealthiest....

http://www.nytimes.com/2015/12/30/business/economy/for-the-wealthiest-private-tax-system-saves-them-billions.html

December 29, 2015

Richest in U.S. Shape Private Tax System to Save Billions
By NOAM SCHEIBER and PATRICIA COHEN

The very wealthiest families are able to quietly shape tax policy that will allow them to shield millions, if not billions, of their income using maneuvers available only to several thousand Americans.

anne said in reply to Sandwichman...

Supposing I understand the essay, Roger Farmer is just writing the logical justification to Herbert Spencer's (never Charles Darwin's) "survival of the fittest" rationale that Spencer made wildly popular after Darwin published "On the Origin of Species."

Spencer was the successful ultimate justifier of British "sun-never-setting-on-the-Empire" capitalism. Spencer sold a biological justification, Farmer is selling a logical justification of Empire.

Sandwichman said in reply to anne

No, I think Farmer is dissing Pareto Optimality and using "sunspots" as sarcasm. He seems to do it in a way that opens up space for countless side arguments that leave Pareto Optimality unscathed.

The bottom line is that NO ONE would have ever paid any attention to the not just "weak" but nonsensical concept if it didn't serve the function of justifying and ultimately glorifying great inequalities of wealth and income.
;

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

I understand the argument and I am entirely right:

Roger Farmer is just writing the logical justification to Herbert Spencer's (never Charles Darwin's) "survival of the fittest" rationale that Spencer made wildly popular after Darwin published "On the Origin of Species."

Spencer was the successful ultimate justifier of British "sun-never-setting-on-the-Empire" capitalism. Spencer sold a biological justification, Farmer is selling a logical justification of Empire capitalism.

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

I needed to be sure the argument was as empty morally as I supposed initially, but I supposed correctly. The Roger Farmer essay is an amoral logical justification of imperial capitalism. Plato's "Republic" conceived amorally. ;

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

A mean little essay, carefully subtle and mean.

Paine said in reply to anne

But Anne as sandy points out Roger blows up the use of Pareto by his future generations argument

Those unable to establish their preferences are unaccounted for in the scrum

He uses this to draw a bold distinction between securities markets and fish catch of the day markets

Paine said in reply to Paine

It's not the way I'd make his point

But his distinction is important

Some are impacted that are not participating

Third party effects that can not be resolved even with repeated " games "
Because the players are not yet present

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

Farmer is dissing Pareto Optimality and using "sunspots" as sarcasm. He seems to do it in a way that opens up space for countless side arguments that leave Pareto Optimality unscathed.

The bottom line is that NO ONE would have ever paid any attention to the not just "weak" but nonsensical concept if it didn't serve the function of justifying and ultimately glorifying great inequalities of wealth and income.

[ Agreed completely, but this argument runs with mine. ]

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

Farmer is dissing Pareto Optimality and using "sunspots" as sarcasm. He seems to do it in a way that opens up space for countless side arguments that leave Pareto Optimality unscathed....

[ The issue is that Roger Farmer leaves Pareto Optimality unscathed, and this is an essential point. The essay is beyond the morality of now, but there is no beyond. ]

[Dec 30, 2015] On Pareto Optimality

Notable quotes:
"... the ideal markets that would produce Pareto Optimal allocations dont actually exist ..."
"... moving from actually existing non-ideal markets to ideal markets WOULD NOT BE Pareto Optimal even if it was possible to do so, which it isnt. ..."
"... In short, Pareto Optiimality is a just so story that has absolutely no bearing on the real world other than as an ideological justification for tons of bullshit. ..."
"... The next step in graduate students indoctrination is to teach them that although Pareto Optimal reallocations are implausible, you can get around that with a principle of compensation. The principle, too is based on a same yardstick fallacy. But never mind the Pareto Optimality smokescreen and the compensation smokescreen have constrained economists to think in terms of doing what is best for the wealthiest. Funny how that happens. ..."
Dec 30, 2015 | Economist's View
Sandwichman, December 30, 2015 at 10:06 AM
"Graduate students of economics learn, early in their careers, that markets allocations are Pareto Optimal."

What they don't learn is that

1. the ideal markets that would produce Pareto Optimal allocations don't actually exist and

2. moving from actually existing non-ideal markets to ideal markets WOULD NOT BE Pareto Optimal even if it was possible to do so, which it isn't.

In short, Pareto Optimality is a just so story that has absolutely no bearing on the real world other than as an ideological justification for tons of bullshit.

The next step in graduate students' indoctrination is to teach them that although Pareto Optimal reallocations are implausible, you can get around that with a "principle of compensation." The principle, too is based on a same yardstick fallacy. But never mind the Pareto Optimality smokescreen and the compensation smokescreen have constrained economists to think in terms of doing what is best for the wealthiest. Funny how that happens.

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

Pareto Optimality is a just so story that has absolutely no bearing on the real world other than as an ideological justification for tons of bull----.

[ Agreed completely and I think this an important conclusion. ]

Paine said in reply to anne

Yes

Sandy gets the guts of it

Though

The compensation principle is precisely what Pareto rule is all about

Yes we can scramble the goods all we want so long as in the end everyone is at least as well off as before the scramble

In a pure exchange model this is less exciting then in a one period production model

Going on to an inter temporal model with an infinite horizon gets into real juicy Wonderlands

The academy makes it's living as much by distracting fine minds as training them

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

The next step in graduate students' indoctrination is to teach them that although Pareto Optimal reallocations are implausible, you can get around that with a "principle of compensation." The principle, too is based on a same yardstick fallacy. But never mind the Pareto Optimality smokescreen and the compensation smokescreen have constrained economists to think in terms of doing what is best for the wealthiest....

http://www.nytimes.com/2015/12/30/business/economy/for-the-wealthiest-private-tax-system-saves-them-billions.html

December 29, 2015

Richest in U.S. Shape Private Tax System to Save Billions
By NOAM SCHEIBER and PATRICIA COHEN

The very wealthiest families are able to quietly shape tax policy that will allow them to shield millions, if not billions, of their income using maneuvers available only to several thousand Americans.

anne said in reply to Sandwichman...

Supposing I understand the essay, Roger Farmer is just writing the logical justification to Herbert Spencer's (never Charles Darwin's) "survival of the fittest" rationale that Spencer made wildly popular after Darwin published "On the Origin of Species."

Spencer was the successful ultimate justifier of British "sun-never-setting-on-the-Empire" capitalism. Spencer sold a biological justification, Farmer is selling a logical justification of Empire.

Sandwichman said in reply to anne

No, I think Farmer is dissing Pareto Optimality and using "sunspots" as sarcasm. He seems to do it in a way that opens up space for countless side arguments that leave Pareto Optimality unscathed.

The bottom line is that NO ONE would have ever paid any attention to the not just "weak" but nonsensical concept if it didn't serve the function of justifying and ultimately glorifying great inequalities of wealth and income.
;

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

I understand the argument and I am entirely right:

Roger Farmer is just writing the logical justification to Herbert Spencer's (never Charles Darwin's) "survival of the fittest" rationale that Spencer made wildly popular after Darwin published "On the Origin of Species."

Spencer was the successful ultimate justifier of British "sun-never-setting-on-the-Empire" capitalism. Spencer sold a biological justification, Farmer is selling a logical justification of Empire capitalism.

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

I needed to be sure the argument was as empty morally as I supposed initially, but I supposed correctly. The Roger Farmer essay is an amoral logical justification of imperial capitalism. Plato's "Republic" conceived amorally. ;

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

A mean little essay, carefully subtle and mean.

Paine said in reply to anne

But Anne as sandy points out Roger blows up the use of Pareto by his future generations argument

Those unable to establish their preferences are unaccounted for in the scrum

He uses this to draw a bold distinction between securities markets and fish catch of the day markets

Paine said in reply to Paine

It's not the way I'd make his point

But his distinction is important

Some are impacted that are not participating

Third party effects that can not be resolved even with repeated " games "
Because the players are not yet present

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

Farmer is dissing Pareto Optimality and using "sunspots" as sarcasm. He seems to do it in a way that opens up space for countless side arguments that leave Pareto Optimality unscathed.

The bottom line is that NO ONE would have ever paid any attention to the not just "weak" but nonsensical concept if it didn't serve the function of justifying and ultimately glorifying great inequalities of wealth and income.

[ Agreed completely, but this argument runs with mine. ]

anne said in reply to Sandwichman

Farmer is dissing Pareto Optimality and using "sunspots" as sarcasm. He seems to do it in a way that opens up space for countless side arguments that leave Pareto Optimality unscathed....

[ The issue is that Roger Farmer leaves Pareto Optimality unscathed, and this is an essential point. The essay is beyond the morality of now, but there is no beyond. ]

[Dec 21, 2015] Monetalism is dead but remains of monetarist thinking are still lingering

Notable quotes:
"... Summers is right that bubbles are usually accompanied by some kind of financial euphoria. ..."
"... There will be massive pushback because so many have wasted many years and resources building mathematically elegant but fatally flawed models that do not make accurate predictions on even represent the fundamentals of any economy. ..."
economistsview.typepad.com
Peter K. said in reply to pgl... December 16, 2015 at 10:07 AM
"It seems to me looking at a year when the stock market has gone down a bit, credit spreads have widened substantially and the dollar has been very strong it is hard to say that now is the time to fire a shot across the bow of financial euphoria. Looking especially at emerging markets I would judge that under-confidence and excessive risk aversion are a greater threat over the next several years than some kind of financial euphoria."

Summers is right that bubbles are usually accompanied by some kind of financial euphoria.

... ... ...

Peter K. said in reply to Benedict@Large...

I disagree with your assessment. People (elite?) are talking about unusual solutions because fiscal policy is being blocked politically.

MMT doesn't seem that different from Keynesianism, except proponents have very big chips on their shoulders for some reason.

Right now the Keynesians are arguing that the Fed shouldn't raise rates. Are the MMTers arguing any differently? Or are they merely giving us the blue prints for utopia. Blue prints don't help much if the politics are against you.

Syaloch said in reply to Peter K....

Great question.

If I have two black boxes that always produce exactly the same outputs, does it matter whether their internal mechanisms are different?

Dan Kervick said in reply to Syaloch...
"Or maybe they would be effective because people believe they ought to be effective."

Possibly. I think back in the 80's when monetarism was the super-sexy new view, there were a lot of people who thought inflation was mainly a function of the monetary base, so if the Fed made a big public stink about pumping up the monetary base, that could be counted on the boost inflation expectations, at least in some quarters, and the high expectations would in turn help to boost actual inflation. That doesn't seem to be the case any longer.

Dan Kervick said in reply to pgl...
The heyday of monetarism was the late 70's and early 80's. That's when Friedman's monetary theory of inflation caught the public imagination, and it's the only time the Fed ever attempted (briefly) to target the money supply.

Conservative spear-carrier Niall Ferguson knows how important monetarism was to the neoliberal movement, and how big a deal it was during the Thatcher-Reagan era.

http://www.niallferguson.com/journalism/finance-economics/friedman-is-dead-monetarism-is-dead-but-what-about-inflation

Other references to the heyday of monetarism abound:

http://www.voxeu.org/article/nominal-gdp-targeting-developing-nations

Dan Kervick said in reply to pgl...
The heyday of monetarism was the late 70's and early 80's. That's when Friedman's monetary theory of inflation caught the public imagination, and it's the only time the Fed ever attempted (briefly) to target the money supply.

Conservative spear-carrier Niall Ferguson knows how important monetarism was to the neoliberal movement, and how big a deal it was during the Thatcher-Reagan era.

http://www.niallferguson.com/journalism/finance-economics/friedman-is-dead-monetarism-is-dead-but-what-about-inflation

Other references to the heyday of monetarism abound:

http://www.voxeu.org/article/nominal-gdp-targeting-developing-nations

bakho said... December 16, 2015 at 05:45 AM
Kevin Hoover, The emperor has no clothes!

"Given what we know about representative-agent models…there is not the slightest reason for us to think that the conditions under which they should work are fulfilled. The claim that representative-agent models provide microfundations succeeds only when we steadfastly avoid the fact that representative-agent models are just as aggregative as old-fashioned Keynesian macroeconometric models. They do not solve the problem of aggregation; rather they assume that it can be ignored."

This the reason Macro needs to move into more data driven empirics.

There will be massive pushback because so many have wasted many years and resources building mathematically elegant but fatally flawed models that do not make accurate predictions on even represent the fundamentals of any economy.

Syaloch said... December 16, 2015 at 05:50 AM

The Advantages of Higher Inflation - The New York Times

From the article:

"A critical problem with aiming for higher inflation is how to get from here to there. The Fed has spent enormous effort anchoring people's expectations to 2 percent. Even economists sympathetic to a higher target are wary of what such a shift might do to its credibility.

"'A perfect world, where you could commit to 4 percent and everybody believed it, would be great,' Mr. Mishkin told me. 'We are not in a perfect world. Moving much higher than 2 percent raises the risk that expectations become unanchored.'

"So here is an alternative proposal. If the Fed is too cautious to risk unhinging inflationary expectations, how about just delivering what it has promised? Among economists and investors, the problem with the Fed's 2 percent target is that just about everybody believes it is really a ceiling. That makes it even harder for inflation to rise to that level. The market expects the Fed to act pre-emptively to ensure it never goes over that line - which is what it seems to be doing now.

"If the Fed is not going to aim for higher inflation, the least it could do is re-anchor expectations to the goal it established, allowing inflation to fluctuate above and below a 2 percent average. That alone might help deal with the next economic crisis.

"'We haven't fully tested whether we can deal with this kind of crisis with a 2 percent inflation target,' said David H. Romer of the University of California, Berkeley. 'Central banks have lots of tools. If they say they are willing to keep using them until they get where they want, they can eventually do it.'"

This highlights a confusing aspect of inflation targets. If the Fed simply announces a higher inflation target without taking any other action, have they really done anything? What's more, they not only need to announce the new target, they need to convince markets that they are willing to do whatever it takes to hit that target -- it's all about credibility and re-anchoring expectations. And while engaging in QE to push down longer-term rates might help make that statement more convincing, it doesn't seem to be strictly necessary for the new target to be effective.

Thus inflation targets seem in at least some cases to operate purely through psychological manipulation, as a sort of placebo effect: inflation rises not because the Fed has injected money into the economy today or changed the cost of lending today, but rather because the Fed is able to "trick" markets into believing it will rise in the future.

Peter K. said in reply to Syaloch...

And the reverse is true. The markets are skeptical that the Fed will hit its 2 percent ceiling target any time soon.

Inflation expectations are becoming un-anchored on the downside but nobody cares because .... oil.

Dan Kervick said in reply to Peter K....
I guess we'll all have to wait for Yellen's future memoirs to know the thinking that was going on inside the Fed during 2015. But it's interesting that both Yellen and Stanley Fischer, both formerly held in gigantic respect by the more prominent liberal economists, are now the targets of ire for apparently not seeing eye-to-eye with their opinionated friends on the outside. Despite the fact that BoG members have access to mountains of internal research and policy input that people on the outside can only guess at, the default position of the outsiders is that the insiders have been corrupted by power and fast-talking bankers or something.

Here's my conjecture about what the Fed's thinking is: The Fed recognizes that keeping policy interest rates down at an unprecedentedly low basement level for years on end sends this message to the global economy: the US economy is a sick basket case. It needs the permanent life support of extraordinary monetary policy intervention to be kept from flat-lining.

I think the people who actually work inside the Fed think that is total bunk, and that as they gradually wean the financial sector off of the monetary ventilator, nothing bad is going to happen at all. The patient is going to get up, walk around and breathe normally. And when that happens, it will say, "Wow, maybe I should have tried that earlier!" Business confidence will spurt; people will think, "Hey, I guess we're not in that gloomy post-2008 depression any more!", and the country will get on with its business more cheerfully.

The Fed has had a devil of a time getting back to normal, because despite its best intentions it has inadvertently re-defined a condition of zero rates and excess reserves bleeding from bankers's ears as the new normal, and created an out-of-control public fixation on monetary policy intervention. Fed communications strategies aimed at guiding the market have turned back on them in a reflexive and self-defeating cycle. They got themselves into a terrible pattern for a while where every time there was good economic news, the markets would respond negatively because they interpreted the good news as evidence that the Fed would "taper" - which they regarded as bad news! And if there was bad news, the markets would respond favorably because they saw the bad news as evidence that the fed would "remain aggressive" - which is good news! Obviously that's a pretty pathological cycle to be in: it's a mechanism fro economic self-stultification. Indicating a move toward normalization too suddenly in 2013 caused the irrational "taper tantrum", so they have had to go more slowly this time around with the hand-holding and by building a longer "guidance" runway.

Their chief need now is to push back against the monetary maniacs and hyperventilators who keep trying to convince impressionable business people and consumers that the Fed has somehow been "keeping the economy" afloat, and that when interest rates go up - from 1/4 to 1/2 of a percent! - we're all going to drown. If you have enough ambulance chasers convincing people they are sick and damaged, they will act sick and damaged.

[Dec 15, 2015] Noahpinion Academic B.S. as artificial barriers to entry

Notable quotes:
"... And of course, some folks accuse the economics profession of being a front for laissez-faire ideology. ..."
"... Or an entire field, which labored mightily to understand why they missed the second worse crisis in 80 years, only to discover it was for the same reason they missed the worst crisis 80 years ago. ..."
"... It is that economics matter and the nonsense that dominates the discourse, and therefore policy, affects everyone's life. ..."
"... So console yourself that as bad of writers most economist are, their obscurantism is couched in equations so it's harder for the unschooled to ridicule heir papers. ..."
"... A cynical advantage to the increased use or mathematics and mathiness is that the economics field gets to use university math departments to thin the herd just like the engineering field does. Better still, the filter imposed by requiring calculus, statistics and differential equations is not always anticipated: while prospective engineers take AP Calculus and end up in a class where they already know half the material, prospective economists enter Calculus I and flunk out. ..."
"... General Equilibrium, Rational Expectations, Microfoundations, The parculiar definitions of "Rationality" and "Efficiency", Utility Optimization, etc. are all very ideologically driven, and if you do not conform to these standards, you are not accepted within the discipline. I've been told just how completely unreadable Econ papers are, not even talking about the math component, thanks to all of the Jargon. ..."
noahpinionblog.blogspot.com

Paul Romer complains of "mathiness" in macroeconomics. Paul Pfleiderer talks about "chameleon" models. Ricardo Caballero says macroeconomists encourage the "pretense of knowledge". Everywhere, people complain about economists' fetish for pointless model-making.

And of course, some folks accuse the economics profession of being a front for laissez-faire ideology.

...A commenter points out that, as usual, Feynman did this snark way before I did.

Jammer812 10:00 PM

Does it really matter if its obscurantism or tendentious cant that a certain type of of economist engages in (cough, neo Fisherism, cough), and then declare victory, when another prominent economist spend 70 pages to find out that if everyone can do algebra in their heads, it might, just might possibly be true. So lets assume a can opener.. sorry I mean that people can, when experience teaches us that most people can't calculate a 20% tip.

Or on the other side, we have the economist who knows that because they are now accounting for the financial sector their DSGE model is just going to nail it.

Or how about a Noble committee that gives a prize to one economist, whose work is disproved by another economist who shared the prize.

Or an entire field, which labored mightily to understand why they missed the second worse crisis in 80 years, only to discover it was for the same reason they missed the worst crisis 80 years ago.

The difference between critical urban theory, or litcrit, or pomo philosophy or popomo art theory and economics isn't that it is easier for people to make fun . It is that economics matter and the nonsense that dominates the discourse, and therefore policy, affects everyone's life.

So console yourself that as bad of writers most economist are, their obscurantism is couched in equations so it's harder for the unschooled to ridicule heir papers.

Anonymous 1:56 PM

Presumably, no one here would expect a humanities PhD to determine whether an economic theory paper is accurate or useful. Why should the reverse be true?

There may well be advantages to this "obscure" language, in the same way that Bourbaki-esque notation and abstraction is useful in economics. This is communication between experts; the notion that you should be able to understand it most likely reflects a disrespect for the given field itself.

I don't envy any theorist whose primary tool of communication is verbal, but if I were put in that position, you may well expect a complex vocabulary to accompany complex ideas (or even simple ideas, rigorously stated). There may well be problems in the humanities, but we're not qualified to recognize them.

Graham Peterson 4:52 PM

Agree about cartels, but I don't think they're that schematic or conspiratorial. Professors across disciplines really do believe they are contributing to something beyond themselves, to knowledge or truth, and grabbing territory and raising salaries is just a means toward those altruistic ends.

Raising (or guaranteeing) salaries looks to me like an unintended consequence of what is proudly and loudly intended by economists and professors of humanities -- increasing the rigor of analysis. There is just about nobody who disagrees that increasing the rigor of analysis is a bad thing. But how do we do that? By opening up intellectual competition among disciplines, political ideologies, etc., or by constructing evermore elaborate apprentice programs designed to hone already-existing intellectual traditions *within* disciplines, ideologies, etc.?

I can't really see any qualitative difference between increasing the complexity of grammar using any symbolic system, bourbakian notation in mathematics or latinate phrases in English. What's most dangerous for economics is its disregard for empirical observation outside of econometrics. Econometrics, just like theory itself, becomes a theoretical exercise and is subject to all of the same self referential signaling games as high theory is.

Admiring each other's screw drivers isn't any more empirical than admiring each other's theories of how screws secure materials. The point is to turn some screws.

Yamaneko 11:37 PM

A cynical advantage to the increased use or mathematics and mathiness is that the economics field gets to use university math departments to thin the herd just like the engineering field does. Better still, the filter imposed by requiring calculus, statistics and differential equations is not always anticipated: while prospective engineers take AP Calculus and end up in a class where they already know half the material, prospective economists enter Calculus I and flunk out.

... ... ...

Øystein 6:07 PM

You might be interested to learn that the philosopher Jon Elster has drawn an analogy between "hard and soft obscurantism" (econ and critical theory).

Anonymous 9:38 AM

He devotes the last chapter of his book Explaining Social Behavior to this distinction. The whole book is very much worth a read: http://www.amazon.com/Explaining-Social-Behavior-Bolts-Sciences/dp/0521777445

Kain 7:12 PM

I generally agree with your point, except the part where you don't think of Economics as ideologically driven.

http://blog.supplysideliberal.com/post/128894764282/what-is-indoctrination-and-how-is-it-different

"What is indoctrination and how is it different from regular instruction? Indoctrination, suggests Christina Hoff Summers, is characterized by three features, the major conclusions are assumed beforehand, rather than being open to question in the classroom; the conclusions are presented as part of a "unified set of beliefs" that form a comprehensive worldview; and the system is "closed," committed to interpreting all new data in the light of the theory being affirmed.
Whether this account gives us sufficient conditions for indoctrination, and whether, so defined, all indoctrination is bad college pedagogy, may certainly be debated. According to these criteria, for example, all but the most philosophical and adventurous courses in neoclassical economics will count as indoctrination, since undergraduate students certainly are taught the major conclusions of that field as established truths which they are not to criticize from the perspective of any other theory or worldview; they are taught that these truths form a unitary way of seeing the world; and, especially where microeconomics is concerned, the data of human behavior are presented as seen through the lens of that theory. It is probably good that these conditions obtain at the undergraduate level, where one cannot simultaneously learn the ropes and criticize them–although one might hope that the undergraduate will pick up in other courses, for example courses in moral philosophy, the theoretical apparatus needed to raise critical questions about these foundations."

General Equilibrium, Rational Expectations, Microfoundations, The parculiar definitions of "Rationality" and "Efficiency", Utility Optimization, etc. are all very ideologically driven, and if you do not conform to these standards, you are not accepted within the discipline. I've been told just how completely unreadable Econ papers are, not even talking about the math component, thanks to all of the Jargon.

Might be less politically-motivated, but it doesn't necessarily require a particular political viewpoint to be ideologically-motivated.

Dulimbai 7:48 PM

Yo do understand that this is exactly the point? Thomas Kuhn, which knew something about science, basically said that science requires barriers to entry to get amateurs out.

A good explanation can be found here http://lesswrong.com/lw/lr/evaporative_cooling_of_group_beliefs/

Ghyl Tarvoke 8:29 PM

I think here you are giving too much importance to the gatekeeping/economic aspect of the most vacuous outpourings of Critical Theory. My experience as a history MA is that such academics give so little thought to economics and their economic situation that such thoughts rarely enter their minds. However, it probably has had the effect of reducing the intellectual diversity of many subjects, which in the humanities at least is a major shame and a problem.

My theory is more straightforward and it's simple. Don't underestimate people's, even academics (perhaps especially academics), intellectual laziness and the desire to dress up their priors in language that looks 'intellectual' thus making your priors look smart and those who don't share your priors not so smart. In short the popularity of most of Critical Theory is due to the lazy man's guide to enlightenment, making something look intellectually difficult while not really challenging people at all. After all, it is not as if many of the core beliefs of large parts of critical theory once you remove the verbiage are not widespread among certain elements of society. And those elements are massively over represented among people liking to do a BA in literature or anthropology. Why are such beliefs so popular? Well, that's a different and difficult question.

However, I do feel liking pointing out, as others have already alluded to, critical theory and postmodernism have had their day. It peaked in the 90s and belongs to the era of Seinfeld, Grunge, and Triangulation. Now there is a trend towards another ideology, bland progressivism and the fear of giving anything that looks like a controversial opinion. This, at least, is notable in History (I can't speak for literature, in Anthropology pomo is more prevalent but is certainly declining). Some have justified this as 'empiricism', and perhaps it is a needed reaction to what went before, but it is frequently driven by the same intellectual forces I've described above. The difference between Generation Y and the Boomers perhaps. Either way, the gatekeeping aspect is barely part of it.

Tom Warner 2:00 PM

Seems to me anon you are agreeing with the complaint about academic obscurantism: it's the use of an artificial dialect, which only practitioners would invest in learning how to read, to create a false impression of sophistication. The only oddity is you seem inexplicably proud of your fluency in said dialect.

Anonymous 7:55 PM

"Mathematical theory, of the type economists do, is hard to do..."

Such barriers to entry should be erected so as to keep out the math and physics nerds that have destroyed economics.

[Dec 06, 2015] Beware Economics 101 -- this is a neoclassical junk

Notable quotes:
"... "The problem for early would ­- be neoclassical macroeconomists was that, strictly speaking, there was no microeconomic model of macroeconomics when they began their campaign. So they developed a neoclassical macro model from the foundation of the neoclassical growth model developed by Nobel laureate Robert Solow (Solow 1956) and Trevor Swan (Swan 2002). They interpreted the equilibrium growth path of the economy as being determined by the consumption and leisure preferences of a representative consumer, and explained deviations from equilibrium – which the rest of us know as the business cycle – by unpredictable 'shocks' to technology and consumer preferences. ..."
"... This resulted in a model of the macroeconomy as consisting of a single consumer, who lives for ever, consuming the output of the economy. Which is a single good produced in a single firm, which he owns and in which he is the only employee, which pays him both profits equivalent to the marginal product of capital and a wage equivalent to the marginal product of labor. To which he decides how much labor to supply by solving a utility function that maximizes his utility over an infinite time horizon, which he rationally expects and therefore correctly predicts. ..."
"... Paul Krugman is a quintessential neoclassical economist. Neoclassical economists threw the notion that economics should deal with empirical or factual reality overboard quite some time ago. ..."
"... Economists often invoke a strange argument by Milton Friedman that states that models do not have to have realistic assumptions to be acceptable - giving them license to produce severely defective mathematical representations of reality. ..."
"... Economists as a rule do not deny that their assumptions about human nature are highly unrealistic, but instead claim, following Friedman (1962, 1982), that the absence of realism does not diminish the value of their theory because it "works," in the sense that it generates valid predictions…. ..."
"... Most important, philosophers of science have almost universally rejected Friedman's position (Boland, 1979). It is very widely agreed that the purpose of a theory is to explain. Otherwise, [predictions] are unable to foretell under what conditions they will continue to hold or fail. ..."
"... With the advent of the Great Financial Crisis, which began in 2007 and continues to this day, the neoclassical models did fail. And they failed in the most spectacular way. ..."
"... Nevertheless, for those like Krugman who are in love with orthodox economic theory, when facts don't conform to theory, so much worse for the facts. ..."
"... It should be added that not everyone who rejects the orthodox, neoclassical theory of exogenous money creation and its "available funds" theory of banking, as Keen calls it, believes that debt matters. ..."
"... A very good example of this is the MMT school, which even though it rejects the orthodox theory of money creation, nevertheless discounts the importance of debt, or at least public debt. ..."
"... The distinction between private debt and public debt, however, is not a clear one. We all saw, for instance, the ease with which private debt was converted into public debt in the cases of Ireland and Spain in the wake of the GFC. ..."
"... The piece that VK posted by Keen was essentially a rejection of the macroeconomic theory that was formulated to replace Keynesian theory. ..."
"... The debate between these two economists on the role of banking and specifically the creation of credit is of fundamental importance in understanding the shortcomings of orthodox economic thinking – and why it was so ill-equipped to handle, let alone predict, the crash of 2008. ..."
"... However, because he has such an important platform, it matters more to many monetary economists (including the editor of this series) that he appears to lack a proper understanding of the nature of credit, and the role of banks in the economy. ..."
"... So yes debt is a big problem with a poorly regulated banking industry (financial industry really because of shadow banking). ..."
peakoilbarrel.com
VK, 12/04/2015 at 2:57 pm
Beware Economics 101. The peer review mechanism has horribly failed.

When you read Krugman, this is what he and our central bankers believe.

"The problem for early would ­- be neoclassical macroeconomists was that, strictly speaking, there was no microeconomic model of macroeconomics when they began their campaign. So they developed a neoclassical macro model from the foundation of the neoclassical growth model developed by Nobel laureate Robert Solow (Solow 1956) and Trevor Swan (Swan 2002). They interpreted the equilibrium growth path of the economy as being determined by the consumption and leisure preferences of a representative consumer, and explained deviations from equilibrium – which the rest of us know as the business cycle – by unpredictable 'shocks' to technology and consumer preferences.

This resulted in a model of the macroeconomy as consisting of a single consumer, who lives for ever, consuming the output of the economy. Which is a single good produced in a single firm, which he owns and in which he is the only employee, which pays him both profits equivalent to the marginal product of capital and a wage equivalent to the marginal product of labor. To which he decides how much labor to supply by solving a utility function that maximizes his utility over an infinite time horizon, which he rationally expects and therefore correctly predicts.

The economy would always be in equilibrium except for the impact of unexpected 'technology shocks' that change the firm's productive capabilities (or his consumption preferences) and thus temporarily cause the single capitalist/worker/consumer to alter his working hours.

Any reduction in working hours is a voluntary act, so the representative agent is never involuntarily unemployed, he's just taking more leisure. And there are no banks, no debt, and indeed no money in this model."

Prof. Steve Keen, Debunking Economics.

Dennis Coyne, 12/04/2015 at 6:11 pm
Hi VK,

No this is not what Krugman believes at all. There are some economists that think in these terms, in the US it is primarily in the interior of the country, the economists on the east and west coast, (this includes Krugman and many others) would not think in these terms at all.

Have you ever read anything by Krugman?

VK, 12/05/2015 at 1:41 am
Read Krugman for years. The basic neoclassical models are founded on the representative agent model with the above assumptions as core. Look up the PhD text book on economics – http://www.amazon.com/Microeconomic-Theory-Andreu-Mas-Colell/dp/0195073401

Krugman gives assessments based on the representative agent models, with its no money, no debt, no banks assumptions. Very linear models, no dynamic modeling.

Economic theory and modeling is stuck in the 19th century. Rest of the hard sciences, physics, chemistry, atmospherics moved on with Poincare and later Lorenz to dynamic simulations.

VK, 12/04/2015 at 3:04 pm
To Dennis Coyne, debt levels matter because "loans create deposits" and not vice versa. Bank of England published a paper last year on modern money creation http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/quarterlybulletin/2014/qb14q1prereleasemoneycreation.pdf

The fractional reserve banking model taught in economics is absolutely empirically wrong. Because banks have the power to create credit money, they can issue in excess.

Under the empirically correct credit money creation model, there can be an excessive build up of debt. Hence the more than 250 sovereign and domestic govt debt crises since 1850.

Dennis Coyne, 12/04/2015 at 6:24 pm
Hi VK,

Rune Likvern posted the link and I read the paper. US textbooks through 1990 covered this exactly as in that paper, so it was a good refresher, but not different from what I had learned in the past.

There can be excessive debt and banks can fail due to poor lending practices combined with a severe recession. Nations can also default. The question is how much debt is too much debt. In economics there are different opinions on this question. When I was studying economics the focus was on public debt crowding out private debt when an economy was close to full employment.

Now there seems to be more focus on private debt, which nobody in economics used to worry about.

It may be that the lack of banking regulation and the rise of shadow banking has made this more of a problem, I am out of date on the latest research.

http://www.economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2015/06/public-debt

The article at the link above suggests up to about a 150% debt to GDP ratio is a safe level for public debt.

VK, 12/05/2015 at 1:56 am
U.S. Textbooks don't cover this at all. The assumption that Paul Samuelson used in his seminal undergraduate textbook that millions have studied was the fractional reserve lending model which is empirically false.

The whole of economics is empirically false, it would be a laughing stock if people looked under the hood with its assumptions that are meant to preserve straight line thinking rather than dealing with reality, which is highly non-linear and dynamic.

Private debt wasn't a concern in economics because they assumed away the role of banks to preserve the equilibrium models. Once you incorporate reality into the models, which is what a true science would do, you find that private debt levels matter.

What economists think: Saver lends to borrower. Saver loses purchasing power, borrower gains purchasing power. Purchasing power hasn't changed in the economy. Just a shift

What really happens: Saver puts money in a bank, has access to his money anytime. Borrower wants money, bank issues a credit and writes loan amount as asset. Purchasing power as a whole increases across the economy as both saver and borrower now have money to buy goods and services with.
That's how the economy grows – bank issuance of credit. And it can easily be in excess.

https://unlearningeconomics.wordpress.com/2012/04/03/the-keenkrugman-debate-a-summary/

Jef, 12/05/2015 at 9:12 am
Thanks for hanging in there VK.

I tried to explain this to my father in law who is an attorney specializing in finance and accounting. He simply could not accept it or even wrap his head around it even after reading the Bank of England piece.

It is fraud plain and simple and the cost to humanity in both financial terms and lives lost is huge.

Glenn Stehle, 12/05/2015 at 9:34 am
Paul Krugman is a quintessential neoclassical economist. Neoclassical economists threw the notion that economics should deal with empirical or factual reality overboard quite some time ago.

Perhaps no one was more explicit in articulating this notion that science should discard factual reality than Milton Friedman.

Any number of critics have pointed this out. For instance,

Economists often invoke a strange argument by Milton Friedman that states that models do not have to have realistic assumptions to be acceptable - giving them license to produce severely defective mathematical representations of reality.

–NASSIM NICHOLAS TALEB, The Black Swan

and

Economists as a rule do not deny that their assumptions about human nature are highly unrealistic, but instead claim, following Friedman (1962, 1982), that the absence of realism does not diminish the value of their theory because it "works," in the sense that it generates valid predictions….

Most important, philosophers of science have almost universally rejected Friedman's position (Boland, 1979). It is very widely agreed that the purpose of a theory is to explain. Otherwise, [predictions] are unable to foretell under what conditions they will continue to hold or fail.

AMITAI ETZIONI, The Moral Dimension

With the advent of the Great Financial Crisis, which began in 2007 and continues to this day, the neoclassical models did fail. And they failed in the most spectacular way.

Nevertheless, for those like Krugman who are in love with orthodox economic theory, when facts don't conform to theory, so much worse for the facts.

Glenn Stehle, 12/05/2015 at 9:55 am
It should be added that not everyone who rejects the orthodox, neoclassical theory of exogenous money creation and its "available funds" theory of banking, as Keen calls it, believes that debt matters.

A very good example of this is the MMT school, which even though it rejects the orthodox theory of money creation, nevertheless discounts the importance of debt, or at least public debt.

The distinction between private debt and public debt, however, is not a clear one. We all saw, for instance, the ease with which private debt was converted into public debt in the cases of Ireland and Spain in the wake of the GFC.

Dennis Coyne, 12/05/2015 at 12:38 pm
Hi Glenn,

Krugman does hold relatively mainstream views, but there are significant differences of opinion within economics. Many economists reject Keynesian theory, Krugman does not. The piece that VK posted by Keen was essentially a rejection of the macroeconomic theory that was formulated to replace Keynesian theory. Krugman would make many of the exact same criticisms.

The "debt doesn't matter" theme is carried a little too far, nobody really argues this. The argument is that when the economy is doing poorly due to low aggregate demand (during a severe recession) and monetary policy is not effective because interest rates are near zero (so that the federal funds rate cannot be lowered any further), cutting fiscal deficits is poor public policy.

Perhaps you disagree?

Glenn Stehle, 12/05/2015 at 1:57 pm
Dennis,

Are you unaware of the famous debate between Krugman and Keen, and what it is all about?

Perhaps this article by Ann Pettifor will help:

The debate between these two economists on the role of banking and specifically the creation of credit is of fundamental importance in understanding the shortcomings of orthodox economic thinking – and why it was so ill-equipped to handle, let alone predict, the crash of 2008.

Many rightly applaud Paul Krugman for using his platform at the New York Times to defend further fiscal stimulus in the US–against a hostile political crowd, not to mention the downright opposition of neo-liberal economists –- and we commend him for that.

However, because he has such an important platform, it matters more to many monetary economists (including the editor of this series) that he appears to lack a proper understanding of the nature of credit, and the role of banks in the economy.

https://www.opendemocracy.net/ourkingdom/steve-keen/keen-krugman-debate

I very much recommend reading the entire article, and much more can be found by Googling "Keen vs Krugman debate."

Dennis Coyne, 12/05/2015 at 12:15 pm
Hi Vk,

There are many of us who have studied beyond the introductory level. In my introductory courses, I believe we were taught this correctly, but that was long ago, I know when I instructed the introductory students as a grad student what I was teaching was essentially what I read in the paper you cited. Perhaps the "textbooks" have improved over time, I haven't read an economics textbook for many years.

Have you read any economics papers lately, perhaps there has been more progress than you think. A fundamental problem with economics is that how we understand the workings of the economy can affect the way people behave. People will always try to game the system and this then effects the system. It is a difficult modelling problem not faced by chemists and physicists.

If you solve it you should publish a paper.

Dennis Coyne, 12/05/2015 at 1:41 pm
Hi VK,

You said:

What economists think: Saver lends to borrower. Saver loses purchasing power, borrower gains purchasing power. Purchasing power hasn't changed in the economy. Just a shift

Economists don't think this way at all. These kinds of lessons are often presented in introductory economics courses to show how economists once thought things worked in 1803 when Say introduced "Say's Law".

Then the economics professor goes on to explain how a modern economy actually works (which we don't understand all that well.)

Generally speaking economic growth is considered a good thing, and banks lending to borrowers that are likely to be able to repay the loan (not true leading up to the financial crisis due to poor regulation and lending practices), is not a problem in a well regulated banking sector (in the US this went away in the 1980s).

So yes debt is a big problem with a poorly regulated banking industry (financial industry really because of shadow banking).

Debt is like a lot of things in life, too much or too little can be a bad thing.

The central bank can certainly influence the amount of lending by raising interest rates, as long as inflation is moderate, there is not much reason to do so.

Rune Likvern, 12/05/2015 at 1:43 pm
"US textbooks through 1990 covered this exactly as in that paper, so it was a good refresher, but not different from what I had learned in the past."

And what is the title of those textbooks?

"Now there seems to be more focus on private debt, which nobody in economics used to worry about."

Was it US public or private debt that started the GFC in 2007/2008?

[Dec 02, 2015] Larry Summers and the Subversion of Economics

Notable quotes:
"... As a rising economist at Harvard and at the World Bank, Summers argued for privatization and deregulation in many domains, including finance. Later, as deputy secretary of the treasury and then treasury secretary in the Clinton administration, he implemented those policies. Summers oversaw passage of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act, which repealed Glass-Steagall, permitted the previously illegal merger that created Citigroup, and allowed further consolidation in the financial sector. He also successfully fought attempts by Brooksley Born, chair of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission in the Clinton administration, to regulate the financial derivatives that would cause so much damage in the housing bubble and the 2008 economic crisis. He then oversaw passage of the Commodity Futures Modernization Act, which banned all regulation of derivatives, including exempting them from state antigambling laws. ..."
"... Over the past decade, Summers continued to advocate financial deregulation, both as president of Harvard and as a University Professor after being forced out of the presidency. During this time, Summers became wealthy through consulting and speaking engagements with financial firms. Between 2001 and his entry into the Obama administration, he made more than $20-million from the financial-services industry. (His 2009 federal financial-disclosure form listed his net worth as $17-million to $39-million.) ..."
"... In 2005, at the annual Jackson Hole, Wyo., conference of the worlds leading central bankers, the chief economist of the International Monetary Fund, Raghuram Rajan, presented a brilliant paper that constituted the first prominent warning of the coming crisis. Rajan pointed out that the structure of financial-sector compensation, in combination with complex financial products, gave bankers huge cash incentives to take risks with other peoples money, while imposing no penalties for any subsequent losses. Rajan warned that this bonus culture rewarded bankers for actions that could destroy their own institutions, or even the entire system, and that this could generate a full-blown financial crisis and a catastrophic meltdown. When Rajan finished speaking, Summers rose up from the audience and attacked him, calling him a Luddite, dismissing his concerns, and warning that increased regulation would reduce the productivity of the financial sector. (Ben Bernanke, Tim Geithner, and Alan Greenspan were also in the audience.) ..."
"... Over the past 30 years, the economics profession-in economics departments, and in business, public policy, and law schools-has become so compromised by conflicts of interest that it now functions almost as a support group for financial services and other industries whose profits depend heavily on government policy. The route to the 2008 financial crisis, and the economic problems that still plague us, runs straight through the economics discipline. And its due not just to ideology; its also about straightforward, old-fashioned money. ..."
"... Prominent academic economists (and sometimes also professors of law and public policy) are paid by companies and interest groups to testify before Congress, to write papers, to give speeches, to participate in conferences, to serve on boards of directors, to write briefs in regulatory proceedings, to defend companies in antitrust cases, and, of course, to lobby. This is now, literally, a billion-dollar industry. The Law and Economics Consulting Group, started 22 years ago by professors at the University of California at Berkeley (David Teece in the business school, Thomas Jorde in the law school, and the economists Richard Gilbert and Gordon Rausser), is now a $300-million publicly held company. Others specializing in the sale (or rental) of academic expertise include Competition Policy (now Compass Lexecon), started by Richard Gilbert and Daniel Rubinfeld, both of whom served as chief economist of the Justice Departments Antitrust Division in the Clinton administration; the Analysis Group; and Charles River Associates. ..."
"... I think it is interesting that Summers led the financial deregulation efforts of the Clinton administration and then made a bundle on Wall Street. I think that should be taken into account when evaluating his discussions of economics. ..."
"... It is difficult to get a man to understand something when his salary depends upon his not understanding it. ..."
economistsview.typepad.com

RGC, December 02, 2015 at 06:09 AM

Larry Summers and the Subversion of Economics

By Charles Ferguson October 03, 2010

The Obama administration recently announced that Larry Summers is resigning as director of the National Economic Council and will return to Harvard early next year. His imminent departure raises several questions: Who will replace him? What will he do next? But more important, it's a chance to consider the hugely damaging conflicts of interest of the senior academic economists who move among universities, government, and banking.

Summers is unquestionably brilliant, as all who have dealt with him, including myself, quickly realize. And yet rarely has one individual embodied so much of what is wrong with economics, with academe, and indeed with the American economy. For the past two years, I have immersed myself in those worlds in order to make a film, Inside Job, that takes a sweeping look at the financial crisis. And I found Summers everywhere I turned.

Consider: As a rising economist at Harvard and at the World Bank, Summers argued for privatization and deregulation in many domains, including finance. Later, as deputy secretary of the treasury and then treasury secretary in the Clinton administration, he implemented those policies. Summers oversaw passage of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act, which repealed Glass-Steagall, permitted the previously illegal merger that created Citigroup, and allowed further consolidation in the financial sector. He also successfully fought attempts by Brooksley Born, chair of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission in the Clinton administration, to regulate the financial derivatives that would cause so much damage in the housing bubble and the 2008 economic crisis. He then oversaw passage of the Commodity Futures Modernization Act, which banned all regulation of derivatives, including exempting them from state antigambling laws.

After Summers left the Clinton administration, his candidacy for president of Harvard was championed by his mentor Robert Rubin, a former CEO of Goldman Sachs, who was his boss and predecessor as treasury secretary. Rubin, after leaving the Treasury Department-where he championed the law that made Citigroup's creation legal-became both vice chairman of Citigroup and a powerful member of Harvard's governing board.

Over the past decade, Summers continued to advocate financial deregulation, both as president of Harvard and as a University Professor after being forced out of the presidency. During this time, Summers became wealthy through consulting and speaking engagements with financial firms. Between 2001 and his entry into the Obama administration, he made more than $20-million from the financial-services industry. (His 2009 federal financial-disclosure form listed his net worth as $17-million to $39-million.)

Summers remained close to Rubin and to Alan Greenspan, a former chairman of the Federal Reserve. When other economists began warning of abuses and systemic risk in the financial system deriving from the environment that Summers, Greenspan, and Rubin had created, Summers mocked and dismissed those warnings. In 2005, at the annual Jackson Hole, Wyo., conference of the world's leading central bankers, the chief economist of the International Monetary Fund, Raghuram Rajan, presented a brilliant paper that constituted the first prominent warning of the coming crisis. Rajan pointed out that the structure of financial-sector compensation, in combination with complex financial products, gave bankers huge cash incentives to take risks with other people's money, while imposing no penalties for any subsequent losses. Rajan warned that this bonus culture rewarded bankers for actions that could destroy their own institutions, or even the entire system, and that this could generate a "full-blown financial crisis" and a "catastrophic meltdown."

When Rajan finished speaking, Summers rose up from the audience and attacked him, calling him a "Luddite," dismissing his concerns, and warning that increased regulation would reduce the productivity of the financial sector. (Ben Bernanke, Tim Geithner, and Alan Greenspan were also in the audience.)

Soon after that, Summers lost his job as president of Harvard after suggesting that women might be innately inferior to men at scientific work. In another part of the same speech, he had used laissez-faire economic theory to argue that discrimination was unlikely to be a major cause of women's underrepresentation in either science or business. After all, he argued, if discrimination existed, then others, seeking a competitive advantage, would have access to a superior work force, causing those who discriminate to fail in the marketplace. It appeared that Summers had denied even the possibility of decades, indeed centuries, of racial, gender, and other discrimination in America and other societies. After the resulting outcry forced him to resign, Summers remained at Harvard as a faculty member, and he accelerated his financial-sector activities, receiving $135,000 for one speech at Goldman Sachs.

Then, after the 2008 financial crisis and its consequent recession, Summers was placed in charge of coordinating U.S. economic policy, deftly marginalizing others who challenged him. Under the stewardship of Summers, Geithner, and Bernanke, the Obama administration adopted policies as favorable toward the financial sector as those of the Clinton and Bush administrations-quite a feat. Never once has Summers publicly apologized or admitted any responsibility for causing the crisis. And now Harvard is welcoming him back.

Summers is unique but not alone. By now we are all familiar with the role of lobbying and campaign contributions, and with the revolving door between industry and government. What few Americans realize is that the revolving door is now a three-way intersection. Summers's career is the result of an extraordinary and underappreciated scandal in American society: the convergence of academic economics, Wall Street, and political power.

Starting in the 1980s, and heavily influenced by laissez-faire economics, the United States began deregulating financial services. Shortly thereafter, America began to experience financial crises for the first time since the Great Depression. The first one arose from the savings-and-loan and junk-bond scandals of the 1980s; then came the dot-com bubble of the late 1990s, the Asian financial crisis; the collapse of Long Term Capital Management, in 1998; Enron; and then the housing bubble, which led to the global financial crisis. Yet through the entire period, the U.S. financial sector grew larger, more powerful, and enormously more profitable. By 2006, financial services accounted for 40 percent of total American corporate profits. In large part, this was because the financial sector was corrupting the political system. But it was also subverting economics.

Over the past 30 years, the economics profession-in economics departments, and in business, public policy, and law schools-has become so compromised by conflicts of interest that it now functions almost as a support group for financial services and other industries whose profits depend heavily on government policy. The route to the 2008 financial crisis, and the economic problems that still plague us, runs straight through the economics discipline. And it's due not just to ideology; it's also about straightforward, old-fashioned money.

Prominent academic economists (and sometimes also professors of law and public policy) are paid by companies and interest groups to testify before Congress, to write papers, to give speeches, to participate in conferences, to serve on boards of directors, to write briefs in regulatory proceedings, to defend companies in antitrust cases, and, of course, to lobby. This is now, literally, a billion-dollar industry. The Law and Economics Consulting Group, started 22 years ago by professors at the University of California at Berkeley (David Teece in the business school, Thomas Jorde in the law school, and the economists Richard Gilbert and Gordon Rausser), is now a $300-million publicly held company. Others specializing in the sale (or rental) of academic expertise include Competition Policy (now Compass Lexecon), started by Richard Gilbert and Daniel Rubinfeld, both of whom served as chief economist of the Justice Department's Antitrust Division in the Clinton administration; the Analysis Group; and Charles River Associates.

In my film you will see many famous economists looking very uncomfortable when confronted with their financial-sector activities; others appear only on archival video, because they declined to be interviewed. You'll hear from:

  • Martin Feldstein, a Harvard professor, a major architect of deregulation in the Reagan administration, president for 30 years of the National Bureau of Economic Research, and for 20 years on the boards of directors of both AIG, which paid him more than $6-million, and AIG Financial Products, whose derivatives deals destroyed the company. Feldstein has written several hundred papers, on many subjects; none of them address the dangers of unregulated financial derivatives or financial-industry compensation.
  • Glenn Hubbard, chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers in the first George W. Bush administration, dean of Columbia Business School, adviser to many financial firms, on the board of Metropolitan Life ($250,000 per year), and formerly on the board of Capmark, a major commercial mortgage lender, from which he resigned shortly before its bankruptcy, in 2009. In 2004, Hubbard wrote a paper with William C. Dudley, then chief economist of Goldman Sachs, praising securitization and derivatives as improving the stability of both financial markets and the wider economy.
  • Frederic Mishkin, a professor at the Columbia Business School, and a member of the Federal Reserve Board from 2006 to 2008. He was paid $124,000 by the Icelandic Chamber of Commerce to write a paper praising its regulatory and banking systems, two years before the Icelandic banks' Ponzi scheme collapsed, causing $100-billion in losses. His 2006 federal financial-disclosure form listed his net worth as $6-million to $17-million.
  • Laura Tyson, a professor at Berkeley, director of the National Economic Council in the Clinton administration, and also on the Board of Directors of Morgan Stanley, which pays her $350,000 per year.
  • Richard Portes, a professor at London Business School and founding director of the British Centre for Economic Policy Research, paid by the Icelandic Chamber of Commerce to write a report praising Iceland's financial system in 2007, only one year before it collapsed.
  • And John Campbell, chairman of Harvard's economics department, who finds it very difficult to explain why conflicts of interest in economics should not concern us.

But could he be right? Are these professors simply being paid to say what they would otherwise say anyway? Unlikely. Mishkin and Portes showed no interest whatever in Iceland until they were paid to do so, and they got it totally wrong. Nor do all these professors seem to make policy statements contrary to the financial interests of their clients. Even more telling, they uniformly oppose disclosure of their financial relationships.

The universities avert their eyes and deliberately don't require faculty members either to disclose their conflicts of interest or to report their outside income. As you can imagine, when Larry Summers was president of Harvard, he didn't work too hard to change this.

Now, however, as the national recovery is faltering, Summers is being eased out while Harvard is welcoming him back. How will the academic world receive him? The simple answer: Better than he deserves.

While making my film, we wrote to the presidents and provosts of Harvard, Columbia, and other universities with detailed questions about their conflict-of-interest policies, requesting interviews about the subject. None of them replied, except to refer us to their Web sites.

Academe, heal thyself.

http://chronicle.com/article/Larry-Summersthe/124790/

EMichael said in reply to RGC...
Yeah, after an economist has had one job in the government; one job in the banking system; and one teaching job he should be required to stop working as an economist.
RGC said in reply to EMichael...
I think it is interesting that Summers led the financial deregulation efforts of the Clinton administration and then made a bundle on Wall Street. I think that should be taken into account when evaluating his discussions of economics.
EMichael said in reply to RGC...
Of course it should.

At the same time this is not taking anything into account, this is about "subverting" economics.

Can you make a case that the only reason Summers made a "bundle" working on Wall Street is because of the financial deregulation efforts he made? Last time I looked he did not have a vote on the legislation.

RGC said in reply to EMichael...
I think this is especially troubling for the economics profession:

"Over the past 30 years, the economics profession-in economics departments, and in business, public policy, and law schools-has become so compromised by conflicts of interest that it now functions almost as a support group for financial services and other industries whose profits depend heavily on government policy. The route to the 2008 financial crisis, and the economic problems that still plague us, runs straight through the economics discipline. And it's due not just to ideology; it's also about straightforward, old-fashioned money."

EMichael said in reply to RGC...
Cause no economists actually believed in any of the policies that caused all of those things nor did any economist fail to vote for the policies adopted.
RGC said in reply to EMichael...
Upton Sinclair:

"It is difficult to get a man to understand something when his salary depends upon his not understanding it."

Tom aka Rusty said in reply to RGC...

As Hemingway and F. SCott Fitzgerald exchanged in their writings (the reputed face-to-face conversation may not have happened):

The rich are different.

Yes, they have more money.

Combine elite and rich and you get a toxic combination.

[Dec 01, 2015] The New Supply-Side Economics

Economist's View
reason: December 01, 2015 at 07:27 AM

Sanjait

I think it is perfectly clear that a secular policy of increasing private indebtedness is not indefinitely extendable. Sure, if we had printed money in the past and kept monetary policy relatively tight (or otherwise managed the international financial system so that large persistent balance of payments deficits were not tolerated) we wouldn't have got in the mess we are in. But once we are there just trying to get over-indebted people to take on more debt doesn't seem like a winning strategy.

http://crookedtimber.org/2015/11/29/secular-stagnation-and-the-financial-sector/comment-page-3/#comment-650710

EMichael said in reply to reason... December 01, 2015 at 07:34 AM

I see no real increase in private indebtedness.

The problem with the financial system is what lies behind lending.

reason: December 01, 2015 at 07:36 AM

Avraam Jack Dectis
Not bad.
But

1. asset taxes are tricky things to run (many assets aren't traded and the prices of other assets are very volatile). And there is the problem of offshore ownership and offshore assets, so it requires international co-operation.

2. This takes a very closed economy view of things - the trade deficit might end up affecting the trade balance and hence the flow of assets into and out of the country, and eventually also the terms of trade. You should think through how such a policy would work in say - Luxembourg.

reason:

EMichael

You see no increase in private indebtedness - when do you mean? If you mean now - then yes - that is exactly why the economy is so sluggish. Where is the increase in demand going to come from if the country is running a trade deficit, is not increasing its borrowing and is committed to reducing its government deficit?

[Nov 29, 2015] neoclassical economics is involved in circular reasoning, and without a meaningful concept of capital, the rest of the system collapses.

Notable quotes:
"... neoclassical economics cannot establish the definition/measurement of "capital" without first knowing marginal productivity of capital; but they cannot establish the definition/measurement of marginal productivity of capital without first establishing "capital". ..."
"... ironically, it is conceivable that the entire neoclassical case for invisible hand can be reconstructed based on labor theory of value; after all, Ricardo did that ..."
"... But since then there has been lots of development among the more enlightened mainstream economists that have basically established that market failures are both devastating and universal. This is serious, because this means, in fact, in their heart, they know the invisible hand argument is invalid. Stiglitz came close to admit it in some interviews. ..."
"... Whatever is/was their internal system, both the Soviet Union and China are a part of the capitalist world system and therefore both of them are obligated to pursue economic growth. ..."
"... What you are saying/suggesting presents a profound misunderstanding of open, dissipative complex systems/structures – which we (our society, our economy – indeed our entire world ) are. ..."
"... Such systems cannot be in a permanent thermodynamic equilibrium – controlled plateau, or "sustainability" if we will (which you seem to be wishing/suggesting). They are utterly and totally dependent on ever-expanding energy/resource "consumption" and they ALWAYS and without exception collapse (hint: A.Bartlet)! Indeed, if physics and mathematics is to be trusted, they must collapse! ..."
peakoilbarrel.com
Political Economist, 11/13/2015 at 3:55 pm
Hi Dennis, I wrote a long reply to your question on labor theory of value. But somehow after I posted it, it appears to have disappeared. I am trying to re-post it here

Dennis:

Hi Dennis, thanks for bringing this up. This is definitely not about energy. But since you mentioned this here, let me give you some of my thought.

First, regarding neoclassical economics, the debate between two Cambridges pretty much destroyed the logical foundation of neoclassical economics. Because neoclassical economics cannot establish the definition/measurement of "capital" without first knowing marginal productivity of capital; but they cannot establish the definition/measurement of marginal productivity of capital without first establishing "capital".

So neoclassical economics is involved in circular reasoning, and without a meaningful concept of capital, the rest of the system collapses.

The above is mostly theoretical. It does not necessarily undermine one's faith in the efficiency of a market economy (ironically, it is conceivable that the entire neoclassical case for invisible hand can be reconstructed based on labor theory of value; after all, Ricardo did that)

But since then there has been lots of development among the more enlightened mainstream economists that have basically established that market failures are both devastating and universal. This is serious, because this means, in fact, in their heart, they know the invisible hand argument is invalid. Stiglitz came close to admit it in some interviews.

Why does it matter? Consider the current environmental crisis. It is conceivable that we will fail to stop climate change and the emerging climate catastrophes will bring down human civilization. From the neoclassical perspective, this is because the market prices for fossil fuels are wrong. Can this be corrected by government intervention? From the neoclassical perspective, to do this, the government needs to know the correct prices and even if the government does know the correct prices, there is still the implementation problem (principal-agent problem, people will find ways to outmaneuver government, etc). If the government does not know the correct prices or cannot implement, then we cannot correct market failures. If, on the other hand, the government does know the correct prices and can implement, why not have socialist planning?

Compare this to socialism. Of course one needs to be reminded of the Soviet environmental disasters. But the Soviet environmental failures were almost nothing compared to the contemporary Chinese environmental crisis (and I need to remind people that China's current environmental crisis has happened after China's capitalist transition). Whatever is/was their internal system, both the Soviet Union and China are a part of the capitalist world system and therefore both of them are obligated to pursue economic growth.

Although this has not happened in history, but it is definitely conceivable that a socialist economy can be structured to be based on zero or negative growth. But this cannot be said of capitalism.

In fact the strongest economic argument against socialism is that the socialist economies did not grow rapidly enough (even though Cuba succeeded in delivering higher life expectancy than the United States and for some years Cuba was considered the only country that met the principle of sustainable development by the living planet report). Therefore, the question is, if it turns out that capitalism cannot provide sustainability for human civilization, what social system can deliver sustainability while meeting population's basic needs?

Now, about labor theory of value. There are two different questions here. One has to do with the labor theory of value as a theory to explain the long-term equilibrium prices in a competitive market economy and the other has to do with what Marx called the theory of surplus value.

About the theory of surplus value, it needs to be reminded that Marx's theory of surplus value or exploitation is not moralistic but based on observed economic facts (although it could be used for moralistic purposes). All it says is no more than this: in a capitalist economy, a workers has to work longer than the social labor time embodied in the commodities consumed by the worker himself (or the worker's family) and in this sense, the capitalist profit (surplus value) derives from the worker's surplus labor. This is factually true.

Of course, as you said, a similar quantitative relationship can be established for other production inputs. Say, the total energy consumed in a society will have to be greater than the energy input used for energy production (people here are of course familiar with EROEI, which has to be greater than 1 for society to function). Based on this, one could argue that not only the workers are exploited but energy is also "exploited".

But if one really wants to extend the concept of "exploitation" here (which I don't think makes sense), what is being "exploited" is energy BUT NOT energy owners (even less the owners of capital goods consuming energy).

In any case, the concept of "exploitation" or surplus value has to be used in a context of social relations. It makes sense that the workers can take over the means of production and appropriate their own surplus value (or products of their surplus labor). But it is obviously nonsense to say that the energy input can somehow appropriate the "surplus energy" consumed in other energy consumption processes.

Finally, about the long-term equilibrium prices. It can be easily established that in "simple commodity production" (pre-capitalist market economy, where the producers own their means of production), market prices tend to fluctuate around ratios that are in proportion to the total labor embodied in commodities (including both direct labor and indirect labor embodied in means of production).

The problem has to do with "prices of production" or the equilibrium prices in capitalism (you are probably aware that this is known as the "transformation problem" in the Marxist literature). All the difficulty comes from the fact that in capitalism, the direct labor time ("live labor") is further divided into necessary labor (the labor time it takes for the worker to replace his value of labor power) and surplus labor. In fact, knowing the production coefficients, a unique set of equilibrium prices and the equilibrium profit rate can be solved from a set of past labor (indirect labor), necessary labor, and surplus labor for each commodity. Thus, a definite set of mathematical relations can be established between the prices and the labor variables (although it's no longer simple proportionality; but I think it does not matter)

Of course the Neo-Sraffians would like to emphasize that you can take any other important input (say, energy) and establish a similar set of relationship between prices and say, past energy, necessary energy, and surplus energy. But, as I said, energy cannot be a player in social relations.

In any case, labor theory of value plays an insignificant role in modern Marxist economics (I personally still think labor theory of value is valid but it no longer provides important insights).

You will not find labor theory of value in my book. But I hope you will still find it intellectually interesting (and a little provocative).

Minqi Li, 11/13/2015 at 4:02 pm
Hi Ron, I prepared a long reply to Dennis's question. But each time when I posted it, it was marked as SPAM.

I saved the response to Dennis here:

http://redchinacn.net/portal.php?mod=view&aid=28599#comment

Can you help me to post it? Thank you

Fred Magyar, 11/13/2015 at 5:24 pm
Hi Minqi Li,
I read your reply to Dennis and found it cogent, however I do have a problem with the standard neoclassical economic viewpoint and as I have stated many times I find the standard capitalist and communist economic models to be less than useful systems with which to address our current global dilemmas. I am of the school of thought that we have to invent completely new ways of thinking and acting. There are some people who have embarked on this journey. I think this group best embodies my current thinking about what kinds of systems we need to develop. Some of these ideas are already taking hold in China too.

循环经济

http://www.ellenmacarthurfoundation.org/

Cheers!

Political Economist, 11/13/2015 at 8:07 pm
Fred, thanks for commenting.

The concept of 循环经济 or recycling economy is actually what China borrowed from the West. Chinese economists started talking about it in the 1990s. The practice is not as radical as it sounds. The primary intention has not been so much about saving the environment as accelerating capital accumulation by saving costs.

Although in some cases it has had some beneficial "side effects"

I agree that we need completely new thinking and practice that go beyond the 20th century. I am of the school that zero (if not negative) economic growth is necessary for sustainability. The question is what kind of economic system can deliver it.

Petro, 11/14/2015 at 1:15 am
"…I am of the school that zero (if not negative) economic growth is necessary for sustainability. The question is what kind of economic system can deliver it…."

What you are saying/suggesting presents a profound misunderstanding of open, dissipative complex systems/structures – which we (our society, our economy – indeed our entire world ) are.

Such systems cannot be in a permanent thermodynamic equilibrium – controlled plateau, or "sustainability" if we will (which you seem to be wishing/suggesting).
They are utterly and totally dependent on ever-expanding energy/resource "consumption" and they ALWAYS and without exception collapse (hint: A.Bartlet)!
Indeed, if physics and mathematics is to be trusted, they must collapse!

-So, when you say:
"…The question is what kind of economic system can deliver it…", you are looking for the wrong, non-existing thing.

Consider that before your book is published…

Be well,

Petro

Political Economist, 11/14/2015 at 2:56 am
Unfortuantely, the book is already published.

Keynes said: "In the long run, we are all dead"

Petro, 11/14/2015 at 9:17 pm
"Unfortunately, the book is already published"

Unfortunately indeed!

Be well.

Petro

Javier, 11/14/2015 at 10:36 am
Hi Petro,

I agree in principle, but it is clear that societies can be built that are stable for hundreds to thousands of years until conditions diverge too much from those that allowed their formation. Hunter-gatherer societies were economically and socially stable in many parts of the world for most of the Holocene, so in principle it is theoretically possible to build a stable society that takes from the environment not much more than what can be renewed or recycled or last for a very long time. Animals and plants do it all the time, but of course their numbers are checked by the environment. And of course it would have little to do with current industrial civilization that is completely unsustainable.

Petro, 11/14/2015 at 9:24 pm
Hunter-Gatherers were stable ONLY for nature kept a "big stick" over their head every time they multiplied more than they should have…but as Ron has said multiple times: we are clever and have bypassed that (or so we think…).

Theoretically- as you say- yes!
Practically: NO!

"…We will kill them all…"
~ Ron Patterson

-And lastly, all this is mute for we ALREADY have passed the tipping point, or the point of no return- if you will.

Be well,

Petro

Fred Magyar, 11/14/2015 at 4:23 am
I agree with the idea that trying to achieve a zero growth economy is the only path towards sustainability.

Two points:

First the concept of the 'Circular Economy' goes far beyond simple recycling.

It incorporates systems and design thinking at a fundamental level in all aspects of the economy, government,and social systems. It thinks of the economy as an ecosystem. It borrows heavily from how nature builds sustainable systems. It is also very important to understand that it is not just a greenwashing. It is about a deep and fundamental process change.

Second: At our current juncture 'Perfect' is the enemy of good enough!
We need to move forward with all aspects of the 'Circular Economy' We don't have time to design and build a perfect system, We are in a situation where we know that our current ways of doing things are not sustainable so we have to push ahead with imperfect solutions and learn as we go.

Best Hopes!

BTW, Petro is only technically correct here:

-What you are saying/suggesting presents a profound misunderstanding of open, dissipative complex systems/structures – which we (our society, our economy – indeed our entire world ) are.

Without throwing the baby of ecosystem thermodynamics 101 out with the bath water, I repeat my point 'Perfect' is the enemy of good enough. Ecosystems are relatively speaking stable and have been for long periods of time. Nature has been tweaking them for 3.8 billion years. We on the other hand have managed to really screw things up in just a few thousand years.

We need to go back and learn how nature does design
https://goo.gl/tu3kPj

Ron Patterson, 11/14/2015 at 5:57 am
We need to go back and learn how nature does design

If we went back to when nature was in balance, to the point to where we were no longer destroying the ecosystem, then we would be back to only a few million Homo sapiens on earth.

While it is true that humans are a part of nature, it is also true that cancer is a part of nature.

Fred Magyar, 11/14/2015 at 7:30 am
We need to go back and learn how nature does design

If we went back to when nature was in balance,

Ron, that totally misses the point!

Yes, the ultimate goal would be to have sustainable systems in place. However, we are not in a position to go back to anything. We need to go forward. The point I was making is that we can learn from the way nature creates sustainable ecosystems and apply those lessons to our own systems. This is why I wanted to make crystal clear that I'm not talking about greenwashing or anything 'Green' in the old hippie commune model.

Basically nature uses multiple interconnected circular systems simultaneously on various scales from the microscopic to gigantic. Think of the multiple ecosystems on a single tree in a rainforest. The mosses and lichens fungi living on the bark of the tree. All the insect communities, ants, beetles, arachnids, etc, that depend on that. The tree itself using sunlight through photosynthesis, breathing, producing O2,transporting water and recycling nutrients, the carbon and nitrogen cycles and so on. The top of the tree is colonized with with completely different specialized ecosystems covered with epiphytes. Tree frogs and lizards living in the water filled pools created in the base of bromeliads. The birds and snakes living in the canopy. The large and small mammals living in various niches within all those ecosystems, the detrivores and bacteria and fungi that recycle all the nutrients from the organisms that die, etc… etc… and we are talking just one tree in a forest. This is the kind of integrated systems design that we need to emulate in our cities and businesses.

We humans, on the other hand, have built linear consumptive nonintegrated systems. These systems are extremely wasteful. Linear systems only work when resources limits are nonexistent. We no longer have the luxury of continuing with such systems. We need to learn how nature practically eliminates waste by emulating a model where waste streams are resource inputs and everything is reused there is practically no waste in a functioning stable ecosystem.

Ron Patterson, 11/14/2015 at 8:00 am
We need to learn how nature practically eliminates waste by emulating a model where waste streams are resource inputs and everything is reused there is practically no waste in a functioning stable ecosystem.

I totally understand your point Fred, but you are simply missing the big picture. When you say "we" just who are you talking about? Obviously if you are talking about fixing the terrible mess we find ourselves in, then "we" has to mean "we humans", all of us. And when you do that you are talking absolute nonsense.

Individuals can change but human nature cannot change. "We" will go on behaving in the future exactly as we have behaved in the past. The mass of humanity is consuming the natural resources like a drunken sailor going through his rich uncle's inheritance. And I don't mean just fossil resources, I mean all resources, all nature's bounty. And we are taking it from all the other creatures who are less clever than we are.

And "we" will continue to do so until it is gone, and all the other creatures are gone also.

wimbi, 11/13/2015 at 10:50 pm

A simple engineer's suggestion for basis of new economics, based on conversation with wiser ones elsewhere.

Proper economic structure is that which maximizes the number of options available for future choices.

Same as, minimize irreversibility; same as second law of thermo. Or, don't mess things up for the next guy.

Examples of violations of basic rule- kill the coral, next guy has less fish ; burn the oil, next guy has a smaller hunk of planet at bearable temps.

Example of application of basic rule – go to solar for energy, and stick within bounds of activity thereby set.

NB- another fundamental flaw of capitalism– like stars growing in a dust cloud where more massive ones grab mass faster than littler ones, ending up with big one gobbling it all. Bigger capitalists grab more resources faster than smaller ones, ending up with big ones getting it all.
And, very serious consequence – gross maldistribution of resource relative to individual ability to use resource wisely.

Above observations not to be attributed to me.

[Nov 23, 2015] An Unforgiving Musical-Chairs Economy

Notable quotes:
"... Every year, in the backwaters of America, that economy seems to put out fewer and fewer chairs. ..."
"... Not pull the wool over our eyes. But they both do defend and rely on a mainstream neoliberal, New Keynesian models of the economy which I think paint a very inadequate picture of the way our economy actually functions and is woefully inadequate as a guide for policy action - especially of the kinds that are urgently needed in 2015. ..."
"... I dont think Krugman and DeLong are the forces of evil. I just think the United States is in much worse shape then they seem prepared to come to grips with, and is in need of much more radical social and economic change then they seem willing to propose or entertain. They are stuck in the past and weighed down by defunct orthodoxies and theoretical abstractions. ..."
"... Most of my general criticisms of economists, by the way, are aimed at macroeconomists. I listened to a lecture by Robert Schiller the other day about his new book, and thought it sounded like great stuff. I think there is lots of great empirical work going on based on nuanced and up-to-date theories of human behavior. The macro guys often claim - on the basis of some kind of anti-reductionist credo - that their grand uniform economic theories of everything can float free of any foundation in theories of the actual behavior of actual human beings. But the theories are in practice based on analogies from individual or firm behavior to macro behavior, and the behavioral models on which they are based are extremely crude. ..."
"... But basically, I think my main axe to grind is that these economists are just not sufficiently appalled by the moral horrors of the social world we live in. There is a general lack of zeal. ..."
"... Sadly, it is also the case that the Democrats have backed way off economic issues since the late 1970s. At the time they suffered a massive fundraising disadvantage and wanted to attract big money donors (still Hillarys position). ..."
November 22, 2015 | Economist's View '

Harold Pollack (the beginning of the post talks about a recent column in the NY Times noting that "The people who most rely on the safety-net programs secured by Democrats are, by and large, not voting against their own interests by electing Republicans. Rather, they are not voting, period," and how that has turned blues states red):

What's the matter with Kentucky?: ...Viewed from afar, one might think that categories such as "deserving poor" or "disabled" are reasonably clear-cut. Viewed up-close, things seem much more fuzzy. Many people who rely on public aid straddle the boundaries between deserving and undeserving, disabled and able-bodied. Many of us know people who receive various public benefits, and who might not need to rely on these programs if they made better choices, if they learned how to not talk back at work, if they had a better handle on various self-destructive behaviors, if they were more willing to take that crappy job and forego disability benefits, etc.

It's easy, even viewing our own friends and relatives, to confuse cause and effect regarding more intimate barriers. A sad reality of psychiatric disorders is that the very symptoms which inflict mental pain on the sufferer can make themselves felt to others in ways that undermine empathy and personal relationships.

Across the Thanksgiving dinner table, you see these human frailties and failures more intensely and with greater granularity than the labor economist could possibly see running cold data at the Census Bureau. But operating at high altitude, the labor economist sees structural issues you can't see from eye level.

There have always been vulnerable people, whose troubles arise from an impossible-to-untangle mixture of bad luck, destructive behaviors, and difficult personal circumstance. That economist can't see why your imperfect cousin can't seem to get it together to hold a basic job. She can see that your cousin is being squeezed out by an unforgiving musical-chairs economy. Every year, in the backwaters of America, that economy seems to put out fewer and fewer chairs.

Posted by Mark Thoma on Sunday, November 22, 2015 at 12:10 PM in Economics | Permalink Comments (26)

pgl said...

"Supporters of expanded social provision must find better ways to engage poor people, to get out their votes."

Of course Republicans are doing everything they can to keep poor people from voting.

cm -> pgl...
Also in the US, elections seem to always (?) take place on work days, whereas e.g. in Germany the happen on Sundays as a rule. Of course one can vote by mail, but that requires a pretty stable and reliable mailing address ...
pgl -> cm...
In the South the Republicans loathe the idea that voting might occur on Sundays. Seems they fear those black mega churches turning out the vote.
cm -> pgl...
I was thinking more of people being unable to (or "preferring" not to) miss work, and not being able to show up for work as well as vote on the same day.

Do you think that people don't have enough willpower to sustain their decision to vote from Sunday to Tuesday? Or that they would vote only under the social pressure from the church group?

pgl -> cm...

I'm just saying let them vote when they can. As in your first sentence here.

Number 6 said...

The US is a militarist-imperialist, rentier-socialist, friendly fascist (for now) corporate-state for the top 0.001-1% to ~10% (the best gov't the money of the top 0.001-1% can buy) and a moronocracy for the rest of us, i.e., "no representation without taxation".

What is needed is 'Merikans for Moronocracy (or Morons for a New 'Merika) for us morons in red AND blue states to write in our own names for CEO of the fascist corporate-state. Imagine tens of millions of us unaffiliated morons writing in Joe Moron for POTUS and Jane Moron for Veep (or switch for your gender-specific or non-specific preference, or not).

Surely, none of us could do any worse for the bottom 90%+ than the Establishmet top 0.001%'s "choices" over the past 30-40+ years, or the current lot of Dame Hilbillary, The Donald, Crazy Carson, et al. (Of course, Bernie Sanders speaks to the values and objectives of the vast majority of 'Merikans who are actually democratic socialists but have been propagandized for at least a century or more not to know it.)

Morons of the world unite!!!

anne said...

http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2015/11/22/thinking-about-the-trumpthinkable/

November 22, 2015

Thinking About the Trumpthinkable
By Paul Krugman

Alan Abramowitz * reads the latest Washington Post poll and emails:

"Read these results ** and tell me how Trump doesn't win the Republican nomination? I've been very skeptical about this all along, but I'm starting to change my mind. I think there's at least a pretty decent chance that Trump will be the nominee.

"Here's why I think Trump could very well end up as the nominee:

"1. He's way ahead of every other candidate now and has been in the lead or tied for the lead for a long time.

"2. The only one even giving him any competition right now is Carson who is even less plausible and whose support is heavily concentrated among one (large) segment of the base-evangelicals.

"3. Rubio, the great establishment hope now, is deep in third place, barely in double digits and nowhere close to Trump or Carson.

"4. By far the most important thing GOP voters are looking for in a candidate is someone to 'bring needed change to Washington.'

"5. He is favored on almost every major issue by Republican voters including immigration and terrorism by wide margins. The current terrorism scare only helps him with Republicans. They want someone who will "bomb the shit" out of the Muslim terrorists.

"6. There is clearly strong support among Republicans for deporting 11 million illegal immigrants. They don't provide party breakdown here, but support for this is at about 40 percent among all voters so it's got to be a lot higher than that, maybe 60 percent, among Republicans.

"7. If none of the totally crazy things he's said up until now have hurt him among Republican voters, why would any crazy things he says in the next few months hurt him?

"8. He's very strong in several of the early states right now including NH, NV and SC. And he could do very well on 'Super Tuesday' with all those southern states voting. I can't see anyone but Trump or Carson winning in Georgia right now, for example, most likely Trump.

"9. And as for the idea of the GOP establishment ganging up on him and/or uniting behind another candidate like Rubio, that's at least as likely to backfire as to work. And even if it works, what's to stop Trump from then running as an independent?"

Indeed. You have a party whose domestic policy agenda consists of shouting "death panels!," whose foreign policy agenda consists of shouting "Benghazi!," and which now expects its base to realize that Trump isn't serious. Or to put it a bit differently, the definition of a GOP establishment candidate these days is someone who is in on the con, and knows that his colleagues have been talking nonsense. Primary voters are expected to respect that?

* http://polisci.emory.edu/home/people/faculty/abramowitz-alan.html

** http://apps.washingtonpost.com/g/page/politics/washington-post-abc-news-poll-nov-15-19-2015/1880/

gunste -> anne...
The reason may well be that there is a vast group of voters who consistently vote against their better interests, because their mindset is conservative, though they are actually middle class or lower. - Kansas appears to be a great example. These people do not think things through but vote on their gut (conservative they think) instincts. Education has a great deal to do with that voting decision. Thus we seem to see a blue collar worker with a median income take positions similar to that of the 1%. Curious but educational level is the likely answer. Such voters are also much more susceptible to propaganda based on tainted or false information which is circulated freely by many of the talking heads on radio and TV. Note that the Republicans work assiduously to discourage and restrict voting by gerrymandering, rules, voting days and sometimes requiting ID. - Democracy in America is a theoretical concept now.
cm said...
The Musical Chairs happens not only in the backwaters. It happens in and around the major job centers too. Nor is it only a matter of no job vs. some job, also how well the job is paid, working conditions, full time vs. part time, predictable work hours or on call (and only on-premises hours paid), etc.

It also doesn't just affect people with various "problems". There is the meme that when you are good you will always find a job, but that only works when employers are actually hiring. And the unstated part is that the job will be at your level of skill/ability. In "tech", and probably most "high skilled" fields, employers have a rather strong preference for an unbroken career in the field, you are basically defined by the "lowest" work you have done recently.

Dan Kervick -> Peter K....
"Kervick on the other hand tells us everyday that Krugman and DeLong are trying to pull the wool over our eyes on behalf of an evil neoliberal consensus."

Not pull the wool over our eyes. But they both do defend and rely on a mainstream neoliberal, New Keynesian models of the economy which I think paint a very inadequate picture of the way our economy actually functions and is woefully inadequate as a guide for policy action - especially of the kinds that are urgently needed in 2015.

I don't think Krugman and DeLong are the forces of evil. I just think the United States is in much worse shape then they seem prepared to come to grips with, and is in need of much more radical social and economic change then they seem willing to propose or entertain. They are stuck in the past and weighed down by defunct orthodoxies and theoretical abstractions.

Maybe in their hearts they really do grasp the magnitude of the problems, but just think the political environment is not hospitable to an honest airing of the alternatives. Maybe they are scared like everyone else.

But until prominent, established intellectuals with high profiles begin to come forward with bolder alternatives to late 20th century thinking, the America that is being crushed underfoot by an out-of-control capitalist leviathan is going to have to face a lot of unwelcome headwinds in their drive for liberating progressive change.

Syaloc -> Dan Kervick...
So basically you're calling for a return to a more institutional form of economics led by figures like John Kenneth Galbraith?
Dan Kervick -> Syaloc...
Yes, a more concrete, detailed, institution-based picture of the economic world, with more attention to history, other branches of social science, moral philosophy, cultural criticism, etc. - as well as just a bit more street smarts. Macroeconomists seem to have siloed themselves in self-contained theoretical world, where engagement with the human sciences of power and control, and the moral implications of those fields of study, are ignored.

Most of my general criticisms of economists, by the way, are aimed at macroeconomists. I listened to a lecture by Robert Schiller the other day about his new book, and thought it sounded like great stuff. I think there is lot's of great empirical work going on based on nuanced and up-to-date theories of human behavior. The macro guys often claim - on the basis of some kind of anti-reductionist credo - that their grand uniform economic theories of everything can float free of any foundation in theories of the actual behavior of actual human beings. But the theories are in practice based on analogies from individual or firm behavior to macro behavior, and the behavioral models on which they are based are extremely crude.

But basically, I think my main axe to grind is that these economists are just not sufficiently appalled by the moral horrors of the social world we live in. There is a general lack of zeal.

djb said...
a lot of it , I am sure, has to do with the "there is no difference between democrats and republicans" constant brainwashing

which helps the republicans big time

DrDick -> djb...
Sadly, it is also the case that the Democrats have backed way off economic issues since the late 1970s. At the time they suffered a massive fundraising disadvantage and wanted to attract big money donors (still Hillary's position).
djb -> DrDick...
still republicans are way worse especially now

DrDick said in reply to djb...

True, but for the poor, it is quite obvious that no one really gives a damn about them. Why should they vote when all they get is bailouts for banksters and the TPP? Right now, Sanders is the only one talking about programs that would really help them and he is a long shot (and I am a Sanders supporter).

Avraam Jack Dectis said...
.
A good economy compensates for much social dysfunction.

A bad economy moves people toward the margins, afflicts those near the margins and kills those at the margins.

This is what policy makers should consider as they pursue policies that do not put the citizen above all else.

cm -> Avraam Jack Dectis...
"A good economy compensates for much social dysfunction."

More than that, it prevents the worst of behaviors that are considered an expression of dysfunction from occurring, as people across all social strata have other things to worry about or keep them busy. Happy people don't bear grudges, or at least they are not on top of their consciousness as long as things are going well.

This could be seen time and again in societies with deep and sometimes violent divisions between ethnic groups where in times of relative prosperity (or at least a broadly shared vision for a better future) the conflicts are not removed but put on a backburner, or there is even "finally" reconciliation, and then when the economy turns south, the old grudges and conflicts come back (often not on their own, but fanned by groups who stand to gain from the divisions, or as a way of scapegoating).

[Nov 21, 2015] O'Malley best debate line: I think it may be time for us to quit taking advice from economists

Notable quotes:
"... I loved that Bernie Sanders was willing to drop the "F-bomb" (fraud) on Wall Street but he needs to swing much harder at Clinton. Clinton was quick to zing O'Malley as a hypocrite by noting he appointed a former hedge-fund manager to some state regulatory position when given the chance, but yet neither Sanders or O'Malley hit back with the fact that her only child and Clinton Foundation board member, Chelsea Clinton, worked for the hedge fund of a Clinton family pal and mega-donor in 2006. ..."
"... I thought O'Malley had one of the best lines of the night when he said "I think it may be time for us to quit taking advice from economists" but it seemed to go mostly unnoticed and unappreciated. ..."
"... Sanders did a relatively good job of deflecting and not getting zinged by the 'gotcha' question but a full-frontal assault would have been much better. Stronger, more Presidential and with the added bonus of giving neo-liberal economists under the pay of plutocrats a black eye. Another missed opportunity. The questioner set it up perfectly for him. I would have loved to see the expression on her corn-fed face when Bernie turned her 'gotcha' question that she had spent so much time and thought crafting into the home-run answer of the evening. Perhaps it could happen in a debate in the near future. ..."
November 16, 2015 | naked capitalism

Hillary Clinton Appeal to 9-11 to Defend Wall Street Donations Was Bad, But This Was Worse

Jerry Denim, November 16, 2015 at 11:46 am

I couldn't believe my eyes and ears during the debate when Sanders impugned Clinton's integrity for taking Wall Street super PAC money and she seemed to successfully deflect the accusation by going full-bore star-spangled sparkle eagle. She played the vagina card then quickly blurted out "9/11 New York" for applause while attempting conflate aiding and abetting Wall Street with the 9/11 attacks and patriotism. I couldn't believe people were clapping and I couldn't believe Clinton had the audacity to pull such a illogical and juvenile stunt on live television, but yet CBS reported her highest approval scores of the debate were registered during her confusing but emotionally rousing (for some people apparently) "vagina, 9/11" defense.

I loved that Bernie Sanders was willing to drop the "F-bomb" (fraud) on Wall Street but he needs to swing much harder at Clinton. Clinton was quick to zing O'Malley as a hypocrite by noting he appointed a former hedge-fund manager to some state regulatory position when given the chance, but yet neither Sanders or O'Malley hit back with the fact that her only child and Clinton Foundation board member, Chelsea Clinton, worked for the hedge fund of a Clinton family pal and mega-donor in 2006. Neither candidate mentioned that her son-in-law and the father of her grandchild who she is so fond of mentioning, just so happens to be an extremely rich hedge fund manager who benefits handsomely from the Clinton's political connections and prestige. This isn't mud, this is extremely germane, factual material already on the public record. It gets to the core of who Hillary is and where her loyalties lie. Hillary herself chose to identify unregulated derivatives and the repeal of Glass-Steagall as the primary causes of the financial crisis. She either claimed directly or insinuated that she would address these issues as President, but surprisingly no one pointed out that it was her husband's administration that blocked Brooksley Born from regulating derivatives in the 1990's and it was her husband's administration that effectively repealed Glass-Steagal with the signing of Gramm-Leach-Billey act in 1999. It's not a stretch to say the Clinton's deregulation of Wall Street paved the way for the crisis of 2008 and the extreme income inequality of today. Wall Street is deeply unpopular and Bernie Sanders has built a candidacy on two main issues: attacking Wall Street and addressing income inequality. These are punches he can't afford not to throw at his rival when she holds a commanding lead in the polls plus the support of the DNC and media establishment. Clinton is deeply corrupt and beholden to Wall Street. She needs to be beaten with this stick hard and often. Attempting to deflect this very accurate, very damaging criticism by wrapping herself in the flag and invoking feminism is a cheap stunt that will only work so many times before people notice what she is doing. Bernie needs to swing harder and keep at it, he already has the right message and Clinton is highly vulnerable on his pet topics.

I thought O'Malley had one of the best lines of the night when he said "I think it may be time for us to quit taking advice from economists" but it seemed to go mostly unnoticed and unappreciated. I would have loved a frontal assault on the validity and integrity of economists when the bespectacled lady in blue attempted to nail down Sanders with a 'gotcha' question implying raising the minimum wage would be catastrophic for the economy because "such-and-such economist" said so. There is so much disdain for science and academic credentials in the heartland right now, it seems crazy not to harness this anti-academic populist energy and redirect it to a deserving target like neo-liberal economists instead of climate scientists. " How's that Laffer curve working out for ya Iowa? Are you feeling the prosperity 'trickle down' yet?" Sanders did a relatively good job of deflecting and not getting zinged by the 'gotcha' question but a full-frontal assault would have been much better. Stronger, more Presidential and with the added bonus of giving neo-liberal economists under the pay of plutocrats a black eye. Another missed opportunity. The questioner set it up perfectly for him. I would have loved to see the expression on her corn-fed face when Bernie turned her 'gotcha' question that she had spent so much time and thought crafting into the home-run answer of the evening. Perhaps it could happen in a debate in the near future.

[Nov 17, 2015] Chicagonomics and Economics Rules

It's not about Adam Smith, it's about well paid intellectual prostitutes hired to restore the rule of financial oligarchy. The books discussed are Chicagoedonomics: The Evolution of Chicago Free Market Economics by By Lanny Ebenstein (278pp) and ECONOMICS RULES The Rights and Wrongs of the Dismal Science By Dani Rodrik (253pp)
Notable quotes:
"... He believed that government had a crucial role to play in a well-functioning economy. It should finance and run good schools, as well as build roads, bridges and parks, he argued. It should tax alcohol, sugar and tobacco, all of which impose costs on society. It should regulate businesses to protect workers. And it should tax the rich - who suffer from "indolence and vanity" - to help the poor. ..."
"... Which leftist economist was this? None other than Adam Smith, the inventor of the "invisible hand" and the icon of ­laissez-faire economics today. Smith's modern reputation is a caricature. ... ..."
Nov 17, 2015 | Economist's View

David Leonhardt reviews 'Chicagonomics' and 'Economics Rules':

'Chicagonomics' and 'Economics Rules': He believed that government had a crucial role to play in a well-functioning economy. It should finance and run good schools, as well as build roads, bridges and parks, he argued. It should tax alcohol, sugar and tobacco, all of which impose costs on society. It should regulate businesses to protect workers. And it should tax the rich - who suffer from "indolence and vanity" - to help the poor.

Which leftist economist was this? None other than Adam Smith, the inventor of the "invisible hand" and the icon of ­laissez-faire economics today. Smith's modern reputation is a caricature. ...

pgl
"Dani Rodrik, a Harvard economics professor, has written a much less political book than Ebenstein has, titled "Economics Rules," in which he sets out to explain the discipline to outsiders (and does a nice job). Yet in surveying the larger "rights and wrongs" of economics, to quote his subtitle, Rodrik has diagnosed the central mistake that contemporary libertarians have made: They have conflated ideas that often make sense with those that always make sense."

Dani is often under looked in these discussions which is a shame. His writings on how different societies have dealt with their local issues is some of the most informed economics out there.

likbez -> pgl...

I think we need to distinguish between Friedman the academic economist before writing Capitalism and Freedom (1962) and Friedman the public intellectual after.

"After" Friedman was a dismal intellectual prostitute that promoted neoliberalism for money paid by financial oligarchy. The level of dishonesty and intellectual degradation that he displays in his public appearances that now are available in YouTube videos is simply astonishing.

Actually Professor Wendy Brown touched the mechanics of this slick propaganda campaign in her book "Undoing the Demos". From Amazon:

=== Start of quote ===
Neoliberal rationality -- ubiquitous today in statecraft and the workplace, in jurisprudence, education, and culture -- remakes everything and everyone in the image of homo oeconomicus. What happens when this rationality transposes the constituent elements of democracy into an economic register? In Undoing the Demos, Wendy Brown explains how democracy itself is imperiled. The demos disintegrates into bits of human capital; concerns with justice bow to the mandates of growth rates, credit ratings, and investment climates; liberty submits to the imperative of human capital appreciation; equality dissolves into market competition; and popular sovereignty grows incoherent. Liberal democratic practices may not survive these transformations. Radical democratic dreams may not either.

In an original and compelling argument, Brown explains how and why neoliberal reason undoes the political form and political imaginary it falsely promises to secure and reinvigorate. Through meticulous analyses of neoliberalized law, political practices, governance, and education, she charts the new common sense. Undoing the Demos makes clear that for democracy to have a future, it must become an object of struggle and rethinking.

[Nov 13, 2015] When Economics Works and When it Doesn't

Notable quotes:
"... model one under which the efficient markets hypothesis is correct-and that's a model where there are a number of critical assumptions: one is rationality (we rule out behavioral aspects like bandwagons, excessive optimism and so on); second, we rule out externalities and agency problems ..."
"... to liberalize as many markets as possible and to make regulation as light as possible. In the run-up to the financial crisis, if you'd looked at the steady increase in house prices or the growth of the shadow banking system from the perspective of the efficient markets hypothesis, they wouldn't have bothered you at all. You'd tell a story about how wonderful financial liberalization and innovation are-so many people, who didn't have access before to mortgages, were now able to afford houses; here was a supreme example of free markets providing social benefits. ..."
"... But if you took the same [set of] facts, and applied the kind of models that people who had been looking at sovereign debt crises in emerging markets had been developing-boom and bust cycles, behavioral biases, agency problems, externalities, too-big-to-fail problems-if you applied those tools to the same facts, you'd get a very different kind of story. ..."
"... "efficient markets hypothesis": ..."
"... tendency in the policy world to liberalise as many markets as possible and to make regulation as light as possible ..."
Economist's View

Part of an interview of Dani Rodrik:

Q. You give a couple of examples in the book of the way theoretical errors can lead to policy errors. The first example you give concerns the "efficient markets hypothesis". What role did an overestimation of the scope and explanatory power of that hypothesis play in the run-up to the global financial crisis of 2007-08?

A. If we take as our central model one under which the efficient markets hypothesis is correct-and that's a model where there are a number of critical assumptions: one is rationality (we rule out behavioral aspects like bandwagons, excessive optimism and so on); second, we rule out externalities and agency problems-there's a natural tendency in the policy world to liberalize as many markets as possible and to make regulation as light as possible. In the run-up to the financial crisis, if you'd looked at the steady increase in house prices or the growth of the shadow banking system from the perspective of the efficient markets hypothesis, they wouldn't have bothered you at all. You'd tell a story about how wonderful financial liberalization and innovation are-so many people, who didn't have access before to mortgages, were now able to afford houses; here was a supreme example of free markets providing social benefits.

But if you took the same [set of] facts, and applied the kind of models that people who had been looking at sovereign debt crises in emerging markets had been developing-boom and bust cycles, behavioral biases, agency problems, externalities, too-big-to-fail problems-if you applied those tools to the same facts, you'd get a very different kind of story. I wish we'd put greater weight on stories of the second kind rather than the first. We'd have been better off if we'd done so.

djb said...

"efficient markets hypothesis": magical thinking

Jerry Brown said...

I can't get that link to open. Dani Rodrik says "there is a natural tendency in the policy world to liberalise as many markets as possible and to make regulation as light as possible". Is that in general? Or is that a part of the efficient market hypothesis?

[Nov 13, 2015] Dani Rodrik when economics works and when it doesn't

Notable quotes:
"... There's a certain fetishism that comes along with the use of math. And that shows up in two ways: one is that arguments which are relatively straightforward, that can be put in a directly literary form, we feel we have mathematise them. Sometimes, there's undue mathematisation or formalisation. We get so enamoured of the math that the mathematical structure of models becomes an object of analysis. And that's one of the problems with economic theory-that it often becomes applied mathematics, where the point is the mathematical properties of the models. And so it becomes more and more peripheral to what economics should be about, which is to look at social phenomena. But there's a much better appreciation today of the role and also the limits of math in economics than there was 30 years ago. ..."
"... it has squeezed out the space for mindless, abstract theorising or modelling for the sake of modelling. ..."
"... Models are stylised abstractions that lay bare the relationship between cause and effect. I liken [models] to lab experiments. When you conduct an experiment in a lab, you're trying to isolate the thing you're looking at. ..."
"... As long as we don't forget that [the model we're using] is a model, not the model. An immediate implication of what I just said, of the way I defined the usefulness of the model, is that the model captures only one of many different causal effects. And it's going to be most useful when we apply it to a real world setting where, in some sense, that causal effect is the dominant one. But [we should not] forget that there will be other settings where other causal effects or other models are more relevant. ..."
"... model one under which the efficient markets hypothesis is correct-and that's a model where there are a number of critical assumptions: one is rationality (we rule out behavioural aspects like bandwagons, excessive optimism and so on); second, we rule out externalities and agency problems-there's a natural tendency in the policy world to liberalise as many markets as possible and to make regulation as light as possible. In the run-up to the financial crisis, if you'd looked at the steady increase in house prices or the growth of the shadow banking system from the perspective of the efficient markets hypothesis, they wouldn't have bothered you at all. You'd tell a story about how wonderful financial liberalisation and innovation are-so many people, who didn't have access before to mortgages, were now able to afford houses; here was a supreme example of free markets providing social benefits. ..."
Nov 13, 2015 | Prospect Magazine
The economist Dani Rodrik, a professor at Harvard, recently spent a couple of years at Princeton's Institute for Advanced Study. In his new book, "Economics Rules: Why Economics Works, When it Fails, and How to Tell the Difference," he recalls just what a "mind-stretching experience" that sojourn was. He found that many of the visitors to the Institute's School of Social Sciences, prominent academics from other disciplines, harboured a deep "suspicion toward economists." Those visitors seemed to believe, he writes, that "economists either stated the obvious or greatly overreached by applying simple frameworks to complex social phenomena." It felt, Rodrik says, as if economists were being cast as the "idiots savants of social science: good with math and statistics, but not much use otherwise."

Part of the problem, Rodrik thinks, is "misinformation" about what it is economists do, exactly. "Economics Rules" is in part, therefore, an attempt to set the record straight-and to rebut some fairly widespread criticisms of economics in the process. But it's also aimed at his colleagues in the economics profession, who he thinks have made a sorry fist of "presenting their science to the world." When I spoke to him on the phone from the United States this week, I asked about that assumption he'd encountered at Princeton-that economists are "good with math and statistics" and not much else.

DR: Often we take it [mathematics] too far. There's a certain fetishism that comes along with the use of math. And that shows up in two ways: one is that arguments which are relatively straightforward, that can be put in a directly literary form, we feel we have mathematise them. Sometimes, there's undue mathematisation or formalisation. We get so enamoured of the math that the mathematical structure of models becomes an object of analysis. And that's one of the problems with economic theory-that it often becomes applied mathematics, where the point is the mathematical properties of the models. And so it becomes more and more peripheral to what economics should be about, which is to look at social phenomena. But there's a much better appreciation today of the role and also the limits of math in economics than there was 30 years ago.

JD: Right. You say in the book that one of the most significant developments in economics over the past three decades or so has been the increasingly widespread use of empirical methods.

Yes, that has definitely been a [sign of] great progress and has forced us to be much more grounded. And it has squeezed out the space for mindless, abstract theorising or modelling for the sake of modelling. But there's a tendency in parts of the profession [today] to believe that if you're just doing empirical work, then you can do away with theory or with thinking about the models that lie behind the particular empirical application. The point that is important to realise-and I'm not sure if I make this sufficiently strongly in the book itself-is that it's impossible to interpret any empirical evidence without either an implicit or, better still, an explicit model behind it. So every time we make a causal assertion about the real world using data we are implicitly using a model.

The idea of the economic model is one of the central concepts in the book. Where does the explanatory power of economic models come from?

Models are stylised abstractions that lay bare the relationship between cause and effect. I liken [models] to lab experiments. When you conduct an experiment in a lab, you're trying to isolate the thing you're looking at.

You draw an interesting comparison between models and fables. You say that models, like fables, leave out or abstract from certain aspects of the world as it is. And that, in your view, is a strength, a feature, as you put it, rather than a bug.

As long as we don't forget that [the model we're using] is a model, not the model. An immediate implication of what I just said, of the way I defined the usefulness of the model, is that the model captures only one of many different causal effects. And it's going to be most useful when we apply it to a real world setting where, in some sense, that causal effect is the dominant one. But [we should not] forget that there will be other settings where other causal effects or other models are more relevant.

A charge often made against economics, and which you try to rebut in the book, is that many of its assumptions, particularly about the rationality of economic actors, are unrealistic. To what extent does behavioural economics, which injects the insights of psychology into formal economic modelling, take that kind of criticism for granted? Or, to put it another way, does behavioural economics overturn or invalidate what you call the "garden-variety perfectly competitive market model"?

Yes, but it's only the latest a stream of models that have all had the effect of overturning the central implication of the perfectly competitive model. We've known since the 19th century that a market with a few firms would not produce the efficiency consequences of the perfectly competitive model. Then, of course, in the 1970s there was the imperfect competition revolution, where it turns out that, in the presence of asymmetric information, all kinds of consequences follow. So the behavioural revolution isn't new in the sense of generating results that overturn the basic implications of the perfectly competitive model. It's new in that it directly removes an assumption that had been at the core of neoclassical theorising-the notion of individual rationality.

There's a tendency now to interpret the behavioural models as implying that we can now forget about "rational man," that we can forget about all these optimising frameworks. And again I think that's wrong. There are going to be settings in which the behavioural model provides important insights. But it would be wrong to discard models in which rational behaviour plays an important role. The trick is to know when to apply a behavioural approach and when to apply a rational approach.

You have a chapter entitled "When Economists Go Wrong" in which you argue that economists' biggest mistake concerns the claims they often make for the general validity of certain assumptions and models. The danger, in other words, is that of confusing a model with the model.

Right. In policy, that's where we fall on our faces repeatedly. When we are called on for policy advice our biggest mistake is not drawing the links between the critical assumptions of a model and the real world context with the same kind of rigour and systematic thinking that we exercise when we're operating within a model.

You give a couple of examples in the book of the way theoretical errors can lead to policy errors. The first example you give concerns the "efficient markets hypothesis". What role did an overestimation of the scope and explanatory power of that hypothesis play in the run-up to the global financial crisis of 2007-08?

If we take as our central model one under which the efficient markets hypothesis is correct-and that's a model where there are a number of critical assumptions: one is rationality (we rule out behavioural aspects like bandwagons, excessive optimism and so on); second, we rule out externalities and agency problems-there's a natural tendency in the policy world to liberalise as many markets as possible and to make regulation as light as possible. In the run-up to the financial crisis, if you'd looked at the steady increase in house prices or the growth of the shadow banking system from the perspective of the efficient markets hypothesis, they wouldn't have bothered you at all. You'd tell a story about how wonderful financial liberalisation and innovation are-so many people, who didn't have access before to mortgages, were now able to afford houses; here was a supreme example of free markets providing social benefits.

But if you took the same [set of] facts, and applied the kind of models that people who had been looking at sovereign debt crises in emerging markets had been developing-boom and bust cycles, behavioural biases, agency problems, externalities, too-big-to-fail problems-if you applied those tools to the same facts, you'd get a very different kind of story. I wish we'd put greater weight on stories of the second kind rather than the first. We'd have been better off if we'd done so.

You also have a chapter on "Economics and Its Critics". To what extent does your point about economists' tendency to overestimate the scope and power of their models neutralise some fairly common criticisms of the discipline made by non-economists? Your point being, as I understand it, that the problem is not so much with the models themselves as with economists' expectations of what those models will yield.

What I'm claiming is that if economists were actually truer to their discipline and were to project their discipline to the rest of the world as a collection of models, to a large extent it would help neutralise the criticism that economists are [wedded to] one model in particular. You don't get a reputation as a successful researcher by demonstrating that Adam Smith was right! You get a reputation by showing that there are very circumstances in which he might have been wrong. But this richness, this willingness to countenance non-free-market outcomes, is somehow rarely revealed to the outside world.

Dani Rodrik's "Economics Rules: Why Economics Works, When It Fails, And How to Tell the Difference" is published by Oxford University Press (£16.99)

[Nov 12, 2015] Trickle Down, Starve the Beast, Supply-Side, and Sound Money Fantasies

Notable quotes:
"... STUDY: During the past three years, members of the Standard Poor's 500 Index have spent more than $1.5 trillion buying back stock ... US companies issued stock equal to $1.2 trillion last year. All told the new issues in 2014 exceeded share buybacks ... The conclusion is that what looks like buybacks are actually thinly veiled management-compensation plans. ..."
"... Looser monetary policy increases the value of existing assets but reduces the return on assets. So the impact it has on inequality is to increase it in the short run, but in the long run the first order* impact is zero. ..."
"... I doubt that trickle down, starve the beast, supply-side, sound money fantasies are really economics at all. They look now more like the supportive myths of a new, much more hierarchical social order. As such, they should be seen as modern equivalents of the Divine Right royal myth of the Ancien Regime, or even the claim of Dark Age warlords to be descendants of Woden. ..."
Economist's View

JohnH said in reply to djb...

Tim Canova on trickle down monetary policy:

"Ben Bernanke, the Federal Reserve chairman when the QE programs were first launched, claimed that asset purchases would have a "wealth effect": by the Fed purchasing bonds in such large amounts, bond prices would rise, yields would fall, and investors would shift into riskier securities, driving up the price of corporate shares and stock markets. Everyone would feel richer, businesses would invest and consumers would spend more. This seems much like the theory of "trickle-down" fiscal policy: that tax cuts for those with high incomes would be invested, thereby leading to the hiring of additional workers and spreading the benefits to the rest of the economy. But like the Bush administration's tax cuts, the Fed's monetary trickle-down has not worked so well. The Fed's lending and asset purchase programs have effectively propped up Wall Street interests -- big banks and financial markets -- but they have also neglected the needs of Main Street, including the small community banks, small and moderate sized and family-owned businesses, unemployed and underemployed workers, and state and local governments."
https://www.dissentmagazine.org/article/who-runs-federal-reserve-2008-crash

Canova is one of the nationally renowned economists who advised Bernie Sanders on the Fed, and actually got the Fed audited, exposing apparent conflicts of interest with Wall Street.
http://www.sanders.senate.gov/newsroom/press-releases/top-economists-to-advise-sanders-on-fed-reform

What's amazing: 'liberals' can see trickle down when it comes to tax cuts but not in monetary policy. They march in lock step with Wall Street when it comes to monetary policy...which has barely trickled down at all after seven years.

Bud Meyers said...

Bloomberg (November 2015)

STUDY: "During the past three years, members of the Standard & Poor's 500 Index have spent more than $1.5 trillion buying back stock ... US companies issued stock equal to $1.2 trillion last year. All told the new issues in 2014 exceeded share buybacks ... The conclusion is that what looks like buybacks are actually thinly veiled management-compensation plans."

http://www.bloombergview.com/articles/2015-11-11/why-corporate-management-loves-share-buybacks

Bernie! Bernie! Bernie!
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=6_L5e0fIkQ8

sanjait said...

It's apparently impossible for most to understand this ... but the most accurate way to describe the first order distributional impact of looser monetary policy would be to say:

Looser monetary policy increases the value of existing assets but reduces the return on assets. So the impact it has on inequality is to increase it in the short run, but in the long run the first order* impact is zero.

*Of course, second order impacts are important here. But if we're counting those, we should probably keep in mind the dynamics of the given situation, and the fact that workers in no way benefit from letting the economy slide into depression.

Peter K. said...

WSJ:

"It's also notable that nearly all of the GOP candidates identify the Federal Reserve's post-crisis monetary policy as a source of rising inequality "

I find it hard to believe that the Wall Street Journal or the GOP candidates actually think rising inequality is a bad thing.

gordon said...

I doubt that "trickle down, starve the beast, supply-side, sound money fantasies" are really economics at all. They look now more like the supportive myths of a new, much more hierarchical social order. As such, they should be seen as modern equivalents of the Divine Right royal myth of the Ancien Regime, or even the claim of Dark Age warlords to be descendants of Woden.

[Nov 04, 2015] Do Economists Promote Ideology as Science?

Notable quotes:
"... Is economics, as some assert, little more than a means of dressing up ideological arguments in scientific clothing? ..."
"... This certainly happens, especially among economists connected to politically driven think tanks – places like the Heritage Foundation come to mind. Economists who work for businesses also have a tendency to present evidence more like a lawyer advocating a particular position than a scientist trying to find out how the economy really works. ..."
"... No - we dont allow MDs to prescribe or treat on the basis of theory alone. Its unethical for any professional practitioner to give advice that is not supported by compelling evidence demonstrating that the advise is both safe and effective - First, do no harm. ..."
"... To a man, professional economists shill for the view that they are morally free to treat real economies and real people as their personal lab rats. As a group, economists are an ethically challenged bunch in this respect, and probably in other respects too. ..."
"... The rich plutocrats have a major stake in advocating very specific narratives, so they will throw large sums behind those narratives (and the fight against anything conflicting with them). ..."
"... What sort of opinions are economists allowed to have if they want tenure, want to be published in the major journals or want to make a living? ..."
"... Keynes concluded that government direction was necessary for a viable economy. Keynes interpreters in the US buried that idea, and thus became very important economists - guys like Paul Samuelson. The first ( and only) US book to faithfully represent Keynes ideas faded away soon after publication: http://news.stanford.edu/pr/93/931011Arc3112.html ..."
"... It is impossible to talk about economics without making essentially ideological distinctions. Private property and wage labor are not natural categories. Their adequacy as human practices therefore needs to be either defended or criticized. To simply take them as given is an ideological waffle that begs THE question. ..."
"... Economists thus SHOULD have, acknowledge and fully disclose their ideological biases. When evaluating evidence they should make every effort to set aside and overcome their biases. And they need to stay humble about how Sisyphean, incongruous and incomplete their attempts at objectivity are. ..."
"... And so - though we proceed slowly because of our ideologies, we might not proceed at all without them. - Joseph Schumpeter ..."
Nov 03, 2015 | Economist's View

My latest column:

Do Economists Promote Ideology as Science?: Which is more important in determining the policy positions of economists, ideology or evidence? Is economics, as some assert, little more than a means of dressing up ideological arguments in scientific clothing?
This certainly happens, especially among economists connected to politically driven think tanks – places like the Heritage Foundation come to mind. Economists who work for businesses also have a tendency to present evidence more like a lawyer advocating a particular position than a scientist trying to find out how the economy really works.

But what about academic economists who are supposed to be searching for the truth no matter the political implications? Can we detect the same degree of bias in their research and policy positions? ...

rayward said...

Thoma's assessment seems fair enough. I'd make the point that, for some academic economists, no amount of evidence is sufficient to overcome their bias. "Where's the proof" is the refrain one hears often. And then there's the question: what is evidence? The availability of lots of data is often used to "prove" this or that theory, even when the "proof" is contrary to the historical evidence one can see with her own eyes. Data used as obfuscation rather than clarification. I appreciate that one historical event following another historical event does not prove causation, but what's better proof than history.

RogerFox said...

"Shouldn't theory be a guide when the empirical evidence is unconvincing one way or the other?"

No - we don't allow MDs to prescribe or treat on the basis of theory alone. It's unethical for any professional practitioner to give advice that is not supported by compelling evidence demonstrating that the advise is both safe and effective - 'First, do no harm.'

To a man, professional economists shill for the view that they are morally free to treat real economies and real people as their personal lab rats. As a group, economists are an ethically challenged bunch in this respect, and probably in other respects too.

DeDude said...

Economics as a science is mainly hurt by two things.

  1. The rich plutocrats have a major stake in advocating very specific narratives, so they will throw large sums behind those narratives (and the fight against anything conflicting with them).
  2. Economics does not have anything resembling the double blind placebo controlled trials that help medicine fight off the narratives of those with money and power.
RGC said...

What sort of opinions are economists allowed to have if they want tenure, want to be published in the major journals or want to make a living?

Keynes concluded that government direction was necessary for a viable economy. Keynes' "interpreters" in the US buried that idea, and thus became very important economists - guys like Paul Samuelson. The first ( and only) US book to faithfully represent Keynes' ideas faded away soon after publication: http://news.stanford.edu/pr/93/931011Arc3112.html

pete said...

I did not know there was a debate. Krugman summed it all up in Peddling Prosperity. Folks know who pays the rent, and opine accordingly.

Syaloch said...

I think problems arise when economists are called upon by politicians or the media to give expert advice.

Within the sciences, "We don't know the answer to that" is a perfectly acceptable response, and in scientific fields where the stakes are low that response is generally accepted by the public as well. "What is dark matter made of?" "We don't know yet, but we're working on it." But in politics, where the stakes are higher, not having a definitive answer is viewed as a sign of weakness. How often do you hear a politician responding to a "gotcha" question admit that they don't know the answer rather than trying to BS their way through?

Given the timeliness of news coverage the media prefer to consult experts who offer definitive answers, especially given their preference for pro/con type interviews which require experts on both sides of an issue. Economists who are put on the spot this way feel pressured to ditch the error bars and give unambiguous answers, even answers based purely on theory with little to no empirical backing, and the more often they do this the more often they're invited back.

Sandwichman said...

It is impossible to talk about economics without making essentially ideological distinctions. Private property and wage labor are not "natural" categories. Their adequacy as human practices therefore needs to be either defended or criticized. To simply take them "as given" is an ideological waffle that begs THE question.

Economists thus SHOULD have, acknowledge and fully disclose their ideological biases. When evaluating evidence they should make every effort to set aside and overcome their biases. And they need to stay humble about how Sisyphean, incongruous and incomplete their attempts at objectivity are.

Let's not forget that "The End of Ideology" was a polemical tract aimed at designating the ideology of the managers and symbol manipulators "above" and beyond ideology. Similarly, Marx's brilliant critique of ideology degenerated into polemic as its practitioners adopted the mantle of "science."

anne said in reply to Sandwichman...

Really excellent, and why I am immediately wary of self-described "technocrats."

anne said in reply to Sandwichman...

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_End_of_Ideology

The End of Ideology: On the Exhaustion of Political Ideas in the Fifties is a collection of essays published in 1960 by Daniel Bell, who described himself as a "socialist in economics, a liberal in politics, and a conservative in culture". He suggests that the older, grand-humanistic ideologies derived from the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries had been exhausted, and that new, more parochial ideologies would soon arise. He argues that political ideology has become irrelevant among "sensible" people, and that the polity of the future would be driven by piecemeal technological adjustments of the extant system.

anne said in reply to Sandwichman...

What precisely is "Marx's critique of ideology ?"

Sandwichman said in reply to anne...

A very big question! Like "what is the meaning of life?" At least a semester-long upper division seminar course. ;-)

In a nutshell (to put it crudely), Marx labelled as ideologists a cohort of German followers of Hegel's philosophy who envisioned historical progress as the result of the progressive refinement of intellectual ideas. Marx argued instead that historical change resulted from struggle between social classes over the material conditions of life, fundamental to which was the transformation of nature through human intervention into means of subsistence.

anne said in reply to Sandwichman...

Marx labelled as ideologists a cohort of German followers of Hegel's philosophy who envisioned historical progress as the result of the progressive refinement of intellectual ideas. Marx argued instead that historical change resulted from struggle between social classes over the material conditions of life, fundamental to which was the transformation of nature through human intervention into means of subsistence.

[ What a superb introductory or summary explanation. I could not be more impressed or grateful. ]

DrDick said in reply to Sandwichman...

Well said. I would add "markets" to that list of relatively recent cultural constructs that needs greater scrutiny.

Chuck said...

"And so - though we proceed slowly because of our ideologies, we might not proceed at all without them." - Joseph Schumpeter, "Science and Ideology," The American Economic Review 39:2 (March 1949), at 359
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1812737

Sandwichman said in reply to Chuck...

Indeed.

Ignacio said...

Many guys are not driven by ideology, rather than evidence. The problem with this article is that we cannot compare with other professions and say "economists are more/less prone to promote ideology than the average".

DrDick said in reply to Ignacio...

All human endeavors are shaped by "ideology" in many different ways. What is important is to be aware of and explicit about their influences on our thought and action.

RC AKA Darryl, Ron said in reply to RC AKA Darryl, Ron...

If there are two sides to an argument that radically disagree then it is possible that both sides may be ideology, but both sides cannot be science. Only the correct argument can be science. Of course ideology is a bit too kind of a word since the incorrect argument is actually just a con game by people out to lay claim on greater unearned wealth.

ken melvin said...

Economists seem content with trying to figure out how to make 'it' work. Far better, I think, to try and figure out how it should be.

It was philosophers such as Hume, Locke, Marx, Smith, Rawls, ... who asked the right questions. Laws and economics come down to us according to how we think about such things; they change when we change the way we think. Seems we're in a bit of a philosophical dry patch, here. Someday, we will have to develop a better economic system, might be now. Likewise, there are laws rooted in antiquity that were wrong then and are wrong still.

RC AKA Darryl, Ron said in reply to ken melvin...

Exactly! They all know what they are doing. Some of them are just trying to do the wrong thing.

Arne said...

"Ideology certainly influences which questions academic researchers believe are the most important, but there is nothing wrong with that."

No "experiment" in economics comes with the degree of control that experiments in physical sciences take for granted, so there is tremendous room for ideology to come into the discussion of whether a data set really represents the conditions the model is supposed to consider. Since reviewing another economist's study entails asking questions those questions...

DrDick said in reply to Arne...

Please describe the "experimentation" which takes place in astronomy and geology. Ideologies also play important roles in experimental sciences, such as biology (for which we have a lot of evidence.

[Oct 19, 2015] Is Money Corrupting Research?

Notable quotes:
"... Of course, the Cato Institute, Heritage, and Team Republican economists are proud that their opinions are bought and paid for. ..."
"... Most (all?) academic types are keenly aware of the importance of grantsmanship as a basic skill. Knowing the appropriate funding sources and, in some cases, the interests and biases of funding sources, is stock in trade. Scientific research has become so capital intensive that large grants from government and large foundations are necessary to carry it out. For the most part, the biases of the granting institutions are known and discounted. ..."
economistsview.typepad.com
Luigi Zingales:
Is Money Corrupting Research?: The integrity of research and expert opinions in Washington came into question last week, prompting the resignation of Robert Litan ... from his position as a nonresident fellow at the Brookings Institution.

Senator Elizabeth Warren raised the issue of a conflict of interest in Mr. Litan's testimony before a Senate committee... Senator Warren was herself criticized by economists and pundits, on the left and right. ... But at stake is the integrity of the research process and the trust the nation puts in experts, who advise governments and testify in Congress. Our opinions shape government policy and judicial decisions. Even when we are paid to testify..., integrity is expected from us. ...

Yet it is disingenuous for anybody (especially an economist) to believe that reputational incentives do not matter. Had the conclusions not pleased the Capital Group, it would probably have found a more compliant expert. And the reputation of not being "cooperative" would have haunted Mr. Litan's career as a consultant. ...

Reputational ... concerns do not work as well with sealed expert-witness testimony or paid-for policy papers that circulate only in small policy groups. ... A scarier possibility is that reputational incentives do not work because the practice of bending an opinion for money is so widespread as to be the norm. ...

He goes on to suggest some steps to strengthen the reputational incentive.

pgl said in reply to Larry...

"Businesses sometimes finance policy research much as advocacy groups or other interests do," the economists wrote. "A reader can question the source of the financing on all sides, but ultimately the quality of the work and the integrity of the author are paramount." They praised Litan's quality and integrity as having been "impeccable over a career of four decades."

The fact of the matter is that funding comes from all sorts of places. One should always disclose the sourcing of funding and then let one's writings stand scrutiny.

Of course, the Cato Institute, Heritage, and Team Republican economists are proud that their "opinions" are bought and paid for.

anne said in reply to Larry...
http://www.reuters.com/article/2015/09/30/us-brookings-warren-resignation-idUSKCN0RU00B20150930

September 29, 2015

Brookings fellow resigns after Senator Warren accuses him of conflicts
By SARAH N. LYNCH - Reuters

WASHINGTON

A prominent Brookings Institution fellow resigned on Tuesday, after Massachusetts Senator Elizabeth Warren accused him of failing to fully disclose industry funding tied to a study that criticized the U.S. Labor Department's plan to regulate brokerages.

The resignation of Robert Litan came just one day after Warren, a Democrat, sent Brookings' president a letter demanding to know more about the think tank's policies on financial conflicts and details about the communications between Litan and Capital Group, an investment firm that funded his research paper.

"He has acknowledged that he made a mistake in not following Brookings regulations designed to uphold the independence of the institution," Brookings President Strobe Talbott said in a statement provided to Reuters.

Warren's concerns center a study that Litan and researcher Hal Singer jointly conducted which examined a controversial plan by the Labor Department to try and rein in conflicts posed by brokers who offer retirement advice.

The proposal has garnered fierce opposition from Wall Street, and Litan's study concluded that the plan could harm consumers.

Litan testified about the study's findings in a July hearing before a U.S. Senate panel, in which he represented himself as a fellow at Brookings.

The study was conducted by Litan and Singer in their capacity as staffers for Economists, Inc., a consulting firm.

Although his testimony and his study did disclose that Capital Group provided funding, Warren said that she later learned this was not the full story.

In a series of follow-up questions Warren sent to Litan after the hearing, she said he disclosed that Capital Group also provided feedback and editorial comments on a draft.

This, she said, ran counter to his claim at the hearing that he and Singer were "solely responsible" for the study's conclusions.

In addition, he disclosed that Capital Group had paid Economists Inc $85,000 for the study, and his share was $38,800.

In her letter to Brookings, Warren said the lack of disclosure raises "significant questions about the impartiality of the study and its conclusions."

Litan, a former top official in the Clinton administration, did not respond to an email seeking comment.

He is a well-known economics expert in Washington who has authored or co-authored over 25 books.

"We greatly appreciate all the good work Bob has done for Brookings over the 40-plus years he has been connected to this institution," Talbott said.

mulp said in reply to Larry...
What did Brookings do to Litan???

According to Reuters, he failed to disclose his relationships when presenting his report and when testifying, and seems to have lied:

"Although his testimony and his study did disclose that Capital Group provided funding, Warren said that she later learned this was not the full story.

"In a series of follow-up questions Warren sent to Litan after the hearing, she said he disclosed that Capital Group also provided feedback and editorial comments on a draft.

"This, she said, ran counter to his claim at the hearing that he and Singer were "solely responsible" for the study's conclusions."

Can I edit anything you write and claim as solely your own work? I want to have my point of view endorsed by a much larger group of writers, and the best way is for me to fix their writings.

It was not Litan being paid that was the problem, but the fact he claimed the words written for him were his own as an "independent" authority.

Second Best said...
Money corrupts research as sure as the Pope is Catholic...
greg said in reply to anne...
Rumors of Thomas Malthus' irrelevance to humanity's future are greatly exaggerated.

Consider instead: "Human and nature dynamics (HANDY): Modeling inequality and use of resources in the collapse or sustainability of societies"
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0921800914000615

Authors: Safa Motesharreia, Jorge Rivasb, Eugenia Kalnayc

This is the actual paper of the model, but do not be afraid. Here are the highlights:

" HANDY is a 4-variable thought-experiment model for interaction of humans and nature.
The focus is on predicting long-term behavior rather than short-term forecasting.
Carrying Capacity is developed as a practical measure for forecasting collapses.
A sustainable steady state is shown to be possible in different types of societies.
But over-exploitation of either Labor or Nature results in a societal collapse."

There are equations. And graphs. The concluding paragraph of the abstract:

"The measure "Carrying Capacity" is developed and its estimation is shown to be a practical means for early detection of a collapse. Mechanisms leading to two types of collapses are discussed. The new dynamics of this model can also reproduce the irreversible collapses found in history. Collapse can be avoided, and population can reach a steady state at maximum carrying capacity if the rate of depletion of nature is reduced to a sustainable level and if resources are distributed equitably."

This made the press about a year and a half ago, was commented on, but has since been ignored. Google "Handy Model" for popular presentations and critiques.

You decide whether it should continue to be ignored, given the remarkable progress the world has made towards remedying inequality, conserving resources, and controlling population growth. (That's sarcasm.)

reason said...

There is another solution to this issue. Financing should never be direct to the researcher. That way there is a funding body (say a university) that decides who researches what, and the funding is channeled through them (through a public application process). If a firm is really interested in disinterested research, no problem.

If it wants to control the research, they have a problem. Of course the whole funding body could be corrupted but if there is a public review process that can be minimised.

cm said in reply to reason...

It is more subtle than asking for or implying a preference for specific results. Regardless how the funding is distributed, except perhaps by lottery, there is the issue of "repeat business" or expert shopping (cherry-picking research organizations that are known to fall in a particular camp).

Then there is the issue of fads - even in relatively apolitical tech science, funding and research flocks to certain hot topics, as people hunt for funding by trying to tie their proposal to the current hot topics. But then this is perhaps more a consequence of an already corrupted funding process that only supports R&D that conforms to current preconceived notions and business interests.


bakho said...

Money supports bias.

RC AKA Darryl, Ron said...

Money is power. Power corrupts.

mrrunangun said...

Most (all?) academic types are keenly aware of the importance of grantsmanship as a basic skill. Knowing the appropriate funding sources and, in some cases, the interests and biases of funding sources, is stock in trade. Scientific research has become so capital intensive that large grants from government and large foundations are necessary to carry it out. For the most part, the biases of the granting institutions are known and discounted.

Even in science, when research into a controversial area has been ambiguous enough for sustained disagreement, it is common to find that a given research shop's work consistently comes down on one side of the controversy and another shop's work consistently on the opposing side of the controversy. In such cases, only people who follow the research in the area closely are likely to be aware of this. Usually time and technical improvements in measuring equipment puts controversies to rest, but the time is often measured in years. In these cases, the biases come from the leaders of the research shops rather than the grantors.

There are politics among granting institutions as well. These are less often political biases and more often they are of a personal nature, and since the people on a granting committee are necessarily expert in the field that the grantee will be working in, they will often be personally acquainted with the grant applicants. Not uncommonly, former students of the members of the committee.

Economics and long range climate science are necessarily model-based. Their short-term predictions are often proven wrong which casts doubt on the reliability of their long-term predictions. As a result, there may be legitimate differences of opinion as to the applicability of a particular model to a particular situation.

In the case of Mr Litan, the fact that he acknowledged that his study was funded by Capital and that he was testifying on behalf of the industry announce his bias.

GeorgeK said...

Tainted research is the norm in most industries, research dollar come from corporations that expect their interest to be served. Currently Monsanto emails show how heavy handed this pay for research problem has become. ...""Professors/researchers/scientists have a big white hat in this debate and support in their states, from politicians to producers," Bill Mashek, a vice president at Ketchum, a public relations firm hired by the biotechnology industry, said in an email to a University of Florida professor. "Keep it up!"...

http://www.nytimes.com/2015/09/06/us/food-industry-enlisted-academics-in-gmo-lobbying-war-emails-show.html

DeDude said...

The antidote to this kind of crap is the public funded University with tenured professors and sufficient resources (endowed Chairs) to conduct research without need to go out and get external funding for a study. As the public funding is reduced in order to give tax cuts to the rich plutocrats such truly independent research become more rare -and the plutocrats increasingly manage to own the facts.

[Oct 18, 2015] Everything You Need to Know about Laissez-Faire Economics -- Economist View discussion

Alan Kirman is a great economist. Amazingly clear exposition of complex subjects.
Notable quotes:
"... I think what happened was on the one hand people became obsessed with proving there was some sort of socially satisfactory situation that corresponded to markets in equilibrium, and on the other hand, there was a lot of effort made, right up to the 1950s, to try to show that a market or an economy would converge on that. But we gave up on that in the 70s when there were results that showed that essentially we couldnt prove it. So the theoreticians gave up but the underlying economic content and all of the ideology behind it has just kept going. We are in a strange situation where on the one hand we say we should leave markets to themselves because if they operate correctly and we get to an equilibrium this will be a socially satisfactory state. ..."
"... Nowadays, you hear all the time about how neoliberal ideology and thought is invading European countries and is undoing forms of governance that are actually working quite well. I work a lot in Norway and Scandinavia and there you hear all the time that Nordic model works and at the same time it is being corrupted by the neoliberal ideology, which is being spread in some sort of cancerous fashion. Please comment on that-Current neoliberalism. What justifies it? Is it spreading? Is that a good thing or a bad thing? Anything you would like to say on that topic. ..."
"... The idea that anything even close to laissez faire ever exisited is silly ..."
"... Laissez faire has never existed; it is code for when the govt allows the rich to trample the poor, and the govt actively sides with the rich ..."
"... Too often, efficiency is modeled too simply, failing to capture important benefits. You may make widgets with fewer workers and more unemployed but at the loss of workforce training, most of which is on the job. ..."
"... You can reduce unit labor costs, which usually means reducing wages. But that has all sorts of consequences, which are not perceived. ..."
"... If industry is freed by reducing their investment in human capital, replacement investment in human capital must come from elsewhere in higher taxes on business to pay for training that may be less effective. Else workforce quality declines and becomes a drag on overall economic efficiency. ..."
economistsview.typepad.com

A few excerpts from a much longer interview of Alan Kirman (it was in yesterday's links)

Everything You Need to Know about Laissez-Faire Economics: ... DSW: I'm so happy to talk with you about the concept of laissez faire, all the way back to its origin, which as I understand it is during the Enlightenment. ...

AK: I think the basic story that really interests us is that with the Enlightenment and with people like Adam Smith and David Hume, people had this idea that somehow intrinsically people should be left to their own devices and this would lead society to a state that was satisfactory in some sense for everybody, with some limits of course–law and order and so on. That's the idea that is underlying our whole social and philosophical position ever since. ... I think what happened was on the one hand people became obsessed with proving there was some sort of socially satisfactory situation that corresponded to markets in equilibrium, and on the other hand, there was a lot of effort made, right up to the 1950's, to try to show that a market or an economy would converge on that. But we gave up on that in the 70's when there were results that showed that essentially we couldn't prove it. So the theoreticians gave up but the underlying economic content and all of the ideology behind it has just kept going. We are in a strange situation where on the one hand we say we should leave markets to themselves because if they operate correctly and we get to an equilibrium this will be a socially satisfactory state. On the other hand, since we can't show that it gets there, we talk about economies that are in equilibrium but that's a contradiction because the invisible hand suggests that there is a mechanism that gets us there. And that's what we're lacking–a mechanism. ...

DSW: ...This has been a wonderful conversation, by the way. Nowadays, you hear all the time about how neoliberal ideology and thought is invading European countries and is undoing forms of governance that are actually working quite well. I work a lot in Norway and Scandinavia and there you hear all the time that Nordic model works and at the same time it is being corrupted by the neoliberal ideology, which is being spread in some sort of cancerous fashion. Please comment on that-Current neoliberalism. What justifies it? Is it spreading? Is that a good thing or a bad thing? Anything you would like to say on that topic.

AK: I think that one obsession that economists have is with efficiency. We're always, always, worrying about efficiency. People like to say that this is efficient or not efficient. The argument is, we know that if you free up markets you get a more efficient allocation of resources. That obsession with efficiency has led us to say that we must remove some of these restraints and restrictions and this sort of social aid that is built into the Scandinavian model. I think that's without thinking carefully about the consequences. ...

I think what has happened is, because of this mythology about totally free markets being efficient, we push for that all the time and in so doing, we started to do things like-for example, we hear all the time that we have to reform labor markets in Europe. Why do we want to reform them? Because then they'll be more competitive. You can reduce unit labor costs, which usually means reducing wages. But that has all sorts of consequences, which are not perceived. In model that is more complex, that sort of arrangement wouldn't necessarily be one that in your terms would be selected for. When you do that, you make many people temporary workers. You have complete ease in hiring and firing so that people are shifting jobs all the time. When they do that, we know that employers then invest nothing in their human capital. ... We're reducing the overall human capital in society by having an arrangement like that. ... Again, the idea that people who are out of work have chosen to be out of work and by giving them a social cushion you induce them to be out of work-that simply doesn't fit with the facts. I think that all the ramification of these measures-the side effects and external effects-all of that gets left out and we have this very simple framework that says "to be competitive, you just have to free everything up." That's what undermining the European system. European and Scandinavian systems work pretty well. ... The last remark I would make is that to say "you've got to get rid of all those rules and regulations you have"-in general, those rules and regulations are there for a reason. Again, to use an evolutionary argument, they didn't just appear, they got selected for. We put them in place because there was some problem, so just to remove them without thinking about why they are there doesn't make a lot of sense. ...

DSW: There's no invisible hand to save the day.

AK: (laughs). Joe Stiglitz used to say that we also need a visible hand. The visible hand is sometimes pretty useful. For example in the financial sector I think you really need a visible hand and not an invisible hand. ...

e abrams said...

The idea that anything even close to laissez faire ever exisited is silly

at all stages, the gov't actively intervened in the economy; eg, look at the rules for labor unions....

Laissez faire has never existed; it is code for when the gov't allows the rich to trample the poor, and the gov't actively sides with the rich

bakho said...

I enjoyed the interview with Kirman. Thanks for posting.

Too often, efficiency is modeled too simply, failing to capture important benefits. You may make widgets with fewer workers and more unemployed but at the loss of workforce training, most of which is on the job. This is important:

You can reduce unit labor costs, which usually means reducing wages. But that has all sorts of consequences, which are not perceived. In model that is more complex, that sort of arrangement wouldn't necessarily be one that in your terms would be selected for. When ... you make many people temporary workers.... so that people are shifting jobs all the time. ..employers then invest nothing in their human capital. ... We're reducing the overall human capital in society .. If you're working for ... all your lifetime, they probably invest quite a lot in you. ... it is a much more stable arrangement. .. the ramification of these measures-the side effects and external effects... gets left out and we have this very simple framework that says "to be competitive, you just have to free everything up."

If industry is freed by reducing their investment in human capital, replacement investment in human capital must come from elsewhere in higher taxes on business to pay for training that may be less effective. Else workforce quality declines and becomes a drag on overall economic efficiency.

[Oct 18, 2015] Alan Kirman interview: everything You Need to Know about Laissez-Faire Economics

Notable quotes:
"... That's the idea that is underlying our whole social and philosophical position ever since. Economics is trying to run along side that. Initially the idea was to let everybody do what they want and this would somehow self-organize. But nobody said what the mechanism was that would do the self-organization. John Stewart Mill advanced the same position. He had the idea that people had to be given, as far as their role would permit, the possibility of doing their own thing, and this would be in the interests of everybody. And gradually we came up against this difficulty that we couldn't show economically, in a market for example, how we would ever get to such a position. I think what happened was on the one hand people became obsessed with proving there was some sort of socially satisfactory situation that corresponded to markets in equilibrium, and on the other hand, there was a lot of effort made, right up to the 1950's, to try to show that a market or an economy would converge on that. But we gave up on that in the 70's when there were results that showed that essentially we couldn't prove it. So the theoreticians gave up but the underlying economic content and all of the ideology behind it has just kept going. We are in a strange situation where on the one hand we say we should leave markets to themselves because if they operate correctly and we get to an equilibrium this will be a socially satisfactory state. On the other hand, since we can't show that it gets there, we talk about economies that are in equilibrium but that's a contradiction because the invisible hand suggests that there is a mechanism that gets us there. And that's what we're lacking–a mechanism. Is that clear more or less? ..."
"... Theory of Moral Sentiments ..."
"... Nowadays, if you take a very primitive version of the invisible hand, people say something like "greed is good". Somehow, if everyone is greedy and tries to serve their own interest, it will get to a good position socially. Adam Smith didn't have that view at all. He had the view that people have other things in mind. For example he said that one of the strongest motivations men have is to be seen to be a good citizen and therefore would do things that would appear to other people to be good. If you have motivations like that then you can be altruistic and you're not behaving like the strict Homo economicus ..."
"... Walras wasn't someone who pushed hard for laissez faire, but he started to build the weapons for trying to understand whether all markets could get into equilibrium. He wasn't so interested, himself, on whether the equilibrium was good for society; in other words, Adam Smith's original position. I would say that Walras was more a person who was worried about the very existence of equilibrium and he tried desperately at various points to show how we might get there. I don't think he was arguing in favor of laissez faire. I wouldn't regard Walras as being strictly in that tradition. ..."
"... Pareto was concerned about the idea of the invisible hand himself. He said: "Look, what I want to show you is that the competitive equilibrium is a social optimum. He was the person to define what we now call a Pareto optimum, a situation in which you cannot make one person better off without making somebody else worse off-which is a pretty weak criterion, but still is a criterion for some sort of social efficiency. He was interested in the relationship between the two, so he brought us back on track to what I interpret as the invisible hand. Then, we can make a huge jump it you want to the first theorem of welfare of economics. That, mistakenly, is often referred to as the invisible hand theorem. But it is nothing about the invisible hand. It just says that if you are in a competitive equilibrium, then that will be a Pareto optimum, in the sense that I have just mentioned. You couldn't make someone better off without making someone else worse off. That's all it says. It does not say that if you leave a society alone it will get there, but thousands of people have interpreted it in that way. ..."
"... He had a different position from Walras company and he wasn't very consistent in his views. According to Hayek, Walras said that nobody influences prices but take prices as given, and then somebody, not specified, adjusts them until they get to equilibrium. There is some mechanism out there. ..."
"... The Road to Serfdom ..."
"... He believed that people with little information of their own, like ants, would somehow collectively get it right. It was a very different view of the world than Walras. ..."
"... he was a pioneer in two respects. First of all, he grasped the idea of self-organizing and decentralized processes-that the intelligence is in the system, not in any individual, and secondly cultural group selection, that the reason economic systems were like this is because of some past history of better systems replacing worse systems. The wisdom of the system was the product of cultural group selection, as we would put it today, and that we shouldn't question its wisdom by tampering with it. Is that a fair thing to say? ..."
"... Yes, that's a fair thing to say and I think it is what Hayek believed. He didn't actually show how it would happen but you're absolutely right-I think that's what he believed and he thought tampering with this system would make it less perfect and work less well, so just leave it alone. I don't think he had in mind, strictly speaking, group-level selection, but that's clearly his idea. A system that works well will eventually come to outstrip other systems. That's why he was advising Thatcher. ..."
"... He was much less naïve than Friedman. Friedman has a primitive natural selection argument that if firms aren't doing better than other firms they'll go bust and just die. That's a summary of Friedman's evolutionary argument! But Hayek is much more sophisticated-you're absolutely right. ..."
"... Friedman and Hayek didn't see eye to eye at all, as I understand it. Hayek was actually very concerned that Friedman and other mathematical economists took over the Mont Pelerin Society, if I understand it correctly, but now let's put Friedman on center stage, and also the society as a whole and the creation of all the think tanks, which caused the society to become politically influential. ..."
"... "Greed is Good" sounds so simplistic, but what all of this seems to do is to provide some moral justification for individuals or corporations to pursue their own interests with a clear conscience. It's a moral justification for "Greed is Good", despite all of the complexities and all of the mathematics-that's what it seems to come down to. Am I wrong about that? ..."
"... Macroeconomic models are still all about equilibria, don't worry about how we got them, and their nice efficient properties, and so forth. They are nothing to do with distribution and nothing to do with disequilibrium. Two big strands of thought-Keynes and all the people who work on disequilibrium-they're just out of it. We're still working as if underlying all of this, greed-we don't want to call it greed, but something like greed-is good. ..."
"... Nowadays, you hear all the time about how neoliberal ideology and thought is invading European countries and is undoing forms of governance that are actually working quite well. I work a lot in Norway and Scandinavia and there you hear all the time that Nordic model works and at the same time it is being corrupted by the neoliberal ideology, which is being spread in some sort of cancerous fashion. Please comment on that-Current neoliberalism. ..."
"... We're always, always, worrying about efficiency. People like to say that this is efficient or not efficient. The argument is, we know that if you free up markets you get a more efficient allocation of resources. That obsession with efficiency has led us to say that we must remove some of these restraints and restrictions and this sort of social aid that is built into the Scandinavian model. I think that's without thinking carefully about the consequences. ..."
"... just to make my position clear, the idea of no regulations is absurd. For a system that is basically well adapted to its environment, then most of its regulations are there for a reason, as you say, but one of the things that everyone needs to know about evolution is that a lot of junk accumulates. There is junk DNA and there is junk regulations. Not every regulation has a purpose just because it's there, and when it comes to adapting to the future, that's a matter of new regulations and picking the right one out of many that are wrong. The question would be, how do you create smart regulations? Knowing that you need regulations, how do you create smart ones? That's our challenge and the challenge of someone who appreciates complexity, as you do. How would you respond to that? ..."
evonomics.com

What you always wanted to know about the "let it be" philosophy

I'll bet money that Alan Kirman is the only economist with animated ants running around his email signature. Highly regarded by mainstream economists, he is also a critic of equilibrium theory and proponent of new economic thinking that takes complex systems theory into account. It was my privilege to work with Alan and Germany's Ernst Strungmann Forum to organize a conference titled "Complexity and Evolution: A New Synthesis for Economics" that was held in February 2015 and will result in a volume published by the MIT press in 2016.

After the conference was over, I sought Alan out to help me understand the complex history of laissez faire, the "let it be" philosophy that underlies mainstream economic theory and public policy.

DSW: I'm so happy to talk with you about the concept of laissez faire, all the way back to its origin, which as I understand it is during the Enlightenment. Then we can bring it up to date with some of its formalized versions in economic theory. Tell me what you know about the early history of laissez faire.

AK: I think the basic story that really interests us is that with the Enlightenment and with people like Adam Smith and David Hume, people had this idea that somehow intrinsically people should be left to their own devices and this would lead society to a state that was satisfactory in some sense for everybody, with some limits of course–law and order and so on. That's the idea that is underlying our whole social and philosophical position ever since. Economics is trying to run along side that. Initially the idea was to let everybody do what they want and this would somehow self-organize. But nobody said what the mechanism was that would do the self-organization. John Stewart Mill advanced the same position. He had the idea that people had to be given, as far as their role would permit, the possibility of doing their own thing, and this would be in the interests of everybody. And gradually we came up against this difficulty that we couldn't show economically, in a market for example, how we would ever get to such a position. I think what happened was on the one hand people became obsessed with proving there was some sort of socially satisfactory situation that corresponded to markets in equilibrium, and on the other hand, there was a lot of effort made, right up to the 1950's, to try to show that a market or an economy would converge on that. But we gave up on that in the 70's when there were results that showed that essentially we couldn't prove it. So the theoreticians gave up but the underlying economic content and all of the ideology behind it has just kept going. We are in a strange situation where on the one hand we say we should leave markets to themselves because if they operate correctly and we get to an equilibrium this will be a socially satisfactory state. On the other hand, since we can't show that it gets there, we talk about economies that are in equilibrium but that's a contradiction because the invisible hand suggests that there is a mechanism that gets us there. And that's what we're lacking–a mechanism. Is that clear more or less?

DSW: Yes, but it was very fast! I want to pull us back to the early times and make a couple of observations. First of all, that the first thinking about laissez faire came at a time when government was monarchy and absolutist rule. The whole struggle of the Enlightenment, to have a more egalitarian and inclusive society, was part of this. Am I right about that?

AK: Absolutely right. There was a social and philosophical revolution, precisely because of that. Men were trying to liberate themselves from a very hierarchical and monarchical organization. And economics tried to go along with that. There were good reasons and I think that even now there is no reason to say that there is anything wrong with the liberal position. On the other hand, what we can't show is that there is anything that would enable a liberal approach like that to get things under control. So you're right. It was a reaction to very autocratic systems that led the whole of the laissez faire and liberal position to develop.

DSW: Right. So laissez faire made a lot of sense against the background of monarchy and controlling church and so on. Now I know that Adam Smith invoked the invisible hand metaphor only three times in the entire corpus of his work and it is said that his first book on moral sentiments is much more nuanced than the popular notion of the invisible hand. Could you speak a little more on Adam Smith? On the one hand he's an advocate of laissez faire but on the other hand he is very nuanced in both of his books but especially in his Theory of Moral Sentiments. What do you have to say about that?

AK: Right. Adam Smith was fully cognizant of the fact that man is motivated by many things. Nowadays, if you take a very primitive version of the invisible hand, people say something like "greed is good". Somehow, if everyone is greedy and tries to serve their own interest, it will get to a good position socially. Adam Smith didn't have that view at all. He had the view that people have other things in mind. For example he said that one of the strongest motivations men have is to be seen to be a good citizen and therefore would do things that would appear to other people to be good. If you have motivations like that then you can be altruistic and you're not behaving like the strict Homo economicus. Adam Smith didn't take the strong position that people left entirely to their own selfish devices will make things OK. He had the view that man is much more complicated and governed by his emotions. He talks a lot about sympathy, which we would now call empathy.

DSW: That's great! Now let's talk about Walras and what his ambitions were to come up with the first mathematical justification for laissez faire, as I understand it.

AK: Actually, Walras himself didn't talk so much about laissez faire. He at that time had a very simple idea, that the amount of goods that people wanted to supply at a given price would be the amount that people would want to buy; i.e, demand at that price, so if those two were equal then that was the equilibrium price. Then he said that if we have many markets, how can we be sure that they will simultaneously be cleared, because after all if you raise the price in one market then that will effect the price in other markets. If you raise the price of bananas then the price of oranges will be effected, and so forth. He said "my problem is to solve the market clearing for all goods", but he was not so interested in the underlying philosophical context. Walras wasn't someone who pushed hard for laissez faire, but he started to build the weapons for trying to understand whether all markets could get into equilibrium. He wasn't so interested, himself, on whether the equilibrium was good for society; in other words, Adam Smith's original position. I would say that Walras was more a person who was worried about the very existence of equilibrium and he tried desperately at various points to show how we might get there. I don't think he was arguing in favor of laissez faire. I wouldn't regard Walras as being strictly in that tradition.

DSW: OK, that's new for me. So what about the rise of so-called neoclassical economics. At what point did it become toward demonstrating what I understand is the first fundamental theorem of economics-laissez faire leads to the common good and that being justified by some mathematical apparatus. Where does that come from, if not from Walras?

AK: We missed a very important step, which is [Vilfredo] Pareto. Pareto was concerned about the idea of the invisible hand himself. He said: "Look, what I want to show you is that the competitive equilibrium is a social optimum. He was the person to define what we now call a Pareto optimum, a situation in which you cannot make one person better off without making somebody else worse off-which is a pretty weak criterion, but still is a criterion for some sort of social efficiency. He was interested in the relationship between the two, so he brought us back on track to what I interpret as the invisible hand. Then, we can make a huge jump it you want to the first theorem of welfare of economics. That, mistakenly, is often referred to as the invisible hand theorem. But it is nothing about the invisible hand. It just says that if you are in a competitive equilibrium, then that will be a Pareto optimum, in the sense that I have just mentioned. You couldn't make someone better off without making someone else worse off. That's all it says. It does not say that if you leave a society alone it will get there, but thousands of people have interpreted it in that way.

DSW: OK. So where do we go from here? Tell me a little about agency theory, which is also something that seems to imply, if I understand it, that the only responsibility of corporations is to maximize their profits. The economy will work well if that's their only obligation.

AK: That's not exactly a sideline but a development where people are worrying about firms in addition to individuals. When you are just dealing with individuals in a simple economy, when they are exchanging goods there is no problem. When you get firms in there you need to ask "What's the objectives of these firms?" The objective, the argument is, is if they maximize profit then they are maximizing their shareholders' benefits and so therefore we get to the idea of increasing the welfare of society as a whole. But there is a huge leap there, because we haven't specified closely in our models who owns these firms and how ownership is transferred between these people. So I think there is a fuzzy area there, which is not completely included in the theory.

DSW: Please give me a thumbnail history of the Mont Pelerin Society and the role it played in advancing economic theory and policy. So this would be Hayek, Friedman and all that.

AK: The great hero of that society was Hayek. He had a different position from Walras & company and he wasn't very consistent in his views. According to Hayek, Walras said that nobody influences prices but take prices as given, and then somebody, not specified, adjusts them until they get to equilibrium. There is some mechanism out there. That was Walras. Hayek said "Not at all!" He said - actually he was a horrid man.

DSW: Wait a minute! Why was he a horrid man? You can't just glide over that!

AK: The reason I say that is-he had very clever ideas-but he was extremely bigoted, he was racist. There is a wonderful interview with him that you can find on You Tube, where he says (imitating Hayek's accent) "I am not a racist! People accuse me of being a racist. Now it's true that some of the Indian students at the London School of Economics behave in a very nasty way, typical of Indian people…" and he carries on like this. So that's one reason he is horrid. A second thing is that if you don't believe he is horrid, David, I will send you his book The Road to Serfdom, which said that if there is any planning going on in the economy, it will inevitably lead you to a fascist situation. When he produced that book it had a big success, particularly in the United States, and what is more, he authorized a comic book version of it, which is absolutely dreadful. One Nobel Prize winner, [Ronald] Coase, said "you are carrying on so much against central planning, you forget that a large part of our economy is actually governed by centrally planned institutions, i.e., big firms, and these big firms are doing exactly what you say they can't do. Hayek shrugged that off, but what he did in his book was say that if any planning goes on then eventually you are all going to wind up in a fascist state where you'll be shot if you don't do what you're told to do. At the end of the book there is some poor guy who's being shot because he wants to be a carpenter or a plumber, or something like that. It's terrible! And the irony of the whole situation is that comic book was issued and financed by General Motors, and GM of course is one of those corporations that Hayek didn't see were centrally planned institutions. That's way I say that Hayek was a dreadful person.

Hayek's idea was, there is no way that people could know what was going on and could know what the prices of goods are. Everyone has a little piece of information of their own, and in acting upon it, this news gets out into the market. So, for example I buy something such as a share, and you say "Oh, Kirman bought a share, so something must be going on there, based on information that he had that I didn't have", and so forth. Hayek's idea was that this mechanism-people watching each other and getting information from their acts, would lead you to the equilibrium that would be a socially optimal state. But again, he never specified closely what the mechanism was. He has little examples, such as one about shortage of tin and how people would adjust, but never really specified the mechanism. He believed that people with little information of their own, like ants, would somehow collectively get it right. It was a very different view of the world than Walras.

DSW: So he was a pioneer in two respects. First of all, he grasped the idea of self-organizing and decentralized processes-that the intelligence is in the system, not in any individual, and secondly cultural group selection, that the reason economic systems were like this is because of some past history of better systems replacing worse systems. The wisdom of the system was the product of cultural group selection, as we would put it today, and that we shouldn't question its wisdom by tampering with it. Is that a fair thing to say?

AK: Yes, that's a fair thing to say and I think it is what Hayek believed. He didn't actually show how it would happen but you're absolutely right-I think that's what he believed and he thought tampering with this system would make it less perfect and work less well, so just leave it alone. I don't think he had in mind, strictly speaking, group-level selection, but that's clearly his idea. A system that works well will eventually come to outstrip other systems. That's why he was advising Thatcher. Just trust the markets and let things go. Get rid of the unions, and so forth. So it's clearly he had in mind that interfering with that system would just lead you to a worse social situation. He was much less naïve than Friedman. Friedman has a primitive natural selection argument that if firms aren't doing better than other firms they'll go bust and just die. That's a summary of Friedman's evolutionary argument! But Hayek is much more sophisticated-you're absolutely right.

DSW: I think Hayek was explicit about cultural group selection, and Friedman-I've paid quite a bit of attention to his 1953 article on positive economics, in which he makes a very naïve evolutionary argument. Friedman and Hayek didn't see eye to eye at all, as I understand it. Hayek was actually very concerned that Friedman and other mathematical economists took over the Mont Pelerin Society, if I understand it correctly, but now let's put Friedman on center stage, and also the society as a whole and the creation of all the think tanks, which caused the society to become politically influential.

AK: Yes, I think that it coincided very nicely with conservative ideology and people who had really strongly liberal-not in the Mills sense (you have to make this distinction particularly in the United States where these words have different meanings), but really completely free market leave-everybody-to-their own-thing libertarian point of view. Those people found it a wonderful place to gather and reinforce themselves. And Hayek was a strong member of that. Another was Gary Becker, but I don't know how directly. Becker had the economics of everything-divorce, whatever. You'd have these simple arguments, but not necessarily selection arguments, often some sort of justification in terms of a superior arrangement. The marginal utility of the woman getting divorced just has to equal the marginal utility of not getting divorced and that would be the price of getting divorced, and that sort of stuff. Adam Smith would have rolled over in this grave because he believed emotions played a strong role in all of this and the emotions that you have during divorce don't tie into these strict calculations.

DSW: This is a tailor-made ideology for powerful interests, powerful people and corporations who simply do want to have their way. Is that a false statement to make?

AK: No, I think that's absolutely right. They can benefit from using that argument to advance their own ends. As someone once said, if you think of saying to firms, we're going to diminish their taxes, no firm in its right mind would argue with that. Even though they might think deep down that there are other things that could be done for society. There are some things which are part of this philosophy which is perfect for firms and powerful interest groups. You're absolutely right. And so they lobby for this all the time, pushing for these positions that are in fact in their own interest.

DSW: So, at the end of the day, "Greed is Good" sounds so simplistic, but what all of this seems to do is to provide some moral justification for individuals or corporations to pursue their own interests with a clear conscience. It's a moral justification for "Greed is Good", despite all of the complexities and all of the mathematics-that's what it seems to come down to. Am I wrong about that?

AK: I think you're absolutely right. What's interesting is that if you look at various economic situations, like today the first thing that people tell you about the Greeks is that they are horrid ideological people. But the people on the other side have an equally strong ideology, which is being justified by the sort of economic models that we are building. Remember that even though we had this discussion about how this became a real difficulty in theoretical economics, in macroeconomics they simply carried on as if these theoretical difficulties hadn't happened. Macroeconomic models are still all about equilibria, don't worry about how we got them, and their nice efficient properties, and so forth. They are nothing to do with distribution and nothing to do with disequilibrium. Two big strands of thought-Keynes and all the people who work on disequilibrium-they're just out of it. We're still working as if underlying all of this, greed-we don't want to call it greed, but something like greed-is good.

DSW: Could I ask about Ayn Rand and what role she played, if any? On the one hand she was not an economist, she was just a philosopher and novelist. On the other hand, she is right up there in the pantheon of free market deities alone with Smith, Hayek and Friedman. Do you ever think about Ayn Rand. Does any economist think about Ayn Rand?

AK: That's an example of my narrowness that I never read Ayn Rand, I just read about her. I think it would be unfair now to make any comments about that because I'd be as uninformed as some people who talk about Adam Smith. What I should do at some point is read some of her work, because she is constantly being cited on both sides as a dark bad figure or as a heroine in the pantheon as you said, with Hayek and everybody else. I just admit my ignorance and I don't know if Rand had a serious position on her own or whether she is being cited as a more popular and easily accessible figure.

DSW: Fine! I'd like to wrap this up with two questions. This has been a wonderful conversation, by the way. Nowadays, you hear all the time about how neoliberal ideology and thought is invading European countries and is undoing forms of governance that are actually working quite well. I work a lot in Norway and Scandinavia and there you hear all the time that Nordic model works and at the same time it is being corrupted by the neoliberal ideology, which is being spread in some sort of cancerous fashion. Please comment on that-Current neoliberalism. What justifies it? Is it spreading? Is that a good thing or a bad thing? Anything you would like to say on that topic.

AK: I think that one obsession that economists have is with efficiency. We're always, always, worrying about efficiency. People like to say that this is efficient or not efficient. The argument is, we know that if you free up markets you get a more efficient allocation of resources. That obsession with efficiency has led us to say that we must remove some of these restraints and restrictions and this sort of social aid that is built into the Scandinavian model. I think that's without thinking carefully about the consequences. Let me tell you my favorite and probably not very funny story about how economists are obsessed with efficiency. There were three people playing golf; a priest, a psychoanalyst, and an economist. The got very upset because the guy in front was playing extremely slowly and he had a caddy to help him. So these guys get very upset and they start to shout and say "Come on, can we play through please! You can't waste all of our afternoon!" They sent the priest up to find out what was going on and he came back absolutely crestfallen and said "You know why that poor guy is laying so slowly? It's because he's blind. I'm so upset because every Sunday I'm preaching to people to be nice to others." He turns to his psychoanalyst friend and say's "Joe, what do you think?" Joe says "I have these guys on my coach every week. I'm trying to help them live with this problem and here I am screaming at this guy. It's horrible!" Then they turn to the economist and say "Fred, what do you think?" Fred says "I think that this situation is totally inefficient. This guy should play at night!" As you can see, this is a very different attitude to how the world works.

I think what has happened is, because of this mythology about totally free markets being efficient, we push for that all the time and in so doing, we started to do things like-for example, we hear all the time that we have to reform labor markets in Europe. Why do we want to reform them? Because then they'll be more competitive. You can reduce unit labor costs, which usually means reducing wages. But that has all sorts of consequences, which are not perceived. In model that is more complex, that sort of arrangement wouldn't necessarily be one that in your terms would be selected for. When you do that, you make many people temporary workers. You have complete ease in hiring and firing so that people are shifting jobs all the time. When they do that, we know that employers then invest nothing in their human capital. When you have a guy who may disappear tomorrow-and we have a lot of these temporary agencies now in Europe–which send you people when you need them and take away people when you don't. Employers don't spend anything on human capital. We're reducing the overall human capital in society by having an arrangement like that. If you're working for Toyota, Toyota knows pretty much that you'll be working all your lifetime, so they probably invest quite a lot in you. They make you work hard for that, but nevertheless it is a much more stable arrangement. Again, the idea that people who are out of work have chosen to be out of work and by giving them a social cushion you induce them to be out of work-that simply doesn't fit with the facts. I think that all the ramification of these measures-the side effects and external effects-all of that gets left out and we have this very simple framework that says "to be competitive, you just have to free everything up." That's what undermining the European system. European and Scandinavian systems work pretty well. Unemployment is not that high in the Scandinavian system. It may be a little bit less efficient but it may also be a society where people are a little bit more at ease with themselves, than they are in a society where they are constantly worrying about what will happen to them next. The last remark I would make is that to say "you've got to get rid of all those rules and regulations you have"-in general, those rules and regulations are there for a reason. Again, to use an evolutionary argument, they didn't just appear, they got selected for. We put them in place because there was some problem, so just to remove them without thinking about why they are there doesn't make a lot of sense.

DSW: Right, but at the same time, a regulation is a like a mutation: for every one that's beneficial there are a hundred that are deleterious. So…

AK: You are an American, deep at heart! You believe that all these regulations are dreadful. Think of regulations about not allowing people to work too near a chain saw that's going full blast, or not being allowed to work with asbestos and so forth. Those rules, I think, have a reason to be there.

DSW: Well of course, but just to make my position clear, the idea of no regulations is absurd. For a system that is basically well adapted to its environment, then most of its regulations are there for a reason, as you say, but one of the things that everyone needs to know about evolution is that a lot of junk accumulates. There is junk DNA and there is junk regulations. Not every regulation has a purpose just because it's there, and when it comes to adapting to the future, that's a matter of new regulations and picking the right one out of many that are wrong. The question would be, how do you create smart regulations? Knowing that you need regulations, how do you create smart ones? That's our challenge and the challenge of someone who appreciates complexity, as you do. How would you respond to that?

AK: I think you're absolutely right. It's absolutely clear that as these regulations accumulate, they weren't developed in harmony with each other, so you often get even contradictory regulations. Every now and then, simplifying them is hugely beneficial. But that doesn't mean getting rid of regulations in general. It means somehow managing to choose between them, and that's not necessarily a natural process. For example, in France when I arrived here it used to take about a day and a half to make my tax return. Now it takes around about 20 minutes, because some sensible guy realized that you could simplify this whole thing and you could put a lot of stuff already into the form which they have received. They have a lot of information from your employer and so forth. They've simplified it to a point where it takes me about 20 minutes a year to do my tax return. It used to take a huge amount of time.

DSW: Nice!

AK: What's interesting is that you have some intelligent person saying "let's look at this and see if we can't make these rules much simpler, and they did. I have conflicting views, like you. These things are usually there for a reason, so you shouldn't just throw them away, but how do you select between them. I don't think that they necessarily select themselves out.

DSW: I would amend what you said. You said that some intelligent person figured out how to make the tax system work better in France. Probably not just a single intelligent person. Probably it was an intelligent process, which included intelligent people, but I think that gets us back to the idea that we need systemic processes to evaluate and select so that we become adaptable systems. But that will be systemic thing, not a smart individual.

AK: You're absolutely right. I shouldn't have said smart individual because what surely happened was that there was a lot of pressure on the people who handle all of these things, and gradually together they realized that this situation was becoming one where their work was becoming almost impossible to achieve in the time available. So there was some collective pressure that led them to form committees and things that thought about this and got it together. So it was a natural process of a system, but it wasn't the rules themselves that selected themselves out, as it were. It was the collectivity that evolved in that way to make it simpler.

DSW: There's no invisible hand to save the day.

AK: (laughs). Joe Stiglitz used to say that we also need a visible hand. The visible hand is sometimes pretty useful. For example in the financial sector I think you really need a visible hand and not an invisible hand.

DSW. That's great and a perfect way to end. I'm so happy to have had this conversation, Alan, and to be working with you at the conference we just staged and into the future.

AK: A pleasure. Always good to talk with you.

Alan Kirman is professor emeritus of Economics at the University of Aix-Marseille III and at the Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales and is a member of the Institut Universitaire de France. His Ph.D. is from Princeton and he has been professor of economics at Johns Hopkins University, the Universite Libre de Bruxelles, Warwick University, and the European University Institute in Florence, Italy. He was elected a fellow of the Econometric Society and of the European Economic Association and was awarded the Humboldt Prize in Germany. He is member of the Institute for Advanced Study in Princeton. He has published 150 articles in international scientific journals. He also is the author and editor of twelve books, most recently Complex Economics: Individual and Collective Rationality, which was published by Routledge in July 2010.

[Oct 18, 2015] What Prosperity Is, Where Growth Comes from, Why Markets Work

Notable quotes:
"... In 1959, noted American economist Moses Abramovitz cautioned that "we must be highly skeptical of the view that long-term changes in the rate of growth of welfare can be gauged even roughly from changes in the rate of growth of output." ..."
"... In 2009, a commission of leading economists convened by President Nicolas Sarkozy of France and chaired by Nobel laureate Joseph Stiglitz reported on the inadequacies of GDP. They noted well-known issues such as the fact that GDP does not capture changes in the quality of the products (think of mobile phones over the past 20 years) or the value of unpaid labor (caring for an elderly parent in the home). The commission also cited evidence that GDP growth does not always correlate with increases in measures of well-being such as health or self-reported happiness, and concluded that growing GDP can have deleterious effects on the environment. ..."
"... Our issue isn't with GDP per se. As the English say, "It does what it says on the tin"-it measures economic activity or output. Rather, our issue is with the nature of that activity itself. Our question is whether the activities of our economy that are counted in GDP are truly enhancing the prosperity of our society. ..."
"... Robert Shiller of Yale University, who ironically shared this year's Nobel with Fama, showed in the early 1980s that stock market prices did not always reflect fundamental value, and sometimes big gaps could open up between the two. ..."
"... And therein lies the difference between a poor society and a prosperous one. It isn't the amount of money that a society has in circulation, whether dollars, euros, beads, or wampum. Rather, it is the availability of the things that create well-being-like antibiotics, air conditioning, safe food, the ability to travel, and even frivolous things like video games. It is the availability of these "solutions" to human problems-things that make life better on a relative basis-that makes us prosperous. ..."
"... This is why prosperity in human societies can't be properly understood by just looking at monetary measures of income or wealth. Prosperity in a society is the accumulation of solutions to human problems. ..."
December 1, 2014 | Democracy Journal ( also reprinted in Evonomics )

The Price of Everything, the Value of Nothing

The most basic measure we have of economic growth is gross domestic product. GDP was developed from the work in the 1930s of the American economist Simon Kuznets and it became the standard way to measure economic output following the 1944 Bretton Woods conference. But from the beginning, Kuznets and other economists highlighted that GDP was not a measure of prosperity. In 1959, noted American economist Moses Abramovitz cautioned that "we must be highly skeptical of the view that long-term changes in the rate of growth of welfare can be gauged even roughly from changes in the rate of growth of output."

In 2009, a commission of leading economists convened by President Nicolas Sarkozy of France and chaired by Nobel laureate Joseph Stiglitz reported on the inadequacies of GDP. They noted well-known issues such as the fact that GDP does not capture changes in the quality of the products (think of mobile phones over the past 20 years) or the value of unpaid labor (caring for an elderly parent in the home). The commission also cited evidence that GDP growth does not always correlate with increases in measures of well-being such as health or self-reported happiness, and concluded that growing GDP can have deleterious effects on the environment. Some countries have experimented with other metrics to augment GDP, such as Bhutan's "gross national happiness index."

Our issue isn't with GDP per se. As the English say, "It does what it says on the tin"-it measures economic activity or output. Rather, our issue is with the nature of that activity itself. Our question is whether the activities of our economy that are counted in GDP are truly enhancing the prosperity of our society.

Since the field's beginnings, economists have been concerned with why one thing has more value than another, and what conditions lead to greater prosperity-or social welfare, as economists call it. Adam Smith's famous diamond-water paradox showed that quite often the market price of a thing does not always reflect intuitive notions of its intrinsic value-diamonds, with little intrinsic value, are typically far more expensive than water, which is essential for life. This is of course where markets come into play-in most places, water is more abundant than diamonds, and so the law of supply and demand determines that water is cheaper.

After lots of debate about the nature of economic value in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, economists considered the issue largely settled by the mid-twentieth century. The great French economist Gerard Debreu argued in his 1959 Theory of Value that if markets are competitive and people are rational and have good information, then markets will automatically sort everything out, ensuring that prices reflect supply and demand and allocate everything in such a way that everyone's welfare is maximized, and that no one can be made better off without making someone else worse off. In essence, the market price of something reflects a collective judgment of the value of that thing. The idea of intrinsic value was always problematic because it was inherently relative and hard to observe or measure. But market prices are cold hard facts. If market prices provide a collective societal judgment of value and allocate goods to their most efficient and welfare-maximizing uses, then we no longer have to worry about squishy ideas like intrinsic value; we just need to look at the price of something to know its value.

Debreu was apolitical about his theory-in fact, he saw it as an exercise in abstract mathematics and repeatedly warned about over-interpreting its applicability to real-world economies. However, his work, as well as related work in that era by figures such as Kenneth Arrow and Paul Samuelson, laid the foundations for economists such as Milton Friedman and Robert Lucas, who provided a devastating critique of Keynesianism in the 1960s and '70s, and recent Nobel laureate Eugene Fama, who pioneered the theory of efficient markets in finance in the 1970s and '80s. According to the neoclassical theory that emerged from this era, if markets are efficient and thus "welfare-maximizing," then it follows that we should minimize any distortions that move society away from this optimal state, whether it is companies engaging in monopolistic behavior, unions interfering with labor markets, or governments creating distortions through taxes and regulation.

These ideas became the intellectual touchstone of a resurgent conservative movement in the 1980s and led to a wave of financial market deregulation that continued through the 1990s up until the crash of 2008. Under this logic, if financial markets are the most competitive and efficient markets in the world, then they should be minimally regulated. And innovations like complex derivatives must be valuable, not just to the bankers earning big fees from creating them, but to those buying them and to society as a whole. Any interference will reduce the efficiency of the market and reduce the welfare of society. Likewise the enormous pay packets of the hedge-fund managers trading those derivatives must reflect the value they are adding to society - they are making the market more efficient. In efficient markets, if someone is willing to pay for something, it must be valuable. Price and value are effectively the same thing.

Even before the crash, some economists were beginning to question these ideas. Robert Shiller of Yale University, who ironically shared this year's Nobel with Fama, showed in the early 1980s that stock market prices did not always reflect fundamental value, and sometimes big gaps could open up between the two. Likewise, behavioral economists like Daniel Kahneman began showing that real people didn't behave in the hyper-rational way that Debreu's theory assumed. Other researchers in the 1980s and '90s, even Debreu's famous co-author Arrow, began to question the whole notion of the economy naturally moving to a resting point or "equilibrium" where everyone's welfare is optimized.

An emerging twenty-first century view of the economy is that it is a dynamic, constantly evolving, highly complex system-more like an ecosystem than a machine. In such a system, markets may be highly innovative and effective, but they can sometimes be far from efficient. And likewise, people may be clever, but they can sometimes be far from rational. So if markets are not always efficient and people are not always rational, then the twentieth century mantra that price equals value may not be right either. If this is the case, then what do terms like value, wealth, growth, and prosperity mean?

Prosperity Isn't Money, It's Solutions

In every society, some people are better off than others. Discerning the differences is simple. When someone has more money than most other people, we call him wealthy. But an important distinction must be drawn between this kind of relative wealth and the societal wealth that we term "prosperity." What it takes to make a society prosperous is far more complex than what it takes to make one individual better off than another.

Most of us intuitively believe that the more money people have in a society, the more prosperous that society must be. America's average household disposable income in 2010 was $38,001 versus $28,194 for Canada; therefore America is more prosperous than Canada.

But the idea that prosperity is simply "having money" can be easily disproved with a simple thought experiment. (This thought experiment and other elements of this section are adapted from Eric Beinhocker's The Origin of Wealth, Harvard Business School Press, 2006.) Imagine you had the $38,001 income of a typical American but lived in a village among the Yanomami people, an isolated hunter-gatherer tribe deep in the Brazilian rainforest. You'd easily be the richest Yanomamian (they don't use money but anthropologists estimate their standard of living at the equivalent of about $90 per year). But you'd still feel a lot poorer than the average American. Even after you'd fixed up your mud hut, bought the best clay pots in the village, and eaten the finest Yanomami cuisine, all of your riches still wouldn't get you antibiotics, air conditioning, or a comfy bed. And yet, even the poorest American typically has access to these crucial elements of well-being.

And therein lies the difference between a poor society and a prosperous one. It isn't the amount of money that a society has in circulation, whether dollars, euros, beads, or wampum. Rather, it is the availability of the things that create well-being-like antibiotics, air conditioning, safe food, the ability to travel, and even frivolous things like video games. It is the availability of these "solutions" to human problems-things that make life better on a relative basis-that makes us prosperous.

This is why prosperity in human societies can't be properly understood by just looking at monetary measures of income or wealth. Prosperity in a society is the accumulation of solutions to human problems.

These solutions run from the prosaic, like a crunchier potato chip, to the profound, like cures for deadly diseases. Ultimately, the measure of a society's wealth is the range of human problems that it has found a way to solve and how available it has made those solutions to its citizens. Every item in the huge retail stores that Americans shop in can be thought of as a solution to a different kind of problem-how to eat, clothe ourselves, make our homes more comfortable, get around, entertain ourselves, and so on. The more and better solutions available to us, the more prosperity we have.

The long arc of human progress can be thought of as an accumulation of such solutions, embodied in the products and services of the economy. The Yanomami economy, typical of our hunter-gatherer ancestors 15,000 years ago, has a variety of products and services measured in the hundreds or thousands at most. The variety of modern America's economy can be measured in the tens or even hundreds of billions. Measured in dollars, Americans are more than 500 times richer than the Yanomami. Measured in access to products and services that provide solutions to human problems, we are hundreds of millions of times more prosperous.

[Oct 13, 2015] Steve Keen Mainstream Economics and Its Deadly Equilibrium Assumption

"... The biggest lie is money and the notion that issuers of fiat currencies, sovereign governments, are like households and need to balance deficit spending by borrowing the shortfall in tax revenues. ..."
Jun 16, 2003 | naked capitalism

Chris Williams, October 12, 2015 at 5:24 pm

As an economist who was taught at the Australian National University in the 1980s, I know, now, that the profession has more in common with PolSci than it has to do with math. Yet, we had all those demand and supply graphs, ISLM, Phillips curves and so on. Very mathy, we even did Economic Stats, Accounting and Comp Sci just to round off the notion that Economic theories were like, say Physics, full of 'laws' that were immutable.

Non economists, most of the rest of you, I hope, can only imagine what it feels like to know that much of what you read and thought about during those years of study was complete crap as the syllabus failed to account for fraud, corruption, how money and debt works in reality etc….

The biggest lie is money and the notion that issuers of fiat currencies, sovereign governments, are like households and need to balance deficit spending by borrowing the shortfall in tax revenues.

Hopefully, the new thinkers in the profession like Steve, can continue to spread their message

Knute Rife, October 13, 2015 at 12:05 am

When I was an undergrad, I took macro and micro in very classical courses. It didn't take long to see the "math" on the board was more conjuring than calculating. In law school I took Law and Economics from an econ prof. There were about three of us in the class who had any decent math. The prof's "calculations" had us constantly looking at one another. One day she finally hit the limit. We pointed out to her that she had the central fraction reversed. She stood back and said (I kid you not), "Oh well, it doesn't matter." I turned down the sound on economic "calculations" in general after that.

Furzy Mouse, October 12, 2015 at 12:42 pm

Keen's talk….cannot read the subtitles….the screen is too small, even when I go to YouTube…

Arthur Wilke,

October 12, 2015 at 1:33 pm


This link may be an aid: https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=x7uITEBqQvM

Vatch, October 12, 2015 at 1:44 pm

Have you tried your browser's zoom function? This is often CTRL-Plus. CTRL-Minus reduces the size, and CTRL-Zero restores the default size.

low_integer, October 12, 2015 at 2:00 pm

If you put your cursor on the bottom right corner of the video and click, the video will expand into full screen. It is one of the options in the bar that is only visible when your cursor is at the bottom of the video area, from which you can also turn the subtitles on and off. Also, press escape to exit full screen mode. Hope that makes sense


Arthur Wilke, October 12, 2015 at 2:32 pm

The embedded video is selected from this encounter and
is easy to expand to full-screen:
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=x7uITEBqQvM

[Oct 09, 2015] Economist's View 'Faith in an Unregulated Free Market Don't Fall for It'

Oct 09, 2015 | economistsview.typepad.com
Robert Shiller continues to phish for book sales:
Faith in an Unregulated Free Market? Don't Fall for It: Perhaps the most widely admired of all the economic theories taught in our universities is the notion that an unregulated competitive economy is optimal for everyone. ...
The problem is that these ideas are flawed. Along with George A. Akerlof ... I have used behavioral economics to plumb the soundness of these notions. ...
Don't get us wrong: George and I are certainly free-market advocates. In fact, I have argued for years that we need more such markets, like futures markets for single-family home prices or occupational incomes, or markets that would enable us to trade claims on gross domestic product. I've written about these things in this column.
But, at the same time, we both believe that standard economic theory is typically overenthusiastic about unregulated free markets. It usually ignores the fact that, given normal human weaknesses, an unregulated competitive economy will inevitably spawn an immense amount of manipulation and deception. ...
Current economic theory does recognize that if there is an "externality" - say, a business polluting the air in the course of producing the goods it sells - the outcome won't be optimal, and most economists would agree that in such cases we need government intervention.
But the problem of market-incentivized professional manipulation and deception is fundamental, not an externality...

david said...

"But the problem of market-incentivized professional manipulation and deception is fundamental, not an externality..."

Glad to see Shiller pushing this line.

But that's true of loads of what gets called externality -- that's the trouble with the term, it presumes some idyllic unregulated market with just a few troubling side effects to regulate away. The markets are made so that certain actors gain rewards and others bear costs, fundamentally. Externality suggests tweaks, but to go back to the Stavins bit from a few days ago, we need to be thinking structure and power.

JohnH said...

An unregulated free market is a recipe for oligopoly and monopoly, the very antithesis of a free market.

pgl said in reply to JohnH...

"The problem of market-incentivized professional manipulation and deception is fundamental, not an externality" goes well beyond anti-trust concerns."

Paul Mathis said...

Unregulated Free Markets Never Existed

Nearly 4,000 years ago the Babylonian King Hammurabi carved onto a large stone a code of laws regulating contracts: the wages to be paid to an ox driver or a surgeon, the liability of a builder for a house that collapses, property that is damaged while left in the care of another, etc. – Wikipedia.

Governments have been regulating and enforcing contracts ever since because no economy can function without such regulation and enforcement. And whenever government regulation is absent, businesses collude to fix prices, divide up markets and drive out competitors thereby nullifying any illusion of "free market" competition.

GeorgeNYC said...

Just ask any "free market" advocate if they believe that the stock market is a good example of their vision for a "free market". They will invariably say "yes" as the stock market is the cathedral of religious capitalism.

Point out to them that the "stock market" is actually one of the most highly regulated "markets" with strict disclosure requirements (enforced by the government) and insider trading prohibitions (also enforced by the government), to name but a few, without which much of our faith in the "market" would be completely eliminated (and whose weak enforcement invariably lead to concerns about fraud). Of course, there are also a huge number of "private" regulations that ultimately have the force of the government behind them in that they allow for exchanges to "self-regulate".

Most people do not understand that force is required to maintain the type of transparency needed to allow the proper information flow necessary to actually have a market work with true efficiency. "Free" is a complete misnomer. "Open" would probably be better term although that does not really fully capture the requirements.

likbez said in reply to GeorgeNYC...

That's brilliant: "the stock market is the cathedral of religious capitalism".

The term "free market" became symbol of faith for neoliberalism and obtained distinct religious overtones. Because neoliberalism is in reality a secular religion. That's why neoliberalism is often called casino capitalism.

And at the same time it is powerful instrument of propaganda of neoliberalism, a very skillful deception that masks what is in practice the advocacy of the law of jungle.

Advocates of "free market" (note that they never use the term "fair market") are lavishly paid by Wall Street for one specific purpose: first to restore and now to maintain the absolute dominance of financial oligarchy which now successfully positioned itself above the law. Kind of return to feudalism on a new level.

Bud Meyers said...

Great posts on this topic:

Free Markets are Fraudulent Markets (by Eric L. Prentis)

http://www.economicpopulist.org/content/free-markets-are-fraudulent-markets-5360

Capitalism Requires Government (7 pages: click through the page links near the bottom of each page):

http://www.governmentisgood.com/articles.php?aid=13

[Oct 09, 2015] Free Markets are Fraudulent Markets

Oct 09, 2015 | www.economicpopulist.org
September 7, 2013 | The Economic Populist
How the Financial Elite Con Us into Wanting the Wrong Thing

Competitive or self-regulating market economies promote dynamic creative destruction and rebirth-led by people's needs, wants and desires, thus properly directing economic progress. Historically, competitive market economies are a relatively new economic system, and while very productive, they are not self-sustaining, are unstable and require significant state support and regulation to function properly.

Nevertheless, self-regulating market economies are superior to other political-economic systems-such as dictatorial fascism or autocratic communism-however, the state can mismanage them.

History of Market Economies

Market economies are nonexistent during primitive times, and even during feudal times, markets trade local goods and remain small, with no tendency to grow. External foreign markets carry only specialty items-such as spices, salted fish and wine. Foreign trade does not begin in feudal societies, between individuals, but is only sanctioned by civic leaders-between whole communities.

During feudal times, markets for local community goods do not mix with markets for goods that come from afar. Local and external foreign markets differ in size, origin and function-are strictly segregated, and neither market is permitted to enter the countryside.

Feudal society transitions into the mercantile society of the 16th to late 18th centuries, where the state monopolizes the economic system, for the state's benefit. Colonies are forbidden to trade with other countries, and workers' wages are restricted. However, mercantilism proves divisive; fostering imperialism, colonialism and many wars between the Great Powers. Market economies have yet to arrive, and would not do so until after 1790.

During the Industrial Revolution, production processes transition from hand crafting methods that supply only the local community, into mechanized manufacturing; thereby vastly increasing production, driving down costs and increasing wealth. The source of a person's income is now the result of product sales to far-off, unknown customers. Private business entrepreneurs are the driving force pushing the state to institute the market economy, thereby protecting the sale of their goods in far-off lands.

Unfortunately, in practice, market economies result in corporate monopolies. Corporations may use a product dumping predatory pricing strategy, by charging less than their cost to produce, in a specific market, in order to drive weaker, smaller competitors out of business, and then significantly raise prices at a later date, in order to gouge the consumer. If the monopoly is in a vital economic area and the company institutes monopoly pricing to overcharge the consumer, only the state has the power to protect the market economy from monopolistic inefficiencies and break up the offending company; thus reinstituting competitive pricing. As a result, government regulations and market economies develop simultaneously.

Laws & Regulations Are Necessary

Leaving business a free hand, especially when dealing with far off customers, leads to misrepresentations, shoddy practices and fraud. The food industry is an example.

Upton Sinclair writes The Jungle (1906), exposing the disgusting unsanitary conditions in the Chicago meatpacking industry, during the early 20th century. Public uproar prompts President Theodore Roosevelt to pass the Pure Food and Drug Act of 1906 and the Meat Inspection Act. Roosevelt says that government laws and regulations are the only way to restrain the arrogant and selfish greed of the capitalist system.

Shocking examples of food fraud in 2013 highlight the need for enforcing government regulations. Inspectors uncover corporations selling horse meat as beef, and routinely mislabeling about 40% of the fish served in U.S. restaurants. Cheap rockfish and tilapia are substituted and sold as expensive snapper, and restaurateurs frequently switch escolar for white tuna, causing diners to suffer indigestion.

Over 70% of the tilapia sold in the U.S. is imported from Asia, and only 2% is inspected by the Food and Drug Administration. Much of this Asian farm raised tilapia is "filthy fish," where pesticides and manure run off into the tilapia raising ponds, causing infections. Or the tilapia is raised in polluted Asian rivers. Americans are impairing their health by unknowingly eating filthy Asian tilapia, fraudulently substituted in U.S. restaurants for the healthy fish ordered.

Other fraudulently mislabeled foods include sausage, organic foods, energy drinks, milk and eggs. Without sanitary food preparation standards, set and fairly enforced by the government-Americans will soon return to naively eating rat droppings-so, unknown to them, CEOs can meet Wall Street earnings expectations.

Departments of Weights and Measures (DWMs) at the state and federal level develop "uniform laws, regulations and methods of practice" that impact about 50% of U.S. GDP-to ensure there is equity between buyers and sellers in commercial transactions.

Because gasoline stations routinely pumped less gas then charged for, DWMs now ensure the accuracy of gasoline pumps, octane levels, labeling and restricting water in gasoline. Butchers used to add lead weights to the chest cavity of the poultry sold, prior to weighing, then noiselessly dumped the weights out into an unseen padded draw before the bird was held up for the customer's inspection, thereby swindling their trusting patrons.

Without the state to step in to punish fraudulent wrongdoers, dishonest business practices would be widespread. Consumer trust, in everyday market transactions, is paramount for market economies to function effectively and efficiently-making government regulations vitally important.

Without regulation and transparency, bad businesses drive out good businesses, following Gresham's Law. The economic system then atrophies, with a loss of trust in the marketplace. What is lost is not just the money on an inferior product or service, in the short run, but more importantly, the bad businesses may use their outsized profits to buy political protection and start changing laws, to make new laws favorable only for them-thereby damaging the market economy and reducing the state's economic growth and welfare.

Competitive Market Economies

An economic market system capable of directing the whole of economic life, without out-side help or interference, is called self-regulating. Once the self-regulating or competitive market economy is designed and implemented by the state, to give all participants an equal opportunity for success, the self-regulating market is to be let alone by the state and allowed to function according to laws and regulations, without after-the-fact government intrusions-regardless of the expected consequences.

Those in Western societies are told that competitive market economies, which have self-regulated prices for land, labor and money, set solely by the market, are normal, and that human beings develop market economies on their own, without help from the state, which is the proof of human progress. Also, that market institutions will arise naturally and spontaneously, if only persons are left alone to pursue their economic interests, free from government control. This is incorrect.

Throughout most of human history, self-regulating markets are unnatural and exceptional. Human beings are forced into the self-regulating market economy, by the state. Look at the following false competitive market economy assumptions.

We are told people naturally bartered goods. Actually, human beings, down through history, have no predilection to barter. Social anthropology says that assuming tribal and feudal men and women bartered are rationalist constructs, with no basis in fact. Market economies are the result of often violent government directives, implemented for society's eventual improvement.

The assumption is man is a trader by nature, and that any different human behavior is an artificial economic construct. By not interfering in human behavior, markets will spring up spontaneously. Social anthropology disproves this.

Neoliberal Economic Theory

Originally, neoliberal economic theory means, "free enterprise, competitive markets, the priority of the market price setting mechanism, and a strong and impartial state-to ensure it all functions properly."

The Mont Pelerin Society, led by Dr. Milton Friedman, supports Hayek's economic theories, based on "free market" ideology and help change neoliberal economic theory by rejecting government regulation-calling it inefficient. In addition, financial economists at the University of Chicago School of Business promote the efficient market hypothesis or theory (EMT), supporting the Mont Pelerin Society's conjecture. Thus, the primacy of deregulated or "free markets" becomes mainstream within academe in the 1970s. Large corporations then use "free market fundamentalism" to their advantage, by lobbying the U.S. Congress to pass legislation beneficial to them.

Some think that "free markets" are a matter of degree, and the practical issues of implementation are paramount. This is incorrect, and will not resolve the current "free market fundamentalism" debate. Instead, the real issue is semantics. Notice how quickly those with a political agenda change the debate from "competitive markets," which require state regulations and are highly productive-to "free markets," which result in fraudulent marketplace behavior, crony capitalism and weak economic growth.

Using the term "free markets" is an Orwellian ruse, designed to change the focus in the public's mind from, "those in authority have to do better" to "those in authority know best, therefore, let them have their way."

Today, neoliberal economic dogma promotes "free market fundamentalism" of reducing the size of government through the privatization of government services, deregulation and globalization. Privatization professes to reduce the state's authority over the economy, but state money is used by private companies to lobby legislators, to change laws, which will increase the government's demand for these same private corporation services. Privatization of government services by corporations does not promote the common good, only corporations' private profits.

Neoliberal "free market" economists have doubled down on the failed liberal economic theory, with the ongoing 2008 credit crisis as the result.

Free Markets Are Impractical

"Free markets" are free from state intervention, i.e., unfettered capitalism. Those who understand how markets function realize this is an impractical view-simply a rhetorical device-using the popular word "freedom" to mask its real purpose.

"Free markets" are a fantasy, far outside the realm of practicality, used by wealthy international corporations to bully governments and labor, to get their way. The reality is a competitive market economy requires powerful complex opposing interests, mediated by government, to produce an efficient and effective economy that supplies the most to the many, which includes the common good.

Free Market Fundamentalism Leads To Economic Disaster

Nowhere is "free market fundamentalism" more highly trumpeted by neoliberal economists than in the financial markets. The foundation of neoliberalism is, "a deregulated financial sector will regulate itself efficiently, making better use of capital, thus ushering in a new age of prosperity."

Tragically, the massive deregulation of the financial markets during the Clinton and Bush presidencies, results in the ongoing 2008 credit crisis-which the U.S. Government Accountability Office reports has cost the U.S. economy about $13 trillion dollars in lost GDP output.

"Free market" apologists ingenuously explain the 2008 credit crisis is not caused by "free markets," but because government regulations are not loose enough. All "free market" failures are dismissed by the financial elite, because of cognitive dissonance. Bankers and neoliberal economists want to believe in what is making them richer and more important. This is the same logic used by those in charge in the USSR, when communism failed, "it wasn't being applied purely enough."

Free Market Ideology in Practice

"Free market," ideology, as practiced today, is the opposite of what is stated. Instead, governments step in to save insolvent banks and large international corporations, when they make bankrupting mistakes, and give the bill to the taxpayer. This transforms the difficult but manageable ongoing 2008 credit crisis, into a much larger and dangerous sovereign bankruptcy crisis, with potentially calamitous political consequences.

"Free markets" usher in unfettered capitalism, unleashing the "law of the jungle" and a "dog-eat-dog world" that fosters fraud and corruption. Human beings, no matter their station in life, cannot be trusted to always do the right thing, especially in a competitive situation. Doing away with laws or regulations so those in power know it is impossible to be caught or penalized does not stop them from acting improperly. Only criminal punishment and public disgrace accomplish that.

The resulting "free market" business jungle includes monopolies, coercion, fraud, theft, parasitism, crony cabals and racketeering. Ironically, unfettered "free markets" are not free, but increase injustice, making the economic system inefficient. Only government laws and regulations can keep markets competitive.

The EMT Supporting Free Markets Is Wrong

New scientific evidence on the efficient market hypothesis or theory (EMT), shows University of Chicago School of Business researchers ask the wrong questions, use erroneous data and an incorrect research method to analyze the data, and then jump to false conclusions, based on half-truths-please read further in my journal articles: link, link and link.

The EMT and "free market fundamentalism" are false gods.

Conclusion

Markets are not efficient, based on the data. Consequently, "free markets" have no theoretical foundation. Therefore, reject the incorrect theory of "free market fundamentalism" It is impractical and dangerous, leading us into the ongoing 2008 credit crisis.

Competitive market economies only function properly by having fair laws and regulations, set up and impartially enforced, by a strong state. Dr. Robert M. Solow, 1987 Nobel Prize Winner in Economics and MIT Institute Professor Emeritus says, "The switch to talk about "free" markets diverts attention from these deficiencies and suggests that any attempts at corrective regulation are instead limitations on freedom."

Neoliberal" free market fundamentalists" in business use "free market" ideology as a negotiation ploy. Do not succumb to this ruse. The U.S. requires "competitive markets for economic growth," not "free markets for fraud."

[Sep 27, 2015] A Few Less Obvious Answers on What is Wrong with Macroeconomics

"... ...IMF Survey ..."
"... there ..."
"... There is no and never has been "economics". Only political economy. That means that neoliberal "Flat Earth Theories" will be enforced, by force if necessary. ..."
"... Blanchard is a pro system guy. A maintainer not a disrupter. When he lauds the thousand schools cacophony, it's simply to spread caution about government macro engineering ..."
Sep 27, 2015 | economistsview.typepad.com
Sep 26, 2015 | Economist's View

From an interview with Olivier Blanchard:

...IMF Survey: In pushing the envelope, you also hosted three major Rethinking Macroeconomics conferences. What were the key insights and what are the key concerns on the macroeconomic front?

Blanchard:

Let me start with the obvious answer: That mainstream macroeconomics had taken the financial system for granted. The typical macro treatment of finance was a set of arbitrage equations, under the assumption that we did not need to look at who was doing what on Wall Street. That turned out to be badly wrong.

But let me give you a few less obvious answers:

The financial crisis raises a potentially existential crisis for macroeconomics. Practical macro is based on the assumption that there are fairly stable aggregate relations, so we do not need to keep track of each individual, firm, or financial institution-that we do not need to understand the details of the micro plumbing. We have learned that the plumbing, especially the financial plumbing, matters: the same aggregates can hide serious macro problems. How do we do macro then?

As a result of the crisis, a hundred intellectual flowers are blooming. Some are very old flowers: Hyman Minsky's financial instability hypothesis. Kaldorian models of growth and inequality. Some propositions that would have been considered anathema in the past are being proposed by "serious" economists: For example, monetary financing of the fiscal deficit. Some fundamental assumptions are being challenged, for example the clean separation between cycles and trends: Hysteresis is making a comeback. Some of the econometric tools, based on a vision of the world as being stationary around a trend, are being challenged. This is all for the best.

Finally, there is a clear swing of the pendulum away from markets towards government intervention, be it macro prudential tools, capital controls, etc. Most macroeconomists are now solidly in a second best world. But this shift is happening with a twist-that is, with much skepticism about the efficiency of government intervention. ...

pgl said...

"That mainstream macroeconomics had taken the financial system for granted. The typical macro treatment of finance was a set of arbitrage equations, under the assumption that we did not need to look at who was doing what on Wall Street. That turned out to be badly wrong."

Ah yes - the Efficient Markets Hypothesis (EMH). Nice academic theory but Wall Street exists because they are deviations from EMH. And the scale of operations there - even the slightest deviation can generate huge profits for them. And when the rest of us are not careful - huge costs to the rest of the world.

It is not that these deviations are not known and how to address the downsides of them are that complicated. What is complicated is making sure Congress and not and paid for by the Wall Street crowd. Dodd-Frank was a nice start. It is a same that our expert on everything - Rusty - has joined in the chorus to get rid of Dodd-Frank.

RC AKA Darryl, Ron said in reply to djb...

"now its getting spooky"

[Welcome to my world. I have always been ahead of trend, but usually by several decades rather than just a few hours :<)

I would venture that you don't know the half of it yet. Let me elucidate.]

"...Olivier Blanchard will step down as Economic Counsellor and Director of the IMF's Research Department at the end of September.

He will join the Peterson Institute for International Economics in October as the first C. Fred Bergsten senior fellow, a post named for the founder of the influential 35-year-old, Washington-based think tank..."

[Now tell me how that you can imagine anyone to be more mainstream status quo establishment than that in the general spectrum of academic research and study economics? The plot thickens. Like I said earlier today, we have been solidly in a Second Best world practically since FDR died from the perspective of economics as a socio-political discipline exercised for the common good in any manner discernible by the wage class.

The social expression of our anxiety and grief post-2008 is being played out in compartmentalized parallel tracts organized by socio-economic class. We are experiencing denial, anger, bargaining, depression and acceptance all at once now. Since the crisis was caused by the conservative agenda of financial innovation and deregulation then they are expressing most of the denial. People that lost their jobs and homes are expressing much of the anger, but a threatened white male population deeply invested in the emotional capital of white supremacy and chauvinism is even louder in their anger (and they are having a Tea Party to get to know each other and celebrate being white men). Elites are doing the bargaining because they really don't want to lose establishment control to populists. Folk that still don't have a job or a home are expressing the depression. Finally most people that do have a home and a job that do not fall into any of the other groups are expressing the acceptance.

Me? I recently got laid off, but was lucky enough having just turned 66 that with six years service credit taken from my severance benefits added to my pension plus what little I had in 457 and 401 plans then I could retire and still pay my bills including four more years of mortgage and HELOC payments. So, I am a bit cash strapped presently but have time to work on some projects. I have been waiting to get the establishment on the ropes for nearly fifty years. So, I am not healing from grief. I have been released and am looking for an opportunity to get the establishment on its intellectual ropes.

I thought it was getting spooky when I first began to learn about mainstream economic thought regarding capital gains windfalls, corporate mergers, and financial "innovation" in the mid-sixties. For the first time in my life I am beginning to see a tiny glimmer of it starting to get real.]

JohnH said...

"Mainstream macroeconomics had taken the financial system for granted."

It's actually worse than that. Mainstream macroeconomics willfully ignores the impact of rising asset prices on inequality, democracy, and power dynamics between the 1% and the rest.

Cui bono from their willful negligence? The powerful and wealthy, of course!

Amateur said...

I'm a fan of Olivier.

The leaders of the IMF were in a unique position to see new insights into our macro problems because they are largely caused by the globalization of capital flows and labor.

I think he's getting there, but I suspect the old frameworks are still going to be an impediment to mainstream economic thinking.

I'm glad to hear there are more people that we might be aware of that are rethinking macro in this context.

Dan Kervick said...

"The plumbing matters."

Yes, that's it. I hope that is the main lesson the economics profession takes away from the current crisis. It would be nice if we get a new generation of practitioners who think a bit more like engineers and technicians, and less like mathematical physicists.

Paul Mathis

"Some propositions that would have been considered anathema in the past are being proposed by "serious" economists: For example, monetary financing of the fiscal deficit."

Wasn't Keynes a "serious" economist? Monetary financing of the fiscal deficit was his idea 80 years ago. Today's economists are just getting the message.

likbez said...

There is no and never has been "economics". Only political economy. That means that neoliberal "Flat Earth Theories" will be enforced, by force if necessary.

greg said...

Pathetic half measures. No need to question any of the fundamental assumptions underlying the whole sorry mess, eh? Like what is money, really? Or: How does the production of the various sectors actually combine to create value in the whole economy?

Matt Young said...

Macroeconomists are not up to speed? How long has this been going on? Ever since the Kanosian dandy from England. Sick, sick and fraudulent science.

RC AKA Darryl, Ron said in reply to djb...

That is a good start. You just need to get the context switch straight and then you may find yourself in an epiphany (metaphorically speaking). Likbez up thread touches another live wire, but lacks faith in democratic alternatives. Shocking!

Larry said...

No mention of the end of the ZLB? Of NGDP targeting? Of the missing trade-off between inflation and unemployment? Of the abject failures of governments/CBs to respond to the crisis and restore normal times? Of new levers such as reverse repos, QE and IoER? Maybe the excerpt was ill-chosen...

Davis X. Machina said in reply to Larry...

"Of the abject failures of governments/CBs to respond to the crisis and restore normal times?"

"Normal" for whom, and at whose expense?

Squint just right, and this *is* normal.

Paine said...

Blanchard is a pro system guy. A maintainer not a disrupter. When he lauds the thousand schools cacophony, it's simply to spread caution about government macro engineering

We've recently learned doing the right sorts of interventions but too cautiously.
Works more like " Let the markets correct themselves "

We need to isolate those who try by various means to minimize state intervention

... ... ...

[Sep 18, 2015] I would summarize the Keynesian view in terms of four points

I would summarize the Keynesian view in terms of four points:
1. Economies sometimes produce much less than they could, and employ many fewer workers than they should, because there just isn't enough spending. Such episodes can happen for a variety of reasons; the question is how to respond.
2. There are normally forces that tend to push the economy back toward full employment. But they work slowly; a hands-off policy toward depressed economies means accepting a long, unnecessary period of pain.
3. It is often possible to drastically shorten this period of pain and greatly reduce the human and financial losses by "printing money", using the central bank's power of currency creation to push interest rates down.
4. Sometimes, however, monetary policy loses its effectiveness, especially when rates are close to zero. In that case temporary deficit spending can provide a useful boost. And conversely, fiscal austerity in a depressed economy imposes large economic losses.
Is this a complicated, convoluted doctrine? ...
But strange things happen in the minds of critics. Again and again we see the following bogus claims about what Keynesians believe:
B1: Any economic recovery, no matter how slow and how delayed, proves Keynesian economics wrong. See [2] above for why that's illiterate.
B2: Keynesians believe that printing money solves all problems. See [3]: printing money can solve one specific problem, an economy operating far below capacity. Nobody said that it can conjure up higher productivity, or cure the common cold.
B3: Keynesians always favor deficit spending, under all conditions. See [4]: The case for fiscal stimulus is quite restrictive, requiring both a depressed economy and severe limits to monetary policy. That just happens to be the world we've been living in lately.
I have no illusions that saying this obvious stuff will stop the usual suspects from engaging in the usual bogosity. But maybe this will help others respond when they do.

I would add:

5. Keynesian are not opposed to supply-side, growth enhancing policy. They types of taxes that are imposed matters, entrepreneurial activity should be encouraged, and so on. But these arguments should not be used as cover for redistribution of income to the wealthy through tax cuts and other means, or as a means of arguing for cuts to important social service programs. Not should they be used only to support tax cuts. Infrastructure spending is important for growth, an educated, healthy workforce is more productive, etc., etc. Economic growth is about much more than tax cuts for wealthy political donors.

On the other side, I would have added a point to B3:

B3a: Keynesians do not favor large government. They believe that deficits should be used to stimulate the economy in severe recessions (when monetary policy alone is not enough), but they also believe that the deficits should be paid for during good times (shave the peaks to fill the troughs and stabilize the path of GDP and employment). We haven't been very good at the pay for it during good times part, but Democrats can hardly be blamed for that (see tax cuts for the wealthy for openers).

Anything else, e.g. perhaps something like "Keynesians do not believe that helping people in need undermines their desire to work"?

Axel Merk Warns Investors Are In For A Rude Awakening Zero Hedge


LawsofPhysics

LOL! Almost. You really think that growth can continue forever and ever in a biosphere with finite resources?

Tell us another fairytale and good luck with that!

But yes, let the truly insolvent fucks and worthless fucks go to the guillotine already!

Bro of the Sorrowful

using metrics in economics and applying mathamatical formulas to quantify all aspects of the economy has been a major and far reaching disaster. none worse, perhaps with the exception of unemployment and inflation, than the totally fraudulent metric "GDP". youll notice in von mises' magnum opus human action that there is not a single formula.

were it not for the measurement of the ambiguous "GDP", we would not be so concerned with growth.

pods

We sure as hell would be concerned with growth.

Expansion is what is required by our monetary system.

That is why inflation of 2% is "stable prices" and everyone and their mother talks about growth.

Fraction reserve currency requires expansion (exponential) to function.

No growth=no currency system.

That is why sustainability is a no go right out of the gate.

pods

Bro of the Sorrowful Figure's picture

i was speaking more of an ideal world in which we would be operating under a sound monetary system. my problem with using economic metrics for everything is that it takes the focus off of real problems and gives huge power to the international banking cartel by allowing them to manipulate the numbers without end. we start from a false monetary system, then apply a metric system based on false logic to justify that monetary system, while also making those metrics esoteric enough that the average person simply stops paying attention or freezes up when such metrics are mentioned. that way the economy can be absolute shit, with obvious signs to anyone with eyes, and yet your average person will still say, well GDP is up and unemployment is down so things must be good.

Harry Balzak

Are you implying that reality exists without accounting?

Blasphemy! Burn him!

[Sep 09, 2015] Neoclassical economic reforms were colossal failures

"...The reason the Friedmanian era turned out to be vastly different from the Keynesian era was because the neoclassical economic reforms were colossal failures."
"...Nothing in the history of the universe has failed more than neoclassical ideology. If one is to call that failure, one would have to redefined the word failure to include all other failures that pale by comparison. But according to the Medieval Barbers, their policies were a resounding success. Anyone who questions them is a philistine. Thankfully, these modern high priests aren't able to burn dissenters at the stake like their forebears. "
"..."Krugan's free-trade ideology rhetoric shows he's more New Keynesian (neoclassical synthesis) than Keynesian. More neoliberal than liberal.""
"...Modern Monetary Theology brought back pre-Keynesian boom-to-bust business cycles, drove down real incomes and the employment rate (now expect a decade before the economy can recover from a recession.) "
"...China is in hot water because neoclassical reforms have killed demand in the Western economy. Its economy is founded on importing more and more Western jobs and manufacturing, not to mention GHG emissions. "

EMichael said in reply to Ron Waller, September 07, 2015 at 09:52 AM

I see no purpose in comparing the present with a period of time so vastly different from the present.

Ron Waller said in reply to EMichael, September 07, 2015 at 10:27 AM

Yes the laws of physics change every 35 years too.

The reason the Friedmanian era turned out to be vastly different from the Keynesian era was because the neoclassical economic reforms were colossal failures.

Tax cuts did not pay for themselves or create prosperity, they created skyrocketing government debt. Deregulation didn't create prosperity, but produced numerous disasters including financial meltdowns. Free-trade exported wealth and jobs and killed real income growth. Modern Monetary Theology brought back pre-Keynesian boom-to-bust business cycles, drove down real incomes and the employment rate (now expect a decade before the economy can recover from a recession.)

Nothing in the history of the universe has failed more than neoclassical ideology. If one is to call that failure, one would have to redefined the word failure to include all other failures that pale by comparison.

But according to the Medieval Barbers, their policies were a resounding success. Anyone who questions them is a philistine. Thankfully, these modern high priests aren't able to burn dissenters at the stake like their forebears.

EMichael said in reply to Ron Waller, September 07, 2015 at 10:35 AM

No, the Laws of Physics do not change.

Economic facts do. Are you trying to state there has not been a sea change in the world economy since the post WWII era?

Sorry, but Japan, China and Europe are an awful lot different than they were in 1950. And that is not saying that I disagree with everything you say. Actually, I agree with a lot of it.

But thinking solutions lie in the policies of the 50s and 60s ignore that the problems that exist did not exist in the 50s and the 60s.

Bruce Webb said in reply to EMichael, September 07, 2015 at 11:02 AM

"But thinking solutions lie in the policies of the 50s and 60s ignore that the problems that exist did not exist in the 50s and the 60s."

EMichael there is a logical hole here. I am not sure I disagree with you on the substance but there is a coherent argument that the problems that exist NOW are precisely BECAUSE of changes away from the polices of the 50s and 60s. And that the reason we didn't have the same problems then is that the policies prevented them. And that a change back to those policies would serve to ameliorate them.

What you would need to do to rescue your argument is to prove that current problems could NOT have existed in the 50's and 60's, that there is something unique to today's problems that make them resistant to yesterday's solutions.

I am not saying you couldn't do that. Merely that you haven't attempted it. Instead you present a circular argument. What EXACTLY about today's problems make them incurable by yesterday's solutions?

EMichael said in reply to Bruce Webb, September 07, 2015 at 01:33 PM

The main thing that did not exist in the US was competition for labor. Free trade is a marvelous thing when you are the only one selling.

Take a look at trade balances from that period and the last couple of decades.

You can almost trace the trade balance changes to the changes(or lack of changes) to the income of the vast majority of Americans.

People in here(and myself) talk about the need for a tighter labor market. And we applaud the actions that create one. But I am almost totally committed to the idea that the only way to create a tight labor market is protectionism. We have to protect our workers.

Of course there is a price to be paid, but I think the increased costs of some goods will be overwhelmed by the benefits to be gained by a tight labor market.

Then again, we would be harming other countries trying to move into a industrialized state. But the last time I looked, none of them were helping me pay for SS; or Medicare; or education; or the keep the street lights working.

I know it is not politically correct, but charity begins at home. Especially in a home which has seen such decline in only three or four decades.

cm said in reply to Bruce Webb, September 08, 2015 at 09:51 AM

Economic policy doesn't happen in a vacuum. Before the 90's there was no internet. There were its precursors of a sort, e.g. fax and data transmission over the phone, and computer networks/links based on that (90's comms technology existed but only in the lab or at the high end). In the post-WW2 decades, there weren't built out telephone networks at the national and international level, only few high end players could arrange to make instant international calls. Even electrification wasn't completed.

This meant obviously more bottlenecks and more intermediation and control, barriers to globally distributed operations, and in addition everything happened at a slower speed.

In addition most of the world, including large parts of Europe and the US, was agricultural or sparsely populated and un"developed".

In the decades after, the "second" and "third" world invested big time in education and technological development. It really took off when international business logistics and global IT/telecom became ubiquitous, and "first world" companies eagerly "helped" build the offshore know-how.

Ron Waller said in reply to EMichael, September 07, 2015 at 11:14 AM

Generalizations don't identify any problems, provide any solutions, justify failed policies or rule out successful policies. Japan and Europe are in hot water because of bad economic policy. (Not demand-side Keynesian economic policy.)

China is in hot water because neoclassical reforms have killed demand in the Western economy. Its economy is founded on importing more and more Western jobs and manufacturing, not to mention GHG emissions.

It's only a matter of time before the entire house of cards collapses. Then people will be looking to the 1930s for policy solutions

Peter K. said in reply to EMichael, September 07, 2015 at 01:27 PM

I agree with the others. To say that the economy was different back then is to minimize the manner in which policy has changed for the worse.

I don't think fundamentally the laws of economics have changed that much because of technology or globalization or vague "productivity changes."

This is like being like Martin Feldstein who says we should be happy with what we got. No policy has changed much to the worse since the 1950s and 1960s. For one thing unions have been politically destroyed.

EMichael said in reply to Peter K

Not the laws of economics, the facts. Y'know the old Keynes thing(supposedly):

"When the facts change, I change my mind. What do you do, sir?"

I'll give you one change.

In the 70's China had almost no foreign exchange reserves. Now they have around $4 Trillion.

That is a real fact. And the reasons behind it are obvious.

Reply September 07, 2015 at 01:40 PM
likbez said in reply to Ron Waller

"Krugan's free-trade ideology rhetoric shows he's more New Keynesian (neoclassical synthesis) than Keynesian. More neoliberal than liberal."

Very true. Thank you

[Sep 07, 2015] The Thirty-Year Boom

September 06, 2015 | Economist's View

Part of an essay by David Warsh:

... For the old lions, Paul Samuelson and Milton Friedman, the '80s meant a bittersweet departure from the center stage of economics after forty years of dominating the scene. The two had entered their sixties; neither was out of steam. But the leaders of the next generation had become apparent: Lucas, in macroeconomics; Kenneth Arrow in nearly everything else.

The election of Ronald Reagan was a triumph for Friedman; they had known each other since Friedman spent a quarter at the University of California at Los Angeles, shortly after Reagan had been elected Governor of California.He was invited to lecture in China. And the international success of Free to Choose kept Friedman in the public eye.

But Paul Volcker took a different approach to monetary policy from the one Friedman advocated, and Friedman's forecasts became markedly worse. The editorial page of The Wall Street Journal adopted as its champion Friedman's long-time rival in currency matters, Robert Mundell, now teaching at Columbia University, and went all in for Mundell's young associate, consultant Arthur Laffer. A research appointment at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco was not the same platform as the University of Chicago. Friedman still had his membership on the President's Economic Policy Board, but after he "savaged" Volcker to his face before the president in a meeting in 1983, both men lost influence. Pointing a finger at Volcker, Friedman said (according to Newsweek's account), "because of the policies of the Fed under that man we have had an inflationary surge in the money supply that is going to have to be corrected." Volcker was not reappointed. Edward Nelson, of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis is writing a scientific biography of Friedman. It will make interesting reading when it is done.

In March 1981, Friedman wrote his Newsweek column in the form of a letter to Philip Handler, president of the National Academy of Sciences, advocating major cuts in the budget of the National Science Foundation, as a step towards the abolition of the NSF. The Reagan administration had proposed sharp cuts in the economics program. Friedman argued the government shouldn't pay for any scientific research. True, the NSF had funded much good science; but it had paid for much bad science, too, including, he wrote, overmuch mathematical economics. The great scientists of the past had done without NSF funding. Einstein did his work in a government patent office; general relativity might never have made it past a peer-review panel. "The innovative ideas that have stirred controversy in economics since NSF funding of economics began two decades ago owe little or nothing to NSF funding," he wrote.

Thus did Friedman dismiss the agency that Paul Samuelson had brought to life in 1945. Perhaps more important, by extension he dismissed the program of government fellowships, awarded by competitive exam, that had sent Samuelson to graduate school in 1935, all expenses paid – and countless others since, many of them as impecunious as Friedman had been in 1932. The NSF ran similar programs in mathematics and many ciences, and the principle had been extended, by Sen. Jacob Javits (R-NY) to humanities. NSF research grants funding had helped build the Massachusetts Institute of Technology into a powerhouse to rival Harvard, and played a similar role at many other public and private universities.

No Samuelson column followed Friedman's. Samuelson never wrote again for Newsweek . He resigned the column he written for fifteen years. When, many years later, I asked him about his timing, he firmly denied that it had anything to do with Friedman's column, and wrote me a letter for the file the next day repeating what he had said. I have always wondered if he sought to defuse the matter out of habit. That he and Friedman had remained on civil terms for seventy-five years was clearly a source of pride, though privately he grew less tolerant of his rival after 1980.

Samuelson, too, was in mild recession in the '80s. Keynesian economics hadn't yet rebounded from the biting criticism of the New Classicals in the '70s. Tensions were growing within the MIT department over appointments and the direction of future research. Samuelson formally retired in 1985, at 70, to make room for others. He had plenty to engage his professional attention. Commodities Corp., which had discovered such natural traders as Paul Tudor Jones and Bruce Kovner, was winding down, but Samuelson's interest in Warren Buffet's Berkshire Hathaway was gearing up. The Vanguard Group, whose godfather he had been ever since founder John Bogle introduced the first index fund, was thriving. Samuelson's friends and colleagues James Tobin, Franco Modigliani, and Robert Solow received Nobel Prizes.

Young Lions at Large

To the young lions of Keynesian economics in the '80s, rational- expectations macroeconomics and real business cycle theory posed a considerable bar. To work in the new traditions required a considerable investment in new tools and mathematical techniques, and, even fully teched-up, didn't seem to speak very directly to policy. A strong corps of economists went to work to fashion a "new Keynesian" version of the latest general equilibrium economics. But gradually one rising star of saltwater economics after another left academia for a policy job.

Martin Feldstein, of Harvard University, was the first. As something of an acolyte of Milton Friedman, Feldstein was never very high in salinity, but he demonstrated plenty of professional backbone as Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers under Ronald Reagan for two years in the early days of the controversies over deficits before returning in 1984 to Harvard and his position as president of the National Bureau of Economic Research. Stanley Fischer, of MIT, was next, wrapping up a highly successful research career in order to serve as chief economist of the World Bank (a path that led to leadership positions in the International Monetary Fund, governor of the Bank of Israel and, currently, vice chairman of the Fed). Lawrence Summers, Feldstein's student, served as campaign economist to Democratic candidate Michael Dukakis in the 1988 presidential campaign and succeeded Fischer at the World Bank before joining the Clinton administration, where he advanced to Secretary of the Treasury.

Soon the flood was on: Jeffrey Sachs, Joseph Stiglitz, Olivier Blanchard, Kenneth Rogoff, Gregory Mankiw, Glen Hubbard, and Christina Romer were among those MIT- or Harvard-trained economists who served in government jobs or NGO positions. Paul Krugman retooled as a journalist. Lists of MIT and Harvard graduates in high positions in European, South American, and Asian governments were even longer. Did this differ in kind, and not degree, from the trajectory of academic economists dating back to to the New Frontier, if not the New Deal? I think so.

In 2006, Harvard's Mankiw, in an article for the Journal of Economic Perspectives argued, as I did in a book, that the differences in interests among economists were best understood as being similar to those between scientists and engineers. The early macroeconomists, led by Samuelson and Friedman, had resembled engineers seeking to solve practical problems, Mankiw wrote; macroeconomists of the past several decades, led by Tjalling Koopmans, Jacob Marschak, Kenneth Arrow, and others had been more interested in developing analytic tools and establishing theoretical principles. Their students the '80s had joined teams along similar lines. "Recently Paul Romer, of New York University, introduced a different distinction to elucidate some of the controversies in present-day macro – between bench science and clinical medicine. Both analogies will get plenty of elaboration in future years, for this is what changed in kind in the '80s: economics developed a clinical/engineering wing.

... ... ...

likbez said...

Due to his role in neoliberal transformation of Chile after Pinochet coup of 1973, Friedman can be viewed as a one of the first economic hitman for multinationals, member of organized crime disguised as an economist. According to the 1975 report of a United States Senate Intelligence Committee investigation, the Chilean economic plan was prepared in collaboration with the CIA. In 1987 45% of Chile's population was below poverty line. From Wikipedia:

==Start of quote ===
Milton Friedman gave some lectures advocating free market economic policies in Universidad Católica de Chile. In 1975, two years after the coup, he met with Pinochet for 45 minutes, where the general "indicated very little indeed about his own or the government's feeling" and the president asked Friedman to write him a letter laying out what he thought Chile's economic policies should be, which he also did.[26] To stop inflation, Friedman proposed reduction of government deficits that had increased in the past years and a flat commitment by government that after six months it will no longer finance government spending by creating money. He proposed relief of cases of real hardship among poorest classes.[2] In October 1975 the New York Times columnist Anthony Lewis declared that "the Chilean junta's economic policy is based on the ideas of Milton Friedman…and his Chicago School".[26]
=== End of quote ===

In her book The Shock Doctrine, Naomi Klein criticized Friedman's recipe for neoliberal scheme of the economic rape of the countries under disguise of transformation toward "free" market economics -- the neoliberal restructuring that followed the military coups in several countries using suspiciously similar schemes. She suggested that the primary role of neoliberalism was to be an ideological cover for capital accumulation by multinationals. Chilean economist Orlando Letelier considered that the main driving force behind Pinochet's dictatorship violence toward opponents was the level of opposition to Chicago School policies in Chile.

And Friedman himself was a coward who never personally acknowledged his role in the events. After a 1991 speech on drug legalization, Friedman answered a question on his involvement with the Pinochet regime, saying that he was never an advisor to Pinochet (also mentioned in his 1984 Iceland interview), but that only his students (Chicago boys) were involved.

He was followed by Harvard mafia with their economic rape of Russia in early 90th. Probably also prepared in collaboration with the CIA...

It is interesting that the paper does not mention Galbraith who was important opponent of Friedman (see "Friedman on Galbraith, and on curing the British disease", 1977) . In those two lectures Friedman disagrees with Galbraith's four most popular works: "Countervailing Power," "The Great Crash of 1929," "The Affluent Society," and "The New Industrial State". Friedman consistently repeats the neoliberal dogma that it is unfettered free market, with minimal rules and regulations, is the best economic system.

So it might be useful to distinguish between two instances of Friedman: the first is Friedman before "Capitalism and Freedom" and the second is after. Friedman after Capitalism and Freedom is a pitiful figure of a prostitute to power that be.

chris herbert said...

The best observation was the one by Wojnilower that the animals in the zoo were let out of their cages.. They are still roaming around, not yet put back in their regulatory cages. The list of financial crises beginning in the 1980s looks as bad and as frequent as those of the 1800s. Technology gives a sheen to the past 35 years or so, but underneath there's been immense intellectual damage. A degradation of morals and honesty. Today, greed is good. I'll be gone, you'll be gone (IBGUBG), rules politics and finance today. The animals are still lose, more trouble will visit the Kingdom.

bakho said...

Interesting history lesson.
Needs more links.
Friedman's spat with Volcker:

In Friedman's view, Volcker was too vulnerable to political pressures from Congress and the White House, Condemned by liberals and conservatives for plunging the country into recession and worried that continued high interest rates would cause massive default by Third World debtors, Volcker in mid-1982 shifted his sights away from the monetarist approach, loosening the Fed's targets for money growth and restoring interest-rate manipulation as a policy tool. In the five months before the November 1984 elections, the Fed increased the money supply to bring down interest rates and thus fuel the recovery to better Reagan's chances at re-election. After Reagan's reelection victor in November, the Fed again tightened the money supply, "This is not monetarist policy," Friedman says, "The key element of monetarism is to define what you are going to do and then stick with it."

For any Fed chairman, Friedman thinks, the temptation to linker with money-supply targets is probably irresistible. According to the monetarist doctrine, the Fed chairman's job is purely technical, "a matter of every month looking at the money base and making sure it increases by about a quarter of one percent," Friedman explains, "If the Fed chairman were to do a good job, he would become an unknown, a faceless bureaucrat."

Cooper, M. H. (1987). Economics after Reaganomics. Editorial research reports 1987 (Vol. II). Washington, DC: CQ Press. Retrieved from http://library.cqpress.com/cqresearcher/cqresrre1987082100

I wonder if so many of the young economist went into policy because the people involved: Volcker, Friedman, Laffer etc were pretty clueless and made bad predictions.

bakho said...

Just how wrong was Friedman?
DARPA turned the internet over to NSF and NSF spun it off into a large commercial engine.

NSF funds high risk investment, the kind that most corporations cannot. High risk research means many projects that don'r pan out, a small pool of winners and a handful that hit jackpot. It takes a large organization with very deep pockets to fund enough high risk research over long periods to have a good likelihood of getting a large hit. Industry cannot fund at that level, government can.

Another example: NSF funded obscure biochemistry into esoteric research on enzymes that could degrade DNA. That research became the foundation of genetic engineering. Who could have known?

pgl said in reply to Paine ...

Warsh did write an incredible amount of BS in this silly essay. I didn't think Mundell ever endorsed Laffer's stupid cocktail napkin.

Lafayette said...

REAGANOMICS

From WikiP: {According to Keynesian economists, a combination of deficit spending and the lowering of interest rates slowly led to economic recovery. However, conservatives insist that the significantly lower tax rates caused the recovery. From a high of 10.8% in December 1982, unemployment gradually improved until it fell to 7.2% on Election Day in 1984.}

Even Reagan, a good friend of Friedman, when push-came-to-shove, indulged is stimulus spending to get his presidency out of the deep-doodoo.
Which the Replicants stonewalled in 2010 when a Great Recession was in full sway, but the PotUS was a Democrat ...

pgl said in reply to Lafayette...

Wikipedia gets another wrong. It was Reagan's 1981 tax cut (deficit spending) that led Volcker to do round 2 of his tight money. Volcker kept trying to make a deal withe White House - reverse the fiscal stimulus in exchange for lower interest rates. The White House did not even know what was going on. And Wikipedia does not either.

[Sep 05, 2015] Range of reactions to realism about the social world by Daniel Little

My recent post on realism in the social realm generated quite a bit of commentary, which I'd like to address here.

Brad Delong offered an incredulous response -- he seems to think that any form of scientific realism is ridiculous (link). He refers to the predictive success of Ptolemy's epicycles, and then says, "But just because your theory is good does not mean that the entities in your theory are "really there", whatever that might mean...." I responded on Twitter: "Delong doesn't like scientific realism -- really? Electrons, photons, curvature of space - all convenient fictions?" The position of instrumentalism is intellectually untenable, in my opinion -- the idea that scientific theories are just convenient computational devices for summarizing a range of observations. It is hard to see why we would have confidence in any complex technology depending on electricity, light, gravity, the properties of metals and semiconductors, if we didn't think that our scientific theories of these things were approximately true of real things in the world. So general rejection of scientific realism seems irrational to me. But the whole point of the post was that this reasoning doesn't extend over to the social sciences very easily; if we are to be realists about social entities, it needs to be on a different basis than the overall success of theories like Keynsianism, Marxism, or Parsonian sociology. They just aren't that successful!

There were quite a few comments (71) when Mark Thoma reposted this piece on economistsview. A number of the commentators were particularly interested in the question of the realism of economic knowledge. Daniel Hausman addresses the question of realism in economics in his article on the philosophy of economics in the Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (link):

Economic methodologists have paid little attention to debates within philosophy of science between realists and anti-realists (van Fraassen 1980, Boyd 1984), because economic theories rarely postulate the existence of unobservable entities or properties, apart from variants of "everyday unobservables," such as beliefs and desires. Methodologists have, on the other hand, vigorously debated the goals of economics, but those who argue that the ultimate goals are predictive (such as Milton Friedman) do so because of their interest in policy, not because they seek to avoid or resolve epistemological and semantic puzzles concerning references to unobservables.

Examples of economic concepts that commentators seemed to think could be interpreted realistically include concepts such as "economic disparity". But this isn't a particularly arcane or unobservable theoretical concept. There is a lot of back-and-forth on the meaning of investment in Keynes's theory -- is it a well-defined concept? Is it a concept that can be understood realistically? The question of whether economics consists of a body of theory that might be interpreted realistically is a complicated one. Many technical economic concepts seem not to be referential; instead, they seem to be abstract concepts summarizing the results of large numbers of interactions by economic agents.

The most famous discussion of realism in economics is that offered by Milton Friedman in relation to the idea of economic rationality (Essays in Positive Economics); he doubts that economists need to assume that real economic actors do so on the basis of economic rationality. Rather, according to Friedman this is just a simplifying assumption to allow us to summarize a vast range of behavior. This is a hard position to accept, though; if agents are not making calculating choices about costs and benefits, then why should we expect a market to work in the ways our theories say it should? (Here is a good critique by Bruce Caldwell of Friedman's instrumentalism; link.)

And what about the concept of a market itself? Can we understand this concept realistically? Do markets really exist? Maybe the most we can say is something like this: there are many social settings where stuff is produced and exchanged. When exchange is solely or primarily governed by the individual self-interest of the buyers and sellers, we can say that a market exists. But we must also be careful to add that there are many different institutional and social settings where this condition is satisfied, so there is great variation across the particular "market settings" of different societies and communities. As a result, we need to be careful not to reify the concept of a market across all settings.

[Sep 05, 2015] Tribes

"...Personally, I think he senses that RE/New Classicalism is in decline, not comprehending why, struggling to understand, looking for scapegoats (Solow, tribal behaviour, mathiness) and is essentially mourning its demise."
"...read Kuhn famous book on The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, in which he argues persuasively (or shows definitively, for those who prefer), that "Competition between segments of the scientific community [tribes?] is the only historical process that ever actually results in the rejection of one previously accepted theory or in the adoption of another," though at the same time, most progress comes from working within an established paradigm. My own intuition is that economics if very much like physics in both those respects. "
Sep 04, 2015 | Stephen Williamson New Monetarist Economics

So, within economics, is macro unusual? Of course not. Indeed, the whole emphasis of post-1970 macroeconomics is to do it like everyone else. Before 1970, no one would have been discussing macro and Dixit-Stiglitz in the same sentence. Should economics work like physics? Of course not. We're studying very different problems requiring very different methods. Why would you expect economists to behave like physicists?

What's my bottom line? Romer is just leading us through an unproductive conversation - one that's not going to persuade anyone of anything.

Anonymous, September 4, 2015 at 4:42 PM

"Romer is just leading us through an unproductive conversation - one that's not going to persuade anyone of anything."

It's almost as if Romer is wandering around testing the waters seeing how far he can push things before he actually says what he wants to say coherently.

Anonymous September 4, 2015 at 5:38 PM

Personally, I think he senses that RE/New Classicalism is in decline, not comprehending why, struggling to understand, looking for scapegoats (Solow, tribal behaviour, mathiness) and is essentially mourning its demise.

Henry.

Constantine Alexandrakis, September 4, 2015 at 6:16 PM
Steve, Solow agrees with you on Romer's contribution.

https://www.minneapolisfed.org/publications/the-region/interview-with-robert-solow

Norman, September 5, 2015 at 4:45 AM

Actually, Romer doesn't argue that physicists are not tribalists – he just asserts it, on the basis of a thought experiment based on two particular statements. It may well be true that there is a lot of consensus on the particular physics statements in his post, but no doubt you could also find a couple of statements in economics that most economists agree about. For evidence of tribalism in physics, google "superstring controversy," or at a more personal level, Newton and Hooke, Einstein and Lenard.

Or read Kuhn famous book on The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, in which he argues persuasively (or shows definitively, for those who prefer), that "Competition between segments of the scientific community [tribes?] is the only historical process that ever actually results in the rejection of one previously accepted theory or in the adoption of another," though at the same time, most progress comes from working within an established paradigm. My own intuition is that economics if very much like physics in both those respects.

As to how tribalism has arisen in economics, the answer is easy: economists are people, and people are tribal. Search the psychology of "ingroup bias".

[Sep 04, 2015] Four-fifths of the Economy is a Complete Waste of Time

EconoSpeak

Four-fifths of the "Economy" is a Complete Waste of Time

There are really two questions we are dealing with here. First, do inputs to production earn their marginal product? Second, do the owners of non-rival ideas have market power or not? -- Dietz Vollrath "What Assumptions Matter for Growth Theory?"
Dietz Vollrath has a new post that goes a long way toward clarifying the battle lines in the fight over the foundations of growth theory. -- Paul Romer, "The Assumptions in Growth Theory"
Huh? These fellows omit the main assumption, the analogy -- "growth is a concept whose proper domicile is the study of organic units..." (Kuznets, 1947). Kuznets cited with approval Sidney Hook's discussion of the dangers of the use of this analogy.
As an argument it is formally worthless and never logically compelling. An argument from analogy can be countered usually with another argument from analogy which leads to a diametrically opposed conclusion.... The belief that society is an organism is an old but fanciful notion. It can only be seriously entertained by closing the eye to all the respects in which a group of separate individuals differs from a system of connected cells, and by violently redefining terms like 'birth,' 'reproduction,' and 'death.'

Growth "theory" gets around this objection to the uncritical use of analogy by ignoring it -- by 'closing the eye' to explicit caveats in the seminal contribution to the measurement of growth. Let's pretend that the economy really is an organism that grows perpetually but never dies.

Name one.

Carry on, growth theorists.

[Sep 04, 2015] An Indicator of Tribalism in Macroeconomics by Paul Romer

Paul Romer just want personal recognition and posts junk. It's not tribalism, it is complete subservience to financial oligarchy.
"...Peer review matters when peers matter. Peers matter when neither government nor markets can guide progress. When peers don't matter tribalism takes over to redefine 'progress' into a conundrum of redundant repetitive Orwellian loops that allow anything to mean anything."
Sep 03, 2015 Paul Romer

Second Best said...


An Indicator of Tribalism in Macroeconomics - Paul Romer

'If we replace statements 1 and 2 with statements 3 and 4, we could construct a comparable measure of tribalism in physics. If we did, I suspect that we would find little tribalism there. I suspect that in comparison, this indicator would reveal that macroeconomists are very tribal.

The positive question that this assessment prompts is how this tribalism emerged in macroeconomics. To me, this is what makes the recent intellectual history of the field so interesting.'

---

The normative question is should anyone be allowed to don the credentials of an 'economist' and reduce the entire discipline to a sophmoric smattering of random thoughts that just happen to fill a particular tribal 'objectivist' standard?

Peer review matters when peers matter. Peers matter when neither government nor markets can guide progress. When peers don't matter tribalism takes over to redefine 'progress' into a conundrum of redundant repetitive Orewellian loops that allow anything to mean anything.

[Sep 03, 2015] Economics Has a Math Problem - Noah Smith

Comment from Economist's View Links for 09-02-15

Dan Kervick said...

Noah Smith:

"Econ developed as a form of philosophy and then added math later, becoming basically a form of mathematical philosophy."

Interesting! And true I think.

My own academic background was in analytic philosophy, and we too used and studied those various technical models of decision-making under uncertainty that the economists love. The difference is that philosophers use those tools to address purely conceptual puzzles and conundrums about the behavior of idealized super-rational agents in conceptually possible circumstances that are generally quite distant from actual world people and behavior: circumstances such as Newcomb problems or the Sleeping Beauty Problem.

When I first began to look into economics, I was surprised to learn how similar it was to philosophy in its tools and arguments. The difference was that economists put forward the same conceptual idealizations as descriptions of *the actual world*!

My impression is that a lot of economists are people who wandered into the field from math, theoretical physics and philosophy. Despite the fact that economics pretends to be a behavioral or social science, these wanderers from the other conceptual realms of the academy lack the empirical discipline to be real scientists, and aren't really terribly interested in the understanding and studying the behavior of actual human beings and societies. So they gravitate toward the areas of the field in which pulling sophisticated and rigorous conceptually fantasies out of one's butt is admired and glorified. These are the glamour pusses who intimidate everyone else with displays of pure mathematical and conceptual intelligence, and seem to lord it over the field and define the ground for pertinent discussion.

I have read a lot of interesting papers over the past few years that were based on serious data. But doing that kind of work doesn't seem to be the way you get famous in economics.

[Aug 31, 2015] The Case for Realism in the Social Realm

"...So there is nothing to choose. Current economics consists of political economics, which is scientifically worthless, and theoretical economics, which is logically and materially inconsistent. Luckily, Jackson Hole shows: economists are clueless but never speechless."
"...We will understand that there are real social processes, mechanisms, and powers; that they derive from the actions and agency of actors; and that these processes can be traced out through fairly direct sociological and historical research. And we will understand too that claims about the reality of "capitalism", the world financial system, or fascism are to be understood less weightily than they first appear. Capitalism exists in a time and place; but it is understood to be an ensemble of relations and actions by the people of the time."
Aug 31, 2015 | Economist's View

RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> djb...

[Yes, I know mine is exactly 6.25 inches because I measured it, but I can only guess that yours is shorter because there is no way that I am ever going to measure it :http://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2015/08/us-inflation-developments.html

Egmont Kakarot-Handtke said...

Always clueless, never speechless
Comment on 'U.S. Inflation Developments'

For a dispassionate observer Stanley Fischer's speech and the tidal wave of blog comments makes it pretty clear that there is an intellectual black hole where something like a true economic theory should be.

There is absolutely no use in entering into the morass of conflicting nonsense. Here are two fixpoints to secure some orientation.

• Inflation theory has never risen much above the commonplace Quantity Theory. The QT is plausible but ultimately untenable. The correct formula for the overall price level is given herehttps://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:AXEC64.pngfor details see (2015, eq. (12)).

• Alternative macroeconomic approaches like Krugman's IS-LM are fundamentally flawed since Keynes and Hicks (2014) without any economist ever spotting the provable formal defect.

So there is nothing to choose. Current economics consists of political economics, which is scientifically worthless, and theoretical economics, which is logically and materially inconsistent. Luckily, Jackson Hole shows: economists are clueless but never speechless.

Egmont Kakarot-Handtke

References
Kakarot-Handtke, E. (2014). Mr. Keynes, Prof. Krugman, IS-LM, and the End of Economics as We Know It. SSRN Working Paper Series, 2392856: 1–19. URL
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2392856
Kakarot-Handtke, E. (2015). Major Defects of the Market Economy. SSRN Working Paper Series, 2624350: 1–40. URL http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2624350

RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron...

[WOW! Typepad really screwed up that post. Here is what it dropped.

Keynes' definitions are debatable. I am in no way advocating the comment from yesterday's 'U.S. Inflation Developments' thread that I copy here nor its linked academic papers. I am actually defending Little's poorly written paper on this thread because there is a cogent point buried in his muddled over elaborated treatise on the distinctions between physical and social sciences. After reviewing the following and considering the sources of the actual "metrics" used in macro (e.g., interest, GDP, unemployment) then you might ask whether formalization or usefulness are the more important goals for macroeconomics.

For my part, then I find no fault in a heuristic approach as long as we know where we are trying to go. I am a huge fan of Keynes.]

RogerFox said...

"First, there are no theories in the social sciences that have the predictive and explanatory success of the physical sciences ..."

That admission necessarily puts the sword to social science theorizing, including interventionist macro, as an ethical guide to real world decision-making - the intervenors themselves admit they don't know whether the consequences of their interventions will make things worse or better.

Away with all the charlatans who insist on meddling anyway.

ilsm -> RogerFox...

Admission? Nah!

But there are no pentagon theories for war that can be relied upon.

See Vietnam, Iraq three times, Afghanistan.......

Fox admission only applies if you ignore reality.

djb -> RogerFox...

Yes RogerFox

Daniel Little who represents all people who have ever studied economics has let the cat out of the bag

That economists don't know anything

We were all hoping no one would notice, but of course, you are too sharp for us

Now of course it is probably too difficult for your shrunken brain to understand that your laissez faire philosophy is an economic concept, the results of which be studied and tested

But that's alright you got us

DAMN !!!

Peter K. -> RogerFox...

"interventionist macro,"

How can macro not be interventionist? In the middle of Krugman's latest blog post, he writes:

"What determines where we end up on that curve? Monetary policy. The Fed sets interest rates, whether it wants to or not - even a supposed hands-off policy has to involve choosing the level of the monetary base somehow, which means that it's a monetary policy choice."

"the intervenors themselves admit they don't know whether the consequences of their interventions will make things worse or better."

Not so, it's often easy to judge result.

What is Mr. Fox's school of thought? Know-nothingism? The Austrian school?

Peter K. -> Peter K....

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Know_Nothing

"The immigration of large numbers of Irish and German Catholics to the United States in the period between 1830 and 1860 made religious differences between Catholics and Protestants a political issue. Violence occasionally erupted at the polls. Protestants alleged that Pope Pius IX had put down the failed liberal Revolutions of 1848 and that he was an opponent of liberty, democracy and Republicanism. One Boston minister described Catholicism as "the ally of tyranny, the opponent of material prosperity, the foe of thrift, the enemy of the railroad, the caucus, and the school."

"The origin of the "Know Nothing" term was in the semi-secret organization of the party. When a member was asked about its activities, he was supposed to reply, "I know nothing." Outsiders called them "Know-Nothings", and the name stuck."

One can imagine an old-timey Donald Trump railing against Irish and German immigrants.

Lafayette said...

{We will understand that there are real social processes, mechanisms, and powers; that they derive from the actions and agency of actors; and that these processes can be traced out through fairly direct sociological and historical research. And we will understand too that claims about the reality of "capitalism", the world financial system, or fascism are to be understood less weightily than they first appear. Capitalism exists in a time and place; but it is understood to be an ensemble of relations and actions by the people of the time.}

Good point.

Capitalism is a mechanism, a tool. All outcomes depend upon how it is employed in a given socioeconomic context.

Have all property owned by the state, then all profits will also be owned by the state, since individuals will receive only income. Of course, they tried that (calling it commune-ism), and it worked very badly.

Having property owned by individuals is just as bad if said properties generate Income that trickles-up to Wealth, then is used to manipulate political outcomes that favor uniquely a certain class of individuals. (Which, for lack of a better word, we can call "Plutocrats".)

Who then, because they think they are good-parents, leave their riches to their children thus extending dynastically the inherent Income Disparity into Wealth Disparity. That's not the case? Then why does Domhoff show this class breakdown of Net Worth (Wealth - Debt) in 2010:
Top 1% Next 19% Bottom 80%
35.4% .....53.5% .....11.1%

No wonder the relatively poorer classes remain poor. Because if you don't have the educational qualifications (vocational, college, university) to scramble into the next class breakdown (the 20Percenters), then forget of any pretense to an existence without constant worry about how solid your job-prospects will be throughout your lifetime.

And, with that, any social coverage for either illness or pension, etc. - ad nauseam.

ilsm -> Lafayette...

Capitalism is a tool [scam] to keep useful fools asking for more flogging.

likbez -> Lafayette...

"Capitalism is a mechanism, a tool. All outcomes depend upon how it is employed in a given socioeconomic context."

I think outcomes can be by-and-large predicted from the form of social relations capitalism enforces. Looks like Marx prediction about increasing misery of the proletariat (or bottom 80%, if you wish) holds, despite temporary reversal of the trend in 1945-1985.

Yes, the current form of capitalism which is neoliberalism is a tool, but it is a tool only for financial oligarchy. The tool of oppression to be exact.

For workers of Asian sweatshops and Mexican maquiladoras and probably for a large part of Americans who face shrinking working hours (with the redefinition what full employment means -- now it does not mean 40 hours a week) and push into contractors without any social protection and McJobs, it is more of a prison then a tool.

Here we get into the concept of countervailing force. Without countervailing force capitalism inevitably degrades into horrible, comparable with feudalism and slavery level of oppression of human beings. And in a way it creates such forces by the mere fact of its existence. In this sense the collapse of the USSR, while improved fortunes of top 20% in the USSR region, was a huge blow to lower 80% of Americans.

Despite Margaret Thatcher pronouncement about TINA, now mankind (including large part of commenters of this blog ;-) is trying to find another viable countervailing force that can held neoliberalism in check.

Very high oil prices might do the trick, as they will reverse globalization but they also can lead to the collapse of Western civilization as we know it.

Some countries, like several in Latin America, try to revive elements of socialism on a new (post USSR crash) level, some elements of religious fundamentalism (with the most strong trends in Islam and Catholicism), some like Russia and China -- elements of state capitalism.

But those development should be probably be understood in the context of the reaction on neoliberalism, not as completely independent developments.

EugenR said...

You speak here about Social sciences about economic factors that drive the society, about the political power in the society, and out there it is not relevant at all. Out there in the other half of the world, which is banging on the doors of your world, the main agenda is tribalism, cultural and ethical belonging.

The leading agenda of these people, in the other half of the world is the faith in their local tribal myths. Their myth is not about God and submission to it, but about conspiracy theory of being victims. Victims of whom? Not of political and spiritual leaders from their tribes, who dragged them to the desperate existential problems. Not against the belief system, that pushes them to legitimize self imposed slavery, submission to the cruelest authority, and above all faith causing self imposed ignorance to knowledge. They don't see themselves victims of those among them, who by using force and violence, actively oppose learning and adaptation of modern teachings about social justice, political correctness, ethical systems of morality, legality, equality, fraternity.

No! They will chose to be stuck in their old belief system familiar to them. Ancient tribal stories full of contradictions, indoctrinating and legitimating hatred, murder of the different, slavery, inequality, female discrimination, minority suppression, racism, etc. All these values, that created the political social systems and brought all this destruction in their homeland, from where they try in these days to run away, still remains to be THEIR value system. They will blame all the "others" who caused them their misery. The European colonists, the US Imperialists, the Zionists, the infidels, the homosexuals, the women exposing their natural beauty to admiration of man and women, the atheists, the scientists who still stick to their rational way of thinking, etc. But most of all will be hated those who gave them hand, when they most needed it, the humanitarian volunteers, because they are the first others, whom they encounter, when they exited from their burning world of destruction, and hate.

They will start a fight against all the ideas of Western philosophers from Descartes to the post modernists, who seemingly successfully brought to the awareness of most of the "Western world" population the idea of human-centralism, following the disastrous WWII caused by similar myth imitators . After they settle down in their now homes, they will not torn their "Holly books", indoctrinating hate and violent action against the humanists, who put in front of their God the human being. They will not torn the burqa, the symbol of women's submission to arrogant male domination upon the women. Their spiritual leaders, when they will stand up in their legal or illegal houses of "GOD", and point to those who have to be hated. And it is not to hard to guess who they will be.

RC AKA Darryl, Ron -> EugenR...

Colonialism breeds reactionary radicalism among indigenous souls. On a grand scale nations do eventually reap a bit more than they sewed. Call it karma for lack of a better word.

EugenR -> RC AKA Darryl, Ron...

You are right, colonialism was a creepy, disastrous idea, even if at certain stage of human history it helped in the development of human understanding of the realities of the world. In the late nineteen century it became a very lousy business, and partially brought the first world war. Still to blame the Western colonialism that ended more than 50 years ago, for all the misery of Africa and the Arab world is just self deception...

ilsm said...

Observations on economics are blurred by the con artists and snake oil salesmen ruining civil society.

Observer and instrument effects are symptoms.

Peter K. said...

"If this is the approach we take, then our claims about what is "real" in the social realm will be more modest that some have thought. We will understand that there are real social processes, mechanisms, and powers; that they derive from the actions and agency of actors; and that these processes can be traced out through fairly direct sociological and historical research."

It's all shorthand. What needs to be kept in mind is that words and phrases are shorthand and don't really capture the concept or "real thing" they are relating between the person who employs them and the listener or reader. Math and equations too obviously are shorthand. You can follow the word or phrase with qualifying sentences to specify and clarify what you mean by it.

So when we talk about inflation, or full employment or "real" full employment or potential GDP or the Wicksellian Natural Rate or expected inflation, they are often contested concepts because they are shorthand and don't apply in an obvious manner to something "real" out there we can touch.

Because of all of this, people disagree on some basic ideas about the social realm. Monetary policy doesn't work they say. Fiscal policy doesn't work they say. Even if most of the smart, objective, honest, knowledgeable people you meet - or dead authors you read - say otherwise.

Just look at Mr. Fox. Language (shorthand) and contestable ideas bend easily to those under the influence of power, privilege and money.

[Aug 29, 2015] Great Recession Job Losses Severe, Enduring

Nothing particularly surprising here -- the Great recession was unusually severe and unusually long, and hence had unusual impacts, but it's good to have numbers characterizing what happened:

Great Recession Job Losses Severe, Enduring: Of those who lost full-time jobs between 2007 and 2009, only about 50 percent were employed in January 2010 and only about 75 percent of those were re-employed in full-time jobs.
The economic downturn that began in December 2007 was associated with a rapid rise in unemployment and with an especially pronounced increase in the number of long-term unemployed. In "Job Loss in the Great Recession and its Aftermath: U.S. Evidence from the Displaced Workers Survey" (NBER Working Paper No. 21216), Henry S. Farber uses data from the Displaced Workers Survey (DWS) from 1984-2014 to study labor market dynamics. From these data he calculates both the short-term and medium-term effects of the Great Recession's sharply elevated rate of job losses. He concludes that these effects have been particularly severe.

Of the workers who lost full-time jobs between 2007 and 2009, Farber reports, only about 50 percent were employed in January 2010 and only about 75 percent of those were re-employed in full-time jobs. This means only about 35 to 40 percent of those in the DWS who reported losing a job in 2007-09 were employed full-time in January 2010. This was by far the worst post-displacement employment experience of the 1981-2014 period.
The adverse employment experience of job losers has also been persistent. While both overall employment rates and full-time employment rates began to improve in 2009, even those who lost jobs between 2011 and 2013 had very low re-employment rates and, by historical standards, very low full-time employment rates.
In addition, the data show substantial weekly earnings declines even for those who did find work, although these earnings losses were not especially large by historical standards. Farber suggests that the earnings decline measure from the DWS is appropriate for understanding how job loss affects the earnings that a full-time-employed former job-loser is able to command.
The author notes that the measures on which he focuses may understate the true economic cost of job loss, since they do not consider the value of time spent unemployed or the value of lost health insurance and pension benefits.
Farber concludes that the costs of job losses in the Great Recession were unusually severe and remain substantial years later. Most importantly, workers laid off in the Great Recession and its aftermath have been much less successful at finding new jobs, particularly full-time jobs, than those laid off in earlier periods. The findings suggest that job loss since the Great Recession has had severe adverse consequences for employment and earnings.

[Aug 28, 2015] Q2 GDP Revised up to 3.7%

Aug 28, 2015 | Economist's View

anon

The Fed wants to raise interest rates:

- in the hope of preserving there institutional economic significance,

- out of a sense of loyalty to the Fed's history of financial influence using interest rates,

- because using rates to influence economic events increases their professional comfort,

- and because their economic grad school training was to fear wage push inflation above all else (they seem to believe that if inflation exceeds 2% it is a harbinger of hyper inflation).

Economists are post-industrial shamans whose witch doctor modeling impedes macro economic understanding. The precision of models is ersatz, more or less inversely proportional to its real world relevance. The delusion of being a scientist is critical to their professional self-respect.

Dan Kervick -> lower middle class...

A 3.7% quarter with several hands tied behind our backs by a don-nothing government. Think about what we could do if we were really trying.

pgl -> Dan Kervick...

YEA! Let's build that Mexican wall. Let's wage war on China. Lord - the stupidity here is multiplying!

Dan Kervick -> pgl...

This is an area in which you seem to be persistently incapable of avoiding lies.

You know very well that are a large number of ambitious long-term projects the US could do that are non-military, have nothing to do with immigration and could boost output tremendously.

You're becoming part of the LPTS crew: "liberal pundits terrified of socialism."

That's why Brad DeLong has an embargo on any talk about Bernie Sanders and his ideas.

That's why Paul Krugman is also avoiding Sanders like the plague and using daily red meet partisan servings to keep Democrats' attention riveted on the foibles of the Republicans.

That's why Brendan Nyhan has yet another column warning us all about the dangers of "Green Lanternism".

You're all pants-wetting terrified that the American people are tired of do-nothing neoliberal government, and will figure out that with a more assertive and economically engaged central government dynamic growth and social transformation are possible, and that the stagnation, predatory exploitation, cruel subjugation and social destruction wrought 40 years of neoliberalism was a horrible and completely avoidable mistake.

40% of this country has household income of under $40,000 per year. If we remove the plutocratic capitalist stranglehold on this economy, use government to more efficiently distribute and invest our national wealth, and demote private enterprise to its proper subordinate place, we could double that rapidly and drive a wave of high-growth social transformation with all of the liberated economic energy.

This is going to happen. Take your pick: we're either going to get the somewhat fascistic and racist Trump version on strong government or democratic socialist version. The Ivy League twits hanging on for dear life to their established networks, revolving doors, tit-for-tatting, sinecures and don't-rock-the-boat regime of stagnant managerialism are going to butts handed to them by history.

pgl -> Dan Kervick...

Blah, blah, blah. I guess we could employ more economists at the BEA to do what they are already doing at Census.

Dan Kervick -> pgl...

The Census doesn't and can't combine income distribution numbers with growth numbers on a monthly and quarterly basis. The BEA could collect this data, but doesn't, because it is part of their mission to pretend class conflict doesn't exist.

The top quintile in the US pulls down about 50% percent of the income. That means we could get 3.7% annualized growth if their income grew by 6% while everybody else's income grew by less than 1/2 a percent.

Is that what's happening? Inquiring minds want to know. It seems like a natural mission for the BEA to track this. But they don't.

pgl -> Dan Kervick...

You have no clue what these people do or the task you are whining about. With all you incessant babbling and whining - your keyboard is likely ready to just rot away.

Me? I'm headed down to the Starbucks to whine that they don't make tacos. Duh.

Dan Kervick -> pgl...

I know what they do, and I know what they don't do. Their mission should be expanded.

likbez -> Dan Kervick...

Dan,

I think you are mistaken about "a natural mission for the BEA to track this". Our elected officials and Wall Street executives all have a vested interest in keeping the perception of a robust economy alive. The economy growth numbers and the employment data announced are critical to this perception, but a thorough analysis of the data suggests something quite different that what we are told.

Statistics now became more and more "number racket" performed, like in the USSR, in the interest of the powers that be.

  • Think about "substitution" games in measuring consumer inflation.
  • Think about "Birth/Death adjustment" in employment data.
  • Think about tricks they play with GDP measurement.

The net result of this tricks is that the error margin of government statistics is pretty high. And nobody in economic profession is taking into account those error margins.

So in no way we can accept this 3.7% annualized growth figure. This is a fuzzy number, a distribution from probably 2.7% to 3.7%. Only upper bound is reported. And if you delve into the methodology deeper this range might be even wider. What is actually the assumption of quarterly inflation in the USA used in calculation of this number?

Which is another factor that makes neoliberal economics a pseudoscience, a branch of Lysenkoism.

JohnH -> Dan Kervick...

This is very revealing...nobody provides regular statistics on distribution. That lack of interest makes it blatantly obvious that policy makers only care about the top number--GDP--and are totally uninterested in knowing whether most Americans are prospering or not.

There is one source that updates Census data on a monthly basis. It shows that real median household income is still 3.8% below where it was in 2008 or in 2001. In fact, it's back where it was in the 1980s.

Of course, the 'recovery' has trickled down a bit, just as you would expect from trickle down monetary policy. Real median household incomes are no longer 9.6% below where they were in 2008...they're now only 3.8% below.
http://www.advisorperspectives.com/dshort/updates/Median-Household-Income-Update.php

Meanwhile, Saez and Montecino have pointed out that the 1% got 58% of the gains from the 'recovery,' while the 99% got 42%.

Of course, pgl doesn't even care enough about this to know where the data is...and, apparently, most 'liberal' economists are just as indifferent to distribution as he is.

Dan Kervick -> JohnH...

If it weren't for Piketty and Saez, we'd still be fumbling around in the dark on income and wealth distribution.

JohnH -> JohnH...

There's more here: real median household income by quintile 1967-2013
http://www.advisorperspectives.com/dshort/updates/Household-Income-Distribution.php

It shows the dramatic the separation between the top quintile and the bottom 80% during the Clinton years. Separation was even greater for the top 5%.

Yet the only thing that most economists ever notice is GDP growth...

pgl -> JohnH...

"Yet the only thing that most economists ever notice is GDP growth".

There you go again. Clueless as can be and lying your ass off.

likbez -> pgl...

And what you actually know about methodology of calculation of this GDP number. Inquiring minds want to know.

Correct calculation of nominal GDP depends on correct calculation of inflation, which is the most politicized of economic metrics and as such subject to tremendous level of manipulation.

Simon Kuznets, the economist who developed the first comprehensive set of measures of national income, stated in his first report to the US Congress in 1934, in a section titled "Uses and Abuses of National Income Measurements":

=== Start of quote ====
The valuable capacity of the human mind to simplify a complex situation in a compact characterization becomes dangerous when not controlled in terms of definitely stated criteria. With quantitative measurements especially, the definiteness of the result suggests, often misleadingly, a precision and simplicity in the outlines of the object measured. Measurements of national income are subject to this type of illusion and resulting abuse, especially since they deal with matters that are the center of conflict of opposing social groups where the effectiveness of an argument is often contingent upon oversimplification. [...]

All these qualifications upon estimates of national income as an index of productivity are just as important when income measurements are interpreted from the point of view of economic welfare. But in the latter case additional difficulties will be suggested to anyone who wants to penetrate below the surface of total figures and market values. Economic welfare cannot be adequately measured unless the personal distribution of income is known. And no income measurement undertakes to estimate the reverse side of income, that is, the intensity and unpleasantness of effort going into the earning of income. The welfare of a nation can, therefore, scarcely be inferred from a measurement of national income as defined above.

JohnH -> JohnH...

Another look at the ineffectiveness of trickle down monetary policy: all but the top decile have suffered decreases in wages and compensation since 2007.
http://www.epi.org/publication/pay-is-stagnant-for-vast-majority-even-when-you-include-benefits/

[Aug 22, 2015] Scientists Do Not Demonize Dissenters. Nor Do They Worship Heroes.

Paul Romer's latest entry on "mathiness" in economics ends with:
Reactions to Solow's Choice: ...Politics maps directly onto our innate moral machinery. Faced with any disagreement, our moral systems respond by classifying people into our in-group and the out-group. They encourage us to be loyal to members of the in-group and hostile to members of the out-group. The leaders of an in-group demand deference and respect. In selecting leaders, we prize unwavering conviction.

Science can't function with the personalization of disagreement that these reactions encourage. The question of whether Joan Robinson is someone who is admired and respected as a scientist has to be separated from the question about whether she was right that economists could reason about rates of return in a model that does not have an explicit time dimension.

The only in-group versus out-group distinction that matters in science is the one that distinguishes people who can live by the norms of science from those who cannot. Feynman integrity is the marker of an insider.

In this group, it is flexibility that commands respect, not unwavering conviction. Clearly articulated disagreement is encouraged. Anyone's claim is subject to challenge. Someone who is right about A can be wrong about B.

Scientists do not demonize dissenters. Nor do they worship heroes.

[The reference to Joan Robinson is clarified in the full text.]

Adam Eran said...

Max Planck would disagree: "The truth never triumphs. Its opponents simply die out. Science advances one funeral at a time."

Friday, August 21, 2015 at 04:02 PM

anne said in reply to Adam Eran...

https://en.wikiquote.org/wiki/Max_Planck

1948

A new scientific truth does not triumph by convincing its opponents and making them see the light, but rather because its opponents eventually die, and a new generation grows up that is familiar with it.

-- Max Planck

[ Thomas Kuhn would later write of this. ]

likbez said...

Now science became highly political occupation. This is especially true about economics.

So dismal behavior of scientists and flourishing of pseudoscience are to be expected. Rewards offered to conformists are just too great not to seduce people.

Actually it looks like Lysenkoism is the mark of the present and the future, not so much of the past.

[Aug 03, 2015] Freshwater's Wrong Turn

"... This reminds me of the "we create reality" stuff from the neo-cons. Maybe it's just more infection of Straussian "ethics" at UofC (see Shadia Drury).
Aug 2, 2015 | Economist's View

Paul Krugman follows up on Paul Romer's latest attack on "mathiness":

Freshwater's Wrong Turn (Wonkish): Paul Romer has been writing a series of posts on the problem he calls "mathiness", in which economists write down fairly hard-to-understand mathematical models accompanied by verbal claims that don't actually match what's going on in the math. Most recently, he has been recounting the pushback he's getting from freshwater macro types, who seem him as allying himself with evil people like me - whereas he sees them as having turned away from science toward a legalistic, adversarial form of pleading.
You can guess where I stand on this. But in his latest, he notes some of the freshwater types appealing to their glorious past, claiming that Robert Lucas in particular has a record of intellectual transparency that should insulate him from criticism now. PR replies that Lucas once was like that, but no longer, and asks what happened.
Well, I'm pretty sure I know the answer. ...

It's hard to do an extract capturing all the points, so you'll likely want to read the full post, but in summary:

So what happened to freshwater, I'd argue, is that a movement that started by doing interesting work was corrupted by its early hubris; the braggadocio and trash-talking of the 1970s left its leaders unable to confront their intellectual problems, and sent them off on the path Paul now finds so troubling.

Recent tweets, email, etc. in response to posts I've done on mathiness reinforce just how unwilling many are to confront their tribalism. In the past, I've blamed the problems in macro on, in part, the sociology within the profession (leading to a less than scientific approach to problems as each side plays the advocacy game) and nothing that has happened lately has altered that view.

Posted by Mark Thoma on Sunday, August 2, 2015 at 11:54 AM in Economics, Macroeconomics, Methodology | Permalink Comments (20)

pgl said...
When I first heard this Lucas island - also known as Friedman-Phelps - story about business cycles being driven by unanticipated inflation, it initially stuck me as interested. Then I thought about the fact that the Rational Expectations version would have trouble explaining why nominal shocks affect real events for more than a few months.

No - it did not take long to realize that this nice neat model could not explain the real world. But what we usually got back then is a large parade of statistical techniques that just confused matters even more.

At which I began to wonder what I was interested in macroeconomics in the first place.

eightnine2718281828mu5 said in reply to pgl...
---
the braggadocio and trash-talking of the 1970s left its leaders unable to confront their intellectual problems
---

iow, assigning a higher value to their accumulated research (reputation?) than it was actually worth.

sticky prices indeed.

RC AKA Darryl, Ron said in reply to eightnine2718281828mu5...
:<)

[For most of us then:]

"...Freedom's just another word for nothing left to lose
Nothing don't mean nothing honey, if it ain't free
Feeling good was easy, Lord, when he sang the blues
You know, feeling good was good enough for me
Good enough for me and my Bobby McGee..."
ARTIST: Kris Kristofferson
TITLE: Me and Bobby McGee

*

[For most of them then freedom is just a matter of low-regulation low-tax supply side economic policy. TO which end their statistics demand many degrees of "freedom" and they have taken increasingly more extensive "freedoms" with their theories ever since Uncle Milty taught us about "Capitalism and Freedom," why the initial conclusions reached by Keynes were all wrong, and why monetarism was sacred. (barf)

I remember the 1970's well. The terminal punctuation was Reagan's election in 1980. When I was drafted in 1969 I still retained some hope, although much diminished since MLK was murdered a year earlier. By the time I returned from Viet Nam it was just one slap in the face after another. All our (the social movement that happened alongside the hippies) hopes from the 60's were dashed. Blacks were to be "locked" into ghettos by public policy and the working class was to be sacrificed on the alter of corporatism one merger or outsource at a time. ]

anne said...

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Real_business_cycle_theory

Real business cycle theory models (RBC theory) are a class of New classical macroeconomics models in which business cycle fluctuations to a large extent can be accounted for by real (in contrast to nominal) shocks. Unlike other leading theories of the business cycle, RBC theory sees business cycle fluctuations as the efficient response to exogenous changes in the real economic environment. That is, the level of national output necessarily maximizes expected utility, and governments should therefore concentrate on long-run structural policy changes and not intervene through discretionary fiscal or monetary policy designed to actively smooth out economic short-term fluctuations.

anne said in reply to anne...
http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2014/02/17/the-trouble-with-being-abstruse-slightly-wonkish/

February 17, 2014

The Trouble With Being Abstruse (Slightly Wonkish)
By Paul Krugman

Political scientists who write clearly for a broader audience are upset * with Nick Kristof ** for saying that political scientists no longer write for a broader audience. I'm not going to get into that fight. I do want to register one point, however: In my field there is indeed a problem with abstruseness, with the many academics who never even try to put their thoughts in plain language.

And what is the nature of that problem? It's not that laypeople don't understand what the academics are saying. It is, instead, that the academics themselves don't understand what they're saying.

Don't get me wrong: I like mathematical modeling. Mathematical modeling is a friend of mine. Math can be a powerful clarifying tool. So, in some cases, can jargon, which used right can both save time and add clarity to the discussion. If I talk about Dixit-Stiglitz preferences, or for that matter the zero lower bound, technically trained economists immediately know whereof I speak, where plain English would both take longer and leave room for misunderstanding.

But it's really important to step away from the math and drop the jargon every once in a while, and not just as a public service. Trying to explain what you're doing intuitively isn't just for the proles; it's an important way to check on yourself, to be sure that your story is at least halfway plausible.

Take real business cycle theory – I know it's a horse I beat a lot, but it's not dead, and it's a prime example within economics of what I have in mind. I still want to spend at least some time explaining that theory to my undergrads, so I've been looking for a simple, intuitive explanation by an RBC theorist of what's going on. And I haven't been able to find one!

I mean, I could do it myself. Strip the story down to basics – make it a steady-state model, not a growth model, and drop the capital accumulation; what you're left with is fluctuations in the marginal productivity of labor, which have a magnified impact on output because workers choose to work less when the technology is bad and more when the technology is good. As I've written before someplace, it's the story of a farmer who stays inside when it's raining and puts in extra hours when the sun is shining.

But the RBC theorists never seem to go there; it's right into calibration and statistical moments, with never a break for intuition. And because they never do the simple version, they don't realize (or at any rate don't admit to themselves) how fundamentally silly the whole thing sounds, how much it's at odds with lived experience.

I once talked to a theorist (not RBC, micro) who said that his criterion for serious economics was stuff that you can't explain to your mother. I would say that if you can't explain it to your mother, or at least to your non-economist friends, there's a good chance that you yourself don't really know what you're doing.

Math is good. Sometimes jargon is good, too. But plain language and simple intuition are important to keep you grounded.

* http://crookedtimber.org/2014/02/16/look-who-nick-kristofs-saving-now/

** http://www.nytimes.com/2014/02/16/opinion/sunday/kristof-professors-we-need-you.html

mulp said in reply to anne...
Freshwater economists, free lunch economists, speak very clearly.

Its too good to be true which makes everyone who wants a free lunch to believe it.

For example, free lunch economists say lower prices are achieved by lower wages, fewer workers, tax cuts, and higher profits, which creates wealth, and the unemployed and working poor spend more using money the will never pay back because of the wealth effect, with mathiness to backup their claims.

What they never do is put them all together like I have done so the words are revealed as nonsense and the math is 1+2-3 = 10 and thus obviously bogus.

Note fresh water economists NEVER state that consumer spending is driven by wage income, as in real wage income, not the income from capital gains which sorta lots like wages but is really rent seeking aka private tax on the savings of workers.

How can lower wages to get lower prices ever result in higher GDP without lots of debt that can never be repaid?

Lafayette said in reply to anne...
TO APE ONE ANOTHER

{PK: with the many academics who never even try to put their thoughts in plain language.}

Ha! I like that!

Tis True. How many times do we see the word "exogenous". Many. How often, "endogenous"? Never.

Anybody for a hard look at the "endogenous" factors causing economic cyclicity? How about the human ability to "ape" one another's consumer habits that builds patterns increasing in intensity - until the "bubble" bursts? ("Cyclicity"? Wow! Nice word? Hardly used! Here we go again!!!;^)

Like lemmings falling off a cliff - cyclic in nature but deadly in consequence.

DeDude said...
When your math is incompatible with the observations from the real world - its the math that's wrong. I don't have a 3 page formula, but just trust me on this one.
GeorgeK said...
You will find the answers to all your questions in this book
http://www.amazon.com/Wiser-Getting-Beyond-Groupthink-Smarter/dp/1422122999/ref=sr_1_1?s=books&ie=UTF8&qid=1438554831&sr=1-1&keywords=Group+think+getting+beyond

bakho said...

Science advances one funeral at a time. - Max Planck

They are too invested in their mistakes to accept criticism.
The next generation of economists will accept that they were wrong.

likbez said...
Before becoming columnist Krugman was mathiness practioner ;-)

reason said...

Anne
"That is, the level of national output necessarily maximizes expected utility"

We could stop right there. Clear nonsense. (You can always INCREASE utility by redistributing from rich to poor - at least with any sensible definition of utility.

See this discussion
http://crookedtimber.org/2015/07/24/utilitarianism-with-the-potentially-left-wing-bits-stripped-out/comment-page-2/

Egmont Kakarot-Handtke said...

Here it comes: the sexit
Comment on 'Freshwater's Wrong Turn'

There is political economics and theoretical economics. In political economics it suffices to tell a plausible story, in theoretical economics scientific standards are observed. Because economists since Adam Smith pursued these two hares simultaneously, coherence got eventually lost. As a result, economists never developed a theory about how the market economy works that satisfies the scientific criteria of material and formal consistency (Klant, 1994, p. 31).

Economics is a failed science. Therefore, Paul Romer is in for a second big surprise. Until now he thought: "As you would expect from an economist, the normative assertion in 'X is wrong because it undermines the scientific method' is based on what I thought would be a shared premise ..."

Now he learns: "In conversations with economists who are sympathetic to the freshwater economists ... it has become clear that freshwater economists do not share this premise. What I did not anticipate was their assertion that economists do not follow the scientific method, so it is not realistic or relevant to make normative statements of the form 'we ought to behave like scientists'."

What is the difference between political and theoretical economics?

"A genuine inquirer aims to find out the truth of some question, whatever the color of that truth. ... A pseudo-inquirer seeks to make a case for the truth of some proposition(s) determined in advance. There are two kinds of pseudo-inquirer, the sham and the fake. A sham reasoner is concerned, not to find out how things really are, but to make a case for some immovably-held preconceived conviction. A fake reasoner is concerned, not to find out how things really are, but to advance himself by making a case for some proposition to the truth-value of which he is indifferent." (Haack, 1997, p. 1)

The fact of the matter is that theoretical economics has from the very beginning been hijacked by the agenda pushers of political economics. Smith and Mill were agenda pushers against feudalism. Marx and Keynes were agenda pushers and so were Hayek and Friedman. However, all these economists insisted that they were doing science. This has changed now: "... the evidence ... suggests that freshwater economists differ sharply from other economists."

The freshwater economists simply state the obvious, that is, that they are committed to politics and not to science. This marks the beginning of a voluntary scientific exit (sexit for short). What Romer has not yet realized is that most saltwater economists have to leave through the same door.

Egmont Kakarot-Handtke

References
Haack, S. (1997). Science, Scientism, and Anti-Science in the Age of Preposterism. Skeptical Inquirer, 21(6): 1–7. URL http://www.csicop.org/si/show/science_scientism_and_anti-science_in_the_age_of_preposterism.
Klant, J. J. (1994). The Nature of Economic Thought. Aldershot, Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar.

lagarita said...

This reminds me of the "we create reality" stuff from the neo-cons. Maybe it's just more infection of Straussian "ethics" at UofC (see Shadia Drury).

Lafayette said in reply to lagarita...

APART FROM BERNIE

{"we create reality"}

Their entire existence revolves around such vapid, empty simplisms because they have no theoretical substance to their politics. It is either their lack of intelligence or their selfish perfidy that reduces their theoretical foundation of political views.

They are hooked on the fallacy of wealth-creation as the sole credible goal/consequence of an economy. Piketty put that thought to shame in his work on Income Disparity, as did Domhoff on Wealth Disparity. The statistical facts (ie., the "numbers") could not be more clear.

What should bother us most is not only the generation of enormous wealth, and the influence it has on a moneyed electoral system, but the dynastic tendency of such riches. The Koch Bros are already the first generation - will we be contending with the political antics of second, or third, or fourth generations?

The last time historically that happened in Europe, called Inheritance Aristocracy, it all came apart in bloodshed.

And yet the better notion of Social Justice, which supposes that all humans are created with the equal right to fairness and equitability, has taken decades upon decades to come to the fore.

It is still no where near dominating political thought in America. Apart from Bernie, that is ...

Lafayette said...
LOOK IN THE MIRROR

{the braggadocio and trash-talking of the 1970s}

Of the 1970s?

This type is still the mainstay of American parlance, whether political or business or just blogging. The aggressiveness of the language employed knows no bounds.

The intent in commentary, whether verbal or written, whether political or otherwise, is overly combative and largely "ad hominem". The real subject of controversy is lost in the personalization of the rebuttals. The issues that largely determine the political consensus thus become secondary and confused.

Really 'n truly puerile ... like the children they were and they remain, particularly in politics. Propelled by one and only one goal - to win, win, win.

And without politics or politicians, what is a democracy? It's an autocracy. With them, its a manifested willfulness by a moneyed few to dominate electoral outcomes - and we are pawns in the game.

My point? As an electorate, the people we chose to represent us personify as well the kind of people we are. So, complaining about the politicos in LaLaLand on the Potomac is useless.

Seeking someone to blame? Look in the mirror ...

[Jul 29, 2015] Using Math to Obfuscate - Observations from Finance

"...Unfortunately, I was wrong even about the equilibrium in the academic world, where mathiness is in fact used to obfuscate. In the world of for-profit finance, the return to obfuscation in communication with regulators is much higher, so there is every reason to expect that mathiness would be used liberally, particularly in mandated disclosures. ..."
More from Paul Romer on "mathiness" -- this time the use of math in finance to obfuscate communication with regulators:
Using Math to Obfuscate - Observations from Finance: The usual narrative suggests that the new mathematical tools of modern finance were like the wings that Daedalus gave Icarus. The people who put these tools to work soared too high and crashed.

In two posts, here and here, Tim Johnson notes that two government investigations (one in the UK, the other in the US) tell a different tale. People in finance used math to hide what they were doing.

One of the premises I used to take for granted was that an argument presented using math would be more precise than the corresponding argument presented using words. Under this model, words from natural language are more flexible than math. They let us refer to concepts we do not yet fully understand. They are like rough prototypes. Then as our understanding grows, we use math to give words more precise definitions and meanings. ...

I assumed that because I was trying to use math to reason more precisely and to communicate more clearly, everyone would use it the same way. I knew that math, like words, could be used to confuse a reader, but I assumed that all of us who used math operated in a reputational equilibrium where obfuscating would be costly. I expected that in this equilibrium, we would see only the use of math to clarify and lend precision.

Unfortunately, I was wrong even about the equilibrium in the academic world, where mathiness is in fact used to obfuscate. In the world of for-profit finance, the return to obfuscation in communication with regulators is much higher, so there is every reason to expect that mathiness would be used liberally, particularly in mandated disclosures. ...

We should expect that there will be mistakes in math, just as there are mistakes in computer code. We should also expect some inaccuracies in the verbal claims about what the math says. A small number of errors of either type should not be a cause for alarm, particularly if the math is presented transparently so that readers can check the math itself and check whether it aligns with the words. In contrast, either opaque math or ambiguous verbal statements about the math should be grounds for suspicion. ...

Mathiness–exposition characterized by a systematic divergence between what the words say and what the math implies–should be rejected outright.

Posted by on Wednesday, July 29, 2015 at 10:52 AM in Economics, Financial System, Methodology | Permalink Comments (2)

[Jul 20, 2015] The Rivals (Samuelson and Friedman)

Jul 19, 2015 | Economist's View

pete said...

I always loved Boulding's somewhat critical review of Samuelson, discussing the limits of the mathematicization of economic theory. Of course Samuelson was the tip of the iceberg, and since then many overconfident economic mathematicians have led to very serious financial problems. I had one stats professor who called a complex theory on the blackboard "graffiti."

http://www.jstor.org/stable/1825768?seq=1#page_scan_tab_contents

pgl -> pete...
Samuelson did not do math for math's sake. He figured out first what the real world issue was and then used math to help explain his insights.
likbez -> pgl...
You need to distinguish "math" from "mathematical masturbation", or as they are now more politically correctly called "mathiness".

Many economic works that use differential equations belong to the latter category ;-). A lot of pitiful clowns pretending to be mathematicians do not even bother to understand what is the precision and error bounds of the input data. As in "garbage in, garbage out".

This is probably a unique case when mathematic equations are used to support particular political ideology. Support via "scietification" (as in Church of Scientology) of essentially political statements. Especially about unemployment and poverty.

anne -> anne...

All in all, the past 7 years have been a very good time for old-fashioned macroeconomics. But of course nothing will make the Germans, or the U.S. right, concede that Keynesian ideas have worked.

[ Keynesian ideas have worked? Influential among policy makers in general or not, Keynesian ideas have worked. ]

pgl -> anne...

Keynesian theory explains what happened. But what happened was the our policy makers failed to do the right thing. Had they listened to Keynes - the recoveries would have been much faster.

likbez -> pgl...

"Had they listened to Keynes - the recoveries would have been much faster."

This was impossible. There is such thing as "Intellectual capture". As Keyes noted

"The ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed, the world is ruled by little else. Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual influences, are usually slaves of some defunct economist."

[Jun 15, 2015] Academics Who Defend Wall St. Reap Reward

"... What Mr. Pirrong has routinely left out of most of his public pronouncements in favor of speculation is that he has reaped financial benefits from speculators and some of the largest players in the commodities business, The New York Times has found. ..."
"... The efforts by the financial players, the interviews show, are part of a sweeping campaign to beat back regulation and shape policies that affect the prices that people around the world pay for essentials like food, fuel and cotton. ..."
December 27, 2013 | NYTimes.com

Signs of the energy business are inescapable in and around Houston - the pipelines, refineries and tankers that crowd the harbor, and the gleaming office towers where oil companies and energy traders have transformed the skyline.

And in a squat glass building on the University of Houston campus, a measure of the industry's pre-eminence can also be found in the person of Craig Pirrong, a professor of finance, who sits at the nexus of commerce and academia.

As energy companies and traders have reaped fortunes by buying and selling oil and other commodities during the recent boom in the commodity markets, Mr. Pirrong has positioned himself as the hard-nosed defender of financial speculators - the combative, occasionally acerbic academic authority to call upon when difficult questions arise in Congress and elsewhere about the multitrillion-dollar global commodities trade.

Do financial speculators and commodity index funds drive up prices of oil and other essentials, ultimately costing consumers? Since 2006, Mr. Pirrong has written a flurry of influential letters to federal agencies arguing that the answer to that question is an emphatic no. He has testified before Congress to that effect, hosted seminars with traders and government regulators, and given countless interviews for financial publications absolving Wall Street speculation of any appreciable role in the price spikes.

What Mr. Pirrong has routinely left out of most of his public pronouncements in favor of speculation is that he has reaped financial benefits from speculators and some of the largest players in the commodities business, The New York Times has found.

While his university's financial ties to speculators have been the subject of scrutiny by the news media and others, it was not until last month, after repeated requests by The Times under the Freedom of Information Act, that the University of Houston, a public institution, insisted that Mr. Pirrong submit disclosure forms that shed some light on those financial ties.

Governments and regulatory agencies in the United States and Europe have been gradually moving to restrict speculation by major banks. The Federal Reserve, concerned about the risks, is reviewing whether it should tighten regulations and limit the activities of banks in the commodities world.

But interviews with dozens of academics and traders, and a review of hundreds of emails and other documents involving two highly visible professors in the commodities field - Mr. Pirrong and Professor Scott H. Irwin at the University of Illinois - show how major players on Wall Street and elsewhere have been aggressive in underwriting and promoting academic work.

The efforts by the financial players, the interviews show, are part of a sweeping campaign to beat back regulation and shape policies that affect the prices that people around the world pay for essentials like food, fuel and cotton.

Professors Pirrong and Irwin say that industry backing did not color their opinions.

Mr. Pirrong's research was cited extensively by the plaintiffs in a lawsuit filed by Wall Street interests in 2011 that for two years has blocked the limits on speculation that had been approved by Congress as part of the Dodd-Frank financial reform law. During that same time period, Mr. Pirrong has worked as a paid research consultant for one of the lead plaintiffs in the case, the International Swaps and Derivatives Association, according to his disclosure form.

While he customarily identifies himself solely as an academic, Mr. Pirrong has been compensated in the last several years by the Chicago Mercantile Exchange, the commodities trading house Trafigura, the Royal Bank of Scotland, and a handful of companies that speculate in energy, according to the disclosure forms.

The disclosure forms do not require Mr. Pirrong to reveal how much money he made from his consulting work, and a university spokesman said that the university believed it was strengthened by the financial support it received from the business community. When asked about the financial benefits of his outside activities, Mr. Pirrong replied, "That's between me and the I.R.S."

Debating to a Stalemate

No one disputes that a substantial portion of price increases in oil and food over the last decade were caused by fundamental market factors: increased demand from China and other industrializing countries, extreme weather, currency fluctuations and the diversion of grain to biofuel.

But so much speculative money poured into markets - from $13 billion in 2003 to $317 billion at a peak in 2008 - that many economists, and even some commodities traders and investment banks, say the flood became a factor of its own in distorting prices.

Others assert that commodities markets have historically gone through intermittent price bubbles and that the most recent gyrations were not caused by the influx of speculative money. Mr. Pirrong has also argued that the huge inflow of Wall Street money may actually lower costs by decreasing what commodities producers pay to manage their risk.

Mr. Pirrong and the University of Houston are not alone in publicly defending speculation while accepting financial help from speculators. Other researchers have received funding or paid consulting jobs courtesy of major commodities traders including AIG Financial Products, banks including the Royal Bank of Canada or financial industry groups like the Futures Industry Association.

One of the most widely quoted defenders of speculation in agricultural markets, Mr. Irwin of the University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign, consults for a business that serves hedge funds, investment banks and other commodities speculators, according to information received by The Times under the Freedom of Information Act. The business school at the University of Illinois has received more than a million dollars in donations from the Chicago Mercantile Exchange and several major commodities traders, to pay for scholarships and classes and to build a laboratory that resembles a trading floor at the commodities market.

Mr. Irwin, the University of Illinois and the Chicago exchange all say that his research is not related to the financial support.

Underwriting researchers and academic institutions is one part of Wall Street's efforts to fend off regulation.

The industry has also spent millions on lobbyists and lawyers to promote its views in Congress and with government regulators. Major financial companies have also funded magazines and websites to promote academics with friendly points of view. When two studies commissioned by the Commodity Futures Trading Commission, the financial regulatory agency, raised questions about the possible drawbacks of speculation and of high-frequency trading, lawyers for the Chicago exchange wrote a letter of complaint, saying that its members' proprietary trading information was at risk of disclosure, and the research program was shut down.

The result of the various Wall Street efforts has been a policy stalemate that has allowed intensive speculation in commodities to continue despite growing concern that it may harm consumers and, for example, worsen food shortages. After a two-year legal delay, the futures trading commission this month introduced plans for new limits on speculation. Some European banks have stopped speculating in food, fearing it might contribute to worldwide hunger.

Mr. Pirrong, Mr. Irwin and other scholars say that financial considerations have not influenced their work. In some cases they have gone against the industry's interests. They also say that other researchers with no known financial ties to the industry have also raised doubts about any link involving speculation and soaring prices.

But ethics experts say that when academics fail to disclose financial ties, they do a disservice to the public and undermine the perception of impartiality.

"If those that are creating the culture around financial regulation also have a significant, if hidden, conflict of interest, our public is not likely to be well served," said Gerald Epstein, an economics professor at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst, who in 2010 released a study about conflicts of interest among academics who advised the federal government after the financial crisis.

Speculation in the Market

Financial ties among professors promoting speculation and the banks and trading firms that profit from it date back to the beginning of the recent commodities boom, which got an intellectual kick-start from academia.

After Congress and the Clinton administration deregulated the commodities markets in 2000, and the Securities and Exchange Commission lowered capital requirements on investment banks in 2004, the financial giants began developing new funds to capitalize on the opportunity.

AIG Financial Products commissioned two highly respected Yale University professors in 2004 to analyze the performance of commodities markets over a half-century. The professors - who prominently acknowledged the financial support - concluded that commodities markets "work well when they are needed most," namely when the stock and bond markets falter.

Money flowed into the commodities markets, and although the markets have cooled in the last two years, the price of oil is now four times what it was a decade ago, and corn, wheat and soybeans are all more than twice as expensive.

A public uproar about the rising prices became heated in the spring of 2008, as oil soared and gas prices became an issue in the presidential campaign. Congress scheduled public hearings to explore whether speculation had become so excessive it was distorting prices.

Financial speculators are investors who bet on price swings without any intention of taking delivery of the physical commodity. They can help smooth the volatility of the market by adding capital, spreading risk and offering buyers and sellers a kind of price insurance. But an assortment of studies by academics, congressional committees and consumer advocate groups had found evidence suggesting that the wave of speculation that accelerated in 2003 had at times overwhelmed the market.

Financial speculators accounted for 30 percent of commodities markets in 2002, and 70 percent in 2008. As gasoline topped $4 a gallon in the summer of 2008, Congress tried to soothe angry motorists by pushing for restrictions on oil speculation.

Mr. Pirrong jumped into the fray. He wrote papers, blog posts and opinion pieces for publications like The Wall Street Journal, calling the concern about speculation "a witch hunt."

Mr. Pirrong also testified before the House of Representatives in 2008 and, identifying himself as an academic who had worked for commodities exchanges a decade earlier, he warned that congressional plans to rein in speculators would only make matters worse.

"Indeed, such policies are likely to harm U.S. consumers and producers," he said. When oil company executives, traders and investment banks cited speculation as a major cause of surging prices which, by some estimates, was costing American consumers more than $300 billion a year, Mr. Pirrong dutifully contradicted them.

Mr. Pirrong's profile grew as he sat on advisory panels and hosted conferences with senior executives from the trading world as well as top federal regulators. Last year, Blythe Masters, head of commodity trading at JPMorgan Chase, approached him to write a report for a global bank lobbying group, the Global Financial Markets Association.

The report was completed in July 2012, but the association declined to release it. Mr. Pirrong said it was because he had reached the conclusion that banks should be regulated more heavily than other commodity traders. "I wouldn't change the call, so they sat on the report," he wrote on his blog, The Streetwise Professor.

What Mr. Pirrong did not reveal in his public statements about the report is that he had financial ties to both sides of that debate: the commodities traders as well as the banks. Ms. Masters declined to comment. Over the years, Mr. Pirrong has resisted releasing details of his own financial dealings with speculators, and when The Times first requested his disclosure forms in March, the University of Houston said that none were required of him. The disclosure forms Mr. Pirrong ultimately filed in November indicate that since 2011, he has been paid for outside work involving 11 different clients. Some fees are for his work as an expert witness, testifying in court cases on behalf of the Chicago Mercantile Exchange and a bank and a company that makes futures-trading software. The commodities firm Trafigura contracted him to conduct a research project.

Mr. Pirrong is also a member of the advisory board for TruMarx Partners, a company that sells software to energy traders, a position that entitles him to a stock option package.

It was reported in The Nation magazine in November that the University of Houston's Global Energy Management Institute, where Mr. Pirrong serves as a director, has also received funding from the Chicago exchange, as well as financial institutions that profit from speculation, including Citibank and Bank of America.

On his blog, Mr. Pirrong has dismissed suggestions that his work for a school that trains future oil industry executives creates a conflict of interest.

"Uhm, no, dipstick," he wrote in 2011, replying to a reader who had questioned his objectivity. "I call 'em like I see 'em." In a telephone interview last week, Mr. Pirrong said that his consulting work gave him insight into the kind of real-world case studies that improve his research and teaching. "My compensation doesn't depend on my conclusions," he said.

When asked about Mr. Pirrong's disclosure, Richard Bonnin, a university spokesman said only that all employees were given annual training on the school's policy, which requires researchers to report paid outside consultant work.

Professors as Pitchmen

Concerns about academic conflicts of interest have become a major issue among business professors and economists since the financial crisis. In 2010, the documentary "Inside Job" blasted a handful of prominent academic economists who did not reveal Wall Street's financial backing of studies which, in some cases, extolled the virtues of financially unsound assets. Two years later, the American Economic Association adopted tougher disclosure rules.

Even with the guidelines, however, financial firms have been able to use the resources and credibility of academia to shape the political debate.

The Chicago Mercantile Exchange and the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, for example, at times blur the line between research and public relations.

The exchange's public relations staff has helped Mr. Irwin shop his pro-speculation essays to newspaper op-ed pages, according to emails reviewed by The Times. His studies, writings, videotaped speeches and interviews have been displayed on the exchange's website and its online magazine.

In June 2009, when a Senate subcommittee released a report about speculation in the wheat market that raised concerns about new regulations, executives at the Chicago exchange turned to Mr. Irwin and his University of Illinois colleagues to come up with a response.

Dr. Paul Ellinger, department head of agriculture and consumer economics, said, "The interactions that have occurred here are common among researchers."

A spokesman for the exchange said that Mr. Irwin was just one of a "large and growing pool of esteemed academics, governmental editors and editors in the mainstream press" whose work it follows and posts on its various publications. While the C.M.E. has given more than $1.4 million to the University of Illinois since 2008, most has gone to the business school and none to the School of Agriculture and Consumer Economics, where Mr. Irwin teaches. And when Mr. Irwin asked the exchange's foundation for $25,000 several years ago to sponsor a website he runs to inform farmers about agricultural conditions and regulations, his request was denied.

Still, some of Mr. Irwin's recent research has been funded by major players in the commodities world. Last year, he was paid $50,000 as a consultant for Gresham Investment Management in Chicago, which manages $16 billion and runs its own commodities index fund. He noted Gresham's sponsorship in the paper and on his disclosure form, and said it gave him the opportunity to use new data and test new hypotheses.

Mr. Irwin also works for a business called Yieldcast that caters to agricultural producers, investments banks and other speculators, selling them predictions of corn and soybean yields. Mr. Irwin has said he does not consider it a conflict because he works only with the mathematical forecasting models and never consults with clients.

"The debate about financialization is primarily about the large index funds, none of whom are clients," he said.

Mr. Irwin declined to provide a list of his clients, and the university said its disclosure requirements did not compel him to do so.

This article has been revised to reflect the following correction:

Correction: December 31, 2013

An article on Saturday about financial rewards from Wall Street to academic experts whose research supports the financial community's views on commodity trading misidentified a Canadian bank and commodities trader that financed the work of academic researchers or paid consultants. It is the Royal Bank of Canada, not the Bank of Canada, which is that nation's central bank. The article also rendered incorrectly the university affiliation of Scott H. Irwin, a prominent defender of speculation in agricultural markets. He is a professor at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign - not Champaign-Urbana. And a picture caption with the continuation of the article misidentified the subject of one of several pictures. The lower right photograph showed the atrium of the University of Illinois's business school - not its Market Information Lab, which was shown behind Professor Irwin in the photograph at the left.

Response from the academic criminal: Streetwise Professor

Related

Read All Comments (440)

[Jun 15, 2015] What Assumptions Matter for Growth Theory

Jun 15, 2015 | Economist's View
Dietz Vollrath explains the "mathiness" debate (and also Euler's theorem in a part of the post I left out). Glad he's interpreting Romer -- it's very helpful:
What Assumptions Matter for Growth Theory?: The whole "mathiness" debate that Paul Romer started tumbled onwards this week... I was able to get a little clarity in this whole "price-taking" versus "market power" part of the debate. I'll circle back to the actual "mathiness" issue at the end of the post.
There are really two questions we are dealing with here. First, do inputs to production earn their marginal product? Second, do the owners of non-rival ideas have market power or not? We can answer the first without having to answer the second.
Just to refresh, a production function tells us that output is determined by some combination of non-rival inputs and rival inputs.
  • Non-rival inputs are things like ideas that can be used by many firms or people at once without limiting the use by others. Think of blueprints.
  • Rival inputs are things that can only be used by one person or firm at a time. Think of nails.
  • The income earned by both rival and non-rival inputs has to add up to total output.
Okay, given all that setup, here are three statements that could be true.
  1. Output is constant returns to scale in rival inputs
  2. Non-rival inputs receive some portion of output
  3. Rival inputs receive output equal to their marginal product
Pick two.
Romer's argument is that (1) and (2) are true. (1) he asserts through replication arguments, like my example of replicating Earth. (2) he takes as an empirical fact. Therefore, (3) cannot be true. If the owners of non-rival inputs are compensated in any way, then it is necessarily true that rival inputs earn less than their marginal product.

Notice that I don't need to say anything about how the non-rival inputs are compensated here. But if they earn anything, then from Romer's assumptions the rival inputs cannot be earning their marginal product.

Different authors have made different choices than Romer. McGrattan and Prescott abandoned (1) in favor of (2) and (3). Boldrin and Levine dropped (2) and accepted (1) and (3). Romer's issue with these papers is that (1) and (2) are clearly true, so writing down a model that abandons one of these assumptions gives you a model that makes no sense in describing growth. ...
The "mathiness" comes from authors trying to elide the fact that they are abandoning (1) or (2). ...

[There's a lot more in the full post. Also, Romer comments on Vollrath here.]

Paine

Excellent

Lots of conclusions are per determined by simple assumptions like constant returns to scale

If by scale we mean replication of the existing production system on a larger scale

Where say we triple every plant and highway etc

The model nicely captures the reality of a static production system
Where all factors are expandable even if at a cost

This is a very narrow notion of scale effects

If for example markets for oust expand and a different technique is optimal
Then there's a dynamic transition
Where residuals emerge.

anne -> Paine ...

I assume this is the reference which the writer is too inconsiderate to mention:

http://worthwhile.typepad.com/worthwhile_canadian_initi/2015/06/are-ideas-really-non-rival.html

June 13, 2015

Are ideas really non-rival?
By Nick Rowe

Paine -> anne...

Rowe thinks he is making a great joke

But in actuality there is nothing but assertion of various hypothetical entities behind the entire neo classical construct

No matter how carefully these atoms are defined they remain figments

That one can conjure like epicycles

Example

Advertising Is a production factor -- Once we move away from he material basis of production lots of spirits dance in the air around us

Once a non rival good has been discovered or invented or created etc it's cost to replicate is nearly zero

To lay the bulk of profits at its feet is ridiculous of course. But intellectual property none the less is a growing means of exploitation...

Paine -> Paine ...

My definition of non rival is wrong of course. The meaning of non rival is castlessly inexhaustible

Nothing fits this description exactly. And almost is as bad as not at all.

Non rival -- Example of belief in the divinity of Jesus. I can believe as much whether you believe or not

anne -> Paine ...

All exchange value flows from labor time. Even if in complex patterns easily mystified by simple definitions. Of imaginary objects like non-rival production factors

[ I understand and am pleased. ]

Sandwichman said...

Four-fifths of the "Economy" is a Complete Waste of Time

"There are really two questions we are dealing with here. First, do inputs to production earn their marginal product? Second, do the owners of non-rival ideas have market power or not?" -- Dietz Vollrath "What Assumptions Matter for Growth Theory?"

"Dietz Vollrath has a new post that goes a long way toward clarifying the battle lines in the fight over the foundations of growth theory." -- Paul Romer, "The Assumptions in Growth Theory"

Huh? These fellows omit the main assumption, the analogy -- "growth is a concept whose proper domicile is the study of organic units..." (Kuznets, 1947). Kuznets cited with approval Sidney Hook's discussion of the dangers of the use of this analogy.

"As an argument it is formally worthless and never logically compelling. An argument from analogy can be countered usually with another argument from analogy which leads to a diametrically opposed conclusion.... The belief that society is an organism is an old but fanciful notion. It can only be seriously entertained by closing the eye to all the respects in which a group of separate individuals differs from a system of connected cells, and by violently redefining terms like 'birth,' 'reproduction,' and 'death.'"

Growth "theory" gets around this objection to the uncritical use of analogy by ignoring it -- by 'closing the eye' to explicit caveats in the seminal contribution to the measurement of growth. Let's pretend that the economy really is an organism that grows perpetually but never dies.

Name one.

Carry on, growth theorists.


anne -> Sandwichman...

http://econospeak.blogspot.com/2015/06/the-chimerical-analogies-of-growth-and.html

June 6, 2015

The Chimerical Analogies of Growth and Distribution


http://econospeak.blogspot.com/2015/06/four-fifths-of-economy-is-complete.html

June 14, 2015

Four-fifths of the "Economy" is a Complete Waste of Time

-- Sandwichman

Sandwichman -> Sandwichman...

1. "growth is a concept whose proper domicile is the study of organic units..."

2. "The belief that society is an organism is an old but fanciful notion."

3. ?

4. Growth!

Sandwichman -> anne...

"the meaning of per capita growth in China over these last 38 years of 8.6% yearly"

It means, literally, that if you ate one bowl of rice for dinner in 1977, in 2015 you would eat 23 bowls of rice for dinner. Of course it doesn't *really* mean that. The "measurement" is actually a figure of speech.

Figuratively, it means something more like: many more Chinese own cars today than 38 years ago and those cars are worth hundreds of times what the old bicycle was worth. Never mind that the car is used to commute to work, that it takes as long to drive to work through congested traffic as it once did to ride a bike to work and that the air is unbreathable so it would be suicide to go back to riding a bike.

Still, growing 8.6% per year for 38 years is a prodigious achievement even if we don't know what it means.

Sandwichman -> anne...

A large part of that gain in life expectancy is attributable to an enormous decline in infant mortality. Expenditures on improved infant health care would be only a miniscule portion of the total economic growth.

When I say "prodigious" I mean remarkable or immense without attaching any value judgement about whether it is a good or a bad thing. There have obviously been some good things associated with that growth -- see infant mortality. There has also been an explosion of GHG emissions. If 2/3 of that growth was good things (reduced infant mortality, improved nutrition etc.) and 1/3 bad things (police surveillance, cost of commuting to work, etc.) then China would have been better off with a 6% growth rate.

Can't we just forget about the confounded aggregate and get on with promoting the good? No, apparently not. Two pieces of pie is better than one if it's cherry pie but not if it's "dirt" pie.

anne -> Sandwichman...

Can't we just forget about the confounded aggregate and get on with promoting the good?

[ Surely so, but if a part of the good is life span, well, that of India is 66 years which shows how far China has come and I really do know of the problems. ]

anne -> Sandwichman...

Again, I am waiting for an explanation of or a description showing what the past 38 years of per capita growth in China represent. What does the past 38 years of astonishing gains in Chinese productivity represent and how to depict these gains?

Paine -> anne...

We need a welfare index. And that greatly increases the degree of difficulty over a simple output index

Sandwichman -> Paine ...

"If the GDP is Up, Why is America Down?" Clifford Cobb, Ted Halstead, and Jonathan Rowe, The Atlantic, 1995.

http://www.theatlantic.com/past/politics/ecbig/gdp.htm

And do you know what the overwhelming response of economists was to that article? "Nothing new here." "We know GDP is not a measure of welfare. But it's useful because it tells us about the capacity to produce goods that could enhance welfare."

Or to paraphrase Orwell, "If this boot wasn't stamping on your face, you could put it on your foot and it would keep your toes warm -- FOREVER!" Paul Samuelson's version, "Evaluation of Real National Income":

"Production possibilities as such have no normative connotations. We are interested in them for the light they throw on utility-possibilities. This is why economists have wanted to include such wasteful output as war goods in their calculations of national product; presumably they serve as some kind of an index of the useful things that might be produced in better times."

I repeat, NO NORMATIVE CONNOTATIONS. What part of "no" do people not understand? It's neither good nor bad that the economy ACTUALLY produces wasteful output.

The amount of wasteful output "serves as an index" for the amount of useful output that could be produced if the economy wasn't producing wasteful output.

anne -> Sandwichman...

http://econospeak.blogspot.com/2015/06/some-kind-of-index-no-normative.html

June 14, 2015

Some Kind of an Index -- No Normative Connotations

-- Sandwichman

Julio -> Sandwichman...

A question for you folks in this subthread:

"In a perfect free market world where the price mechanism adjusts production to our wishes and all externalities are priced in, GDP measures economic happiness."

Proposition: That myth underlies our world.

Conclusion: In our world, "GDP is not correlated to happiness" is, therefore, a subversive statement.

Is this sensible, and if so, does it make alternative measures of economic well-being difficult to construct?

Julio -> Sandwichman...

Aggregate is not the same as average.

The "prices as the driver" argument is that you will buy a yellow car and I a green one, and Detroit will make just enough of each, and that's the closest we'll ever come to an economy that reflects our wishes, and that's in turn the closest we'll ever come to (economic) happiness.

But this may be an aside: is your point that a "welfare index", as paine proposes, is unrealistic and so irrelevant?

We could measure economic decisions by using economics as far as it takes us to evaluate their consequences, and then using our moral compass to do the measuring.

A more ad-hoc method which, for our collective decisions, has political pitfalls; but politics is the appropriate forum for those fights. We would no longer know (or care) what "progress" is, as a national aggregate.

Sandwichman -> Julio...

"is your point that a "welfare index", as paine proposes, is unrealistic and so irrelevant?"

No, it's not entirely unrealistic and irrelevant but it IS very limited and, like GDP subject to misinterpretation as more substantive than it is.

The thing about GDP that won't be gotten away from is that it does provide information that is useful for projecting revenues for business and for government.

A welfare index wouldn't do that. You can tax income but you can't tax happiness -- at least not literally.

anne -> Sandwichman...

The measurement of economic well-being is inherently difficult (impossible) because it involves the aggregation of subjective judgments....

[ Agreed. ]

anne -> Sandwichman...

The sort of growth-happiness surveying referred to is to my mind no more than pseudo research. As empirical as bumble bees.

Sandwichman -> anne...

anne, I tend to agree with your skepticism about happiness surveying. However, I have also worked on so-called real survey research -- Canadian census. If you saw how the sausage was made...

The Case of the Missing Minsky by Paul Krugman

"...On the Bagehot question, economists were initially caught flat-footed, for two reasons: failure to realize that shadow banking had recreated the risk of bank runs, and failure to appreciate the problems of leverage because there is no room for such problems in representative-agent models."

NYTimes.com

Gavyn Davis has a good summary of the recent IMF conference on rethinking macro; Mark Thoma has further thoughts. Thoma in particular is disappointed that there hasn't been more of a change, decrying

the arrogance that asserts that we have little to learn about theory or policy from the economists who wrote during and after the Great Depression.

Maybe surprisingly, I'm a bit more upbeat than either. Of course there are economists, and whole departments, that have learned nothing, and remain wholly dominated by mathiness. But it seems to be that economists have done OK on two of the big three questions raised by the economic crisis. What are these three questions? I'm glad you asked.

As I see it, it makes sense to think of what happened in terms of three phases.

The questions then are how and why each of these things can/did happen. I think of these as the Minsky question - why do economies grow vulnerable over time ; the Bagehot question - why does all hell break loose now and then; and the Keynes question - how economies can stay depressed, and how such depressed economies work.

On the Keynes question, it's true that we haven't had a radical change in thinking, but that's mainly because the old thinking still works pretty well. That is, the answer for people asking who would be the new Keynes turns out to be that Keynes is the new Keynes. Or maybe that's Hicks - anyway, IS-LMish analysis worked well, and the economists who made fools of themselves were those who rejected the time-tested approaches.

What is new is that we have had a flowering of empirical work, and have much more econometric evidence on monetary and especially fiscal policy, price behavior, and more than we used to. Look, for example, at Nakamura/Steinsson's survey, or at the Blanchard work on multipliers in the euro area. So this is a happy story: the existing framework worked fairly well, and is now buttressed by a lot of really good empirical evidence.

On the Bagehot question, economists were initially caught flat-footed, for two reasons: failure to realize that shadow banking had recreated the risk of bank runs, and failure to appreciate the problems of leverage because there is no room for such problems in representative-agent models. But it wasn't very hard to fix these problems, or at least apply workable patches. Once you realized that repo was the new bank deposits, the basic crisis framework was already there; and there was already enough existing analysis of balance-sheet constraints and all that to make creation of a somewhat messy, inelegant, but usable set of models quite easy.

And here too we have seen a flowering of empirical work, e.g. Mian and Sufi on household debt.

Where we have not, as far as I can tell, made much progress is the Minsky question. Why did the system become so vulnerable? Was it deregulation (or failure of regulation to keep up with institutional change)? Simple forgetting, as memories of past crises faded? Excessively loose policy? I have views, but I have to admit that there isn't a lot of either fresh thinking or hard evidence here.

Why is Minsky still mostly missing? Partly because asking how we got here may be less urgent than the question of what we do now. But also, I'd guess, because it's hard. Bubbles, excessive leverage, and all that probably have a lot to do with the limits of rationality, and behavioral economics doesn't provide anything like as much guidance as it should.

Still, I'm relatively positive in my assessment of the state of macroeconomics. Against mathiness and political ideology, the gods themselves contend in vain, but that's not a problem with the models


kbaa, The Irate Plutokrat

It is good to see Krugman write in opposition to 'mathiness', economists' misuse of mathematics to justify their pet theories. And his suggestion that 'behavioral economics doesn't provide anything like as much guidance as it should' is probably as close to an admission as we are ever likely to get from an academic economist that it's human psychology that drives the economy after all, and that all of the various high minded macroeconomics theories are nothing more than propaganda to be used by lobbyists who present them as scholarship.

Economics is a subject that is driven by data, i.e. numbers. Wherever there are numbers there is always the possibility of misusing mathematics to intimidate. Any paper that cites game theory or the Euler consumption equation to promote public policy should be regarded as fraudulent until shown to be otherwise. Mathematics serves the same function for academic economists as Latin theology did for medieval clerics: both provide an aura of erudite wisdom where there is no wisdom at all to be found.

NB For those who have never studied Calculus, "Euler" is pronounced "oiler", but there's no connection with the price of oil or any other commodity, and don't let any academic economist try to tell you otherwise.

Book Review "Keynes The Return of the Master"

WSJ.com

Yet Mr. Skidelsky chooses to make Mr. Lucas sound like some kind of idiot savant, more interested in playing with mathematical models than in trying to understand how the world actually works. Mr. Lucas, we are told, is following in the tradition of the "French mathematician Leon Walras [who] pictured the economy as a system of simultaneous equations." The very idea is made to sound slightly crazed.

This brings us to the biggest problem with "Keynes." Mr. Skidelsky admits to being poorly trained in the tools that economists use: "I find mathematics and statistics 'challenging,' as they say, and it is too late to improve. This has, I believe, saved me from important errors of thinking."

Has it, really? Mr. Skidelsky would like to think that his math-aversion allows him to focus on the big ideas rather than being distracted by mere analytic details. But mathematics is, fundamentally, the language of logic. Modern research into Keynes's theories-I have conducted such research myself-tries to put his ideas into mathematical form precisely to figure out whether they logically cohere. It turns out that the task is not easy.

Keynesian theory is based in part on the premise that wages and prices do not adjust to levels that ensure full employment. But if recessions and depressions are as costly as they seem to be, why don't firms have sufficient incentive to adjust wages and prices quickly, to restore equilibrium? This is a classic question of macroeconomics that, despite much hard work, is yet to be fully resolved.

Which brings us to a third group of macroeconomists: those who fall into neither the pro- nor the anti-Keynes camp. I count myself among the ambivalent. We credit both sides with making legitimate points, yet we watch with incredulity as the combatants take their enthusiasm or detestation too far. Keynes was a creative thinker and keen observer of economic events, but he left us with more hard questions than compelling answers.

Recommended Links

Google matched content

Softpanorama Recommended

Top articles

[Jun 19, 2019] Bias bias the inclination to accuse people of bias by James Thompson Published on Jun 19, 2019 | www.unz.com

[Nov 29, 2017] Economics is a Belief System - and We are Ruled by Fundamentalists Published on Nov 09, 2015 | resilience.org

[Sep 18, 2017] Critical Realism: Mathematics versus Mythematics in Economics Published on Oct 02, 2015 | www.debtdeflation.com

Sites


Last modified: March, 03, 2020